Homework #4. Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009.

Similar documents
Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

ADVANCED MACROECONOMIC TECHNIQUES NOTE 7b

A simple wealth model

Appendix to ìreconciling Conáicting Evidence on the Elasticity of Intertemporal Substitution: A Macroeconomic Perspectiveî

Economics 2010c: Lecture 4 Precautionary Savings and Liquidity Constraints

The historical evolution of the wealth distribution: A quantitative-theoretic investigation

Optimal Income tax rates with non-democratic political constraints: case of Armenia

Syllabus of EC6102 Advanced Macroeconomic Theory

Entrepreneurship, Frictions and Wealth

Luxury Consumption, Precautionary Savings and Wealth Inequality

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Amaintained assumption of nearly all macroeconomic analysis is that

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

Macroeconomics and Inequality (Macro III)

A numerical analysis of the monetary aspects of the Japanese economy: the cash-in-advance approach

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Maximum Likelihood Estimation

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Time-Varying Employment Risks, Consumption Composition, and Fiscal Policy

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

EE266 Homework 5 Solutions

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Movements on the Price of Houses

Understanding the Distributional Impact of Long-Run Inflation. August 2011

Online Appendix of. This appendix complements the evidence shown in the text. 1. Simulations

1 Explaining Labor Market Volatility

WC-5 Just How Credible Is That Employer? Exploring GLMs and Multilevel Modeling for NCCI s Excess Loss Factor Methodology

Economics 742 Brief Answers, Homework #2

The histogram should resemble the uniform density, the mean should be close to 0.5, and the standard deviation should be close to 1/ 12 =

ELEMENTS OF MONTE CARLO SIMULATION

Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour for the quantitative study of Social Security: two examples

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Solutions for Homework #5

Key Moments in the Rouwenhorst Method

Household Debt and Income Inequality,

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Macroeconomic Models of Economic Growth

Comment on: Optimal saving distortions with recursive preferences by Emmanuel Fahri and Iva n Werning $

Asset Demands of Heterogeneous Consumers with Uninsurable Idiosyncratic Risk

ASSET PRICING WITH LIMITED RISK SHARING AND HETEROGENOUS AGENTS

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

THE NEOCLASSICAL GROWTH MODEL WITH HETEROGENEOUS QUASI-GEOMETRIC CONSUMERS* Lilia Maliar and Serguei Maliar** WP-AD

Highly Persistent Finite-State Markov Chains with Non-Zero Skewness and Excess Kurtosis

1 Modelling borrowing constraints in Bewley models

Balance Sheet Recessions

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Exploring the income distribution business cycle dynamics

Marginal Tax Rates and the Tax Reform Act of 1986: the long-run effect on the U.S. wealth distribution

Development Economics: Macroeconomics

Optimal Taxation Under Capital-Skill Complementarity

Markov-Chain Approximations for Life-Cycle Models

Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification

ECON 6022B Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

Topics in Macroeconomics

The Wealth Distribution and the Demand for Status

Joint Dynamics of House Prices and Foreclosures

Explaining Residential Investment over the Business Cycle: The Importance of Information and Collateral Constraints. Yufei Yuan.

Determinants of Wage and Earnings Inequality in the United States

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Capital Income Taxation with Household and Firm Heterogeneity

+1 = + +1 = X 1 1 ( ) 1 =( ) = state variable. ( + + ) +

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Unemployment (fears), Precautionary Savings, and Aggregate Demand

HOW IMPORTANT IS DISCOUNT RATE HETEROGENEITY FOR WEALTH INEQUALITY?

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

Agricultural and Applied Economics 637 Applied Econometrics II

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

Notes. Cases on Static Optimization. Chapter 6 Algorithms Comparison: The Swing Case

Fiscal Policy with Heterogeneous Agents and Incomplete Markets

Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Financial Econometrics

Problem set Fall 2012.

Precautionary Savings or Working Longer Hours?

working FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Do credit shocks matter for aggregate consumption?

