Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Similar documents
Monopolistic competition models

Monopolistic competition: the Dixit-Stiglitz-Spence model

International Trade Lecture 14: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (I) Melitz (2003)

International Trade Lecture 5: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition

New Trade Theory I. Part A: Simple monopolistic competition model. Robert Stehrer. The Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies - wiiw

ECON Micro Foundations

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Economic Geography, Monopolistic Competition and Trade

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

Class Notes on Chaney (2008)

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

On the Political Complementarity between Globalization. and Technology Adoption

An easier to understand version of Melitz (2003)

Keynesian Multipliers with Home Production

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

ESSAYS ON TRADE LIBERALIZATION WITH FIRM HETEROGENEITY. Aleksandr Vashchilko. Dissertation. Submitted to the faculty of the

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Microeconomics I - Midterm

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

TOBB-ETU, Economics Department Macroeconomics II (ECON 532) Practice Problems I (Solutions)

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

Simple e ciency-wage model

International Trade. Lecture 3: the Krugman model of trade. Thomas Chaney. Sciences Po. Thomas Chaney (Sciences Po) International Trade 1 / 24

International Trade

Trade Protection and the Location of Production

ECO 352 International Trade Spring Term 2010 Week 3 Precepts February 15 Introduction, and The Exchange Model Questions

1 Economical Applications

1 Multiple Choice (30 points)

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Factor Endowments. Ricardian model insu cient for understanding objections to free trade.

Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne Cours de Commerce International L3 Exercise booklet

The Dynamic Heckscher-Ohlin Model: A diagrammatic analysis

International Economics Lecture 2: The Ricardian Model

Microeconomics, IB and IBP

International Trade Lecture 23: Trade Policy Theory (I)

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups

Midterm Exam International Trade Economics 6903, Fall 2008 Donald Davis

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

UCLA Department of Economics Ph. D. Preliminary Exam Micro-Economic Theory

Introducing nominal rigidities.

The Role of Physical Capital

Problem Set # Public Economics

Costs. Lecture 5. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 7 1 / 63

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

Two-factor trade model with monopolistic competition

Financial Market Imperfections Uribe, Ch 7

Econ Review Set 3 - Answers

Economics 326: Pro t Maximization and Production. Ethan Kaplan

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

Lecture 12: New Economic Geography

Lecture 7 - Locational equilibrium continued

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Department of Economics Shanghai University of Finance and Economics Intermediate Macroeconomics

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Some Notes on Timing in Games

International Trade

Mean-Variance Analysis

Basic structure Supplements. Labor productivity and comparative advantages: The Ricardian Model. Robert Stehrer. Version: March 6, 2013

Practice Questions Chapters 9 to 11

Exercises on chapter 4

EC202. Microeconomic Principles II. Summer 2009 examination. 2008/2009 syllabus

Opting out of publicly provided services: A majority voting result

U(x 1. ; x 2 ) = 4 ln x 1

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

Consumer Theory. June 30, 2013

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

EconS Firm Optimization

Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Chapter 4 UTILITY MAXIMIZATION AND CHOICE

1 Unemployment Insurance