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems III

Endogenous employment and incomplete markets

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

Solving Asset-Pricing Models with Recursive Preferences

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

CFA Level II - LOS Changes

Private Pensions, Retirement Wealth and Lifetime Earnings

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Skewed Business Cycles

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

GARCH Models. Instructor: G. William Schwert

Problem Set (1 p) (1) 1 (100)

Wealth Distribution with Statedependent. Rong-Wei Chu, Jun Nie, and Bei Zhang January 2014 RWP 13-09

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

Optimal Life-Cycle Investing with Flexible Labor Supply: A Welfare Analysis of Default Investment Choices in Defined-Contribution Pension Plans

Transcription:

Fatih Guvenen University of Minnesota Homework #4 Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009. Questions indicated by a star are required for everybody who attends the class. You can use either MatLab or Fortran to do the homework. For each question, please discuss your answer. (Please do not merely provide some numbers and a code). 1. This question asks you to solve the baseline model in Aiyagari (1994, QJE). You are going to build on the programs you wrote for the previous homework where you solved the partial equilibrium consumption-savings problem. Aiyagari embeds that problem in general equilibrium by assuming a Cobb-Douglas production function with capital and labor as inputs. The capital is supplied by households (obtained from the consumer s savings problem). Therefore, you need to clear the capital market by finding the equilibrium interest rate. As in Aiyagari assume that the idiosyncratic income process for a typical consumer follows an AR(1) process. I want you to compare two different discretization methods to convert this AR(1) into a Markov process Tauchen s (1986) method as described in Aiyagari (1994) as well as Rouwenhurst s method (as described in his chapter in the Cooley volume ("Frontier s of Business Cycle Research"). See the appendix to Rouwenhurst s chapter for description). Do each part below using both discretization methods and a 9-state Markov process in each case. Compare your findings for each part below. (a) First, take the CRRA version of E-Z preferences and set risk aversion to 2. Find the average capital stock in the stationary equilibrium of this model as well as the interest rate that clear the capital market. Report your results. (b) Now separate RRA from EIS. Fix EIS=0.9 and vary the risk aversion. Consider RRA=2 and 20. What happens to the capital stock and interest rate when risk aversion rises? (c) Now fix the RRA=2. Vary the EIS from 2 to 0.1. What happens to the capital stock and interest rate? Do you see a clear difference between the effects of the two parameters on the interest rate? Notice that with CRRA preferences you could not identify which parameter is affecting the interest rate (and capital stock) since they vary together. 2. *Krusell-Smith (1998): This question adds aggregate shocks to Aiyagari s model. Let s simplify the problem by assuming the same aggregate and idiosyncratic shock process assumed in K-S. See the paper for details. Assume log utility and no borrowing. Implement the basic K-S algorithm to solve the model. Report how long it takes to solve the model with a convergence criteria that is based on attaining R 2 = 0.99999 in the predictive regression: logk = α 0 + α 1 logk. 1

(a) *Checking accuracy: Calculate the R 2 and regression residual variance of the predictive regression of the interest rate 25 years ahead? Report the two-standard deviation bands of this prediction of the interest rate. Also calculate the one-step ahead R 2 of the regression: logk logk = α 0 + α 1 logk. (b) *Plot the essential accuracy plot of Den Haan as discussed in class. Are you satisfied that your solution is accurate? (c) *Calculate the Gini coefficient for income, wealth, and consumption inequality in the stationary equilibrium. (Obviously the Gini will vary depending on aggregate state. Take the average.) How do they rank with respect to each other? (d) *Solve the model for increasing values of the persistence of the idiosyncratic shock: 0.8, 0.9, 0.5 and 0.995. How do the dispersion measures you computed in part (a) change with persistence? (e) *What fraction of the population are at their constraints in each parameterization in part (d)? As you make the shocks more persistent do you get more people up against the constraint? Give an economic interpretation of your finding. (f) *Now fix persistence at 0.9 and increase the risk aversion to 5. What happens to the Gini measures? What fraction is constrained now? 2

Econ 8312. Computational Methods Homework 4. Iskander Karibzhanov Problem 1. Part (a) In CRRA version of Aiyagari model, I solved for decision rules using policy function iteration with endogenous grid method since it is much faster than value function iteration. In parts (b) and (c) however, the PFI method no longer can be employed since value function enters Euler equation and I had to resort to VFI. To find stationary wealth distribution I implemented CDF iteration algorithm as described in Rios Rull chapter in Marimon book. I also implemented PDF iteration algorithm from Chapter 7 of Maussner DGE modeling book but the resulting density was more jagged than with CDF method. I didn t do Monte Carlo to compute stationary distribution because I think there is no need to spend too much computing time if I can do the same thing with CDF in less than a second. I also wrote the routines for computing Lorenz curves and Gini coefficients to replicate all tables and figures in Aiyagari 94 working paper. As in Aiyagari 94, I assumed that the idiosyncratic income process for a typical consumer follows an AR(1) process 1, ~Normal 0,1 0.2, 0.4, 0.0, 0.3, 0.6, 0.9 Other parameters are the same as in the paper: 0.96, 0.36, 0.08. No borrowing. Using Tauchen and Rouwenhorst methods to approximate the above AR(1) process, I obtained following results by setting relative risk aversion to 2 and using 202 grid points to compute policy functions and 1010 grid points to compute stationary distribution. As we can see both approximation methods produce almost same results. Table 1. Net Return to Capital in %/Aggregate Capital using CDF iteration Using Rouwenhorst method \ 0.0 0.3 0.6 0.9 0.2 4.1215 / 5.4786 4.0856 / 5.5040 4.0088 / 5.5591 3.8085 / 5.7071 0.4 3.9516 / 5.6007 3.7850 / 5.7250 3.4641 / 5.9773 2.8698 / 6.4957 Using calibrated Tauchen method \ 0.0 0.3 0.6 0.9 0.2 4.1208 / 5.4790 4.0844 / 5.5049 4.0075 / 5.5601 3.8049 / 5.7098 0.4 3.9479 / 5.6034 3.7786 / 5.7298 3.4567 / 5.9833 2.8525 / 6.5119 It turns out that some policy functions do not cross the 45 degree line. This is not a problem for endogenous grid method, but can be dangerous for value function iteration method. So I set maximum asset level to 70 because in stationary equilibrium no agent holds assets above that level.

I changed Tauchen method by calibrating the grid spread to minimize the squared percentage deviations in ln 1 and implied by the Markov chain. I noticed that Aiyagari did not use the Tauchen method properly. Instead of varying the spread of the grid, he fixed it to three standard deviations. If he instead used my method, the approximation would be much better as it can be seen from the table below: Grid spread 2.19 2.37 2.33 2.11 \ 0 0.3 0.6 0.9 0.2 0.200 / 0 0.203 / 0.296 0.203 / 0.591 0.204 / 0.887 0.4 0.400 / 0 0.405 / 0.296 0.406 / 0.591 0.409 / 0.887 Comparing this table and Table 1 in Aiyagari paper, we see that even for high serial correlation 0.9 and coefficient of variation 0.4, my method approximates serial correlation to 0.409 which is far better than 0.49 from Aiyagari paper computed using fixed grid spread. The following results were obtained for RRA=2, and AR(1) process 0.6, 0.2. Interest rate = 4.0000, Average capital = 5.5655 Variable Coefficient of variation Gini coefficient Wealth 0.7523 0.4034 Net income 0.2193 0.1225 Gross income 0.3108 0.1706 Gross saving 0.8871 0.4871 Consumption 0.1394 0.0764 % of wealth, income, saving, consumption held 1 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 wealth net income gross income gross saving consumption Lorenz Curves 0 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 % of households

Problem 1. Part (b,c) To check EZ version of Aiyagari model, I firt tested it with RRA=2, EIS= 0.5 to compare with results in part (a). I obtained following similar results: interest rate = 4.0050, average capital = 5.5618 Variable Coefficient of variation Gini coefficient Wealth 0.7526 0.4030 Net income 0.2157 0.1208 Gross income 0.3091 0.1696 Gross saving 0.8835 0.4852 Consumption 0.1383 0.0757 Now I separate RRA from EIS. I fixed EIS=0.9 and consider two cases RRA=2 and RRA=20. Then I fixed RRA=2 and changed EIS from 2 to 0.1. As we can see from the table below, the higher is RRA and the lower is EIS, the lower is the interest rate, the higher is the average capital. It seems like EIS has more influence on the interest rate than RRA. Unlike RRA, increase in EIS however does not decrease the measures of inequality. RRA EIS interest rate average capital 2 0.9 4.0696 5.5154 20 0.9 3.7467 5.7541 2 2.0 4.1146 5.4834 2 0.1 3.4862 5.9593 Coefficient of variation Gini coefficient RRA=2, EIS=0.9 Wealth 0.7506 0.4031 Net income 0.2160 0.1210 Gross income 0.3085 0.1696 Gross saving 0.8828 0.4856 Consumption 0.1392 0.0763 RRA=20, EIS=0.9 Wealth 0.4791 0.2682 Net income 0.1949 0.1094 Gross income 0.2277 0.1280 Gross saving 0.6600 0.3704 Consumption 0.1008 0.0567 RRA=2, EIS=2 Wealth 0.7358 0.3977 Net income 0.2150 0.1205 Gross income 0.3039 0.1677 Gross saving 0.8710 0.4809 Consumption 0.1379 0.0758 RRA=2, EIS=0.1 Wealth 0.7330 0.3914 Net income 0.2107 0.1181 Gross income 0.3027 0.1659 Gross saving 0.8593 0.4710 Consumption 0.1264 0.0692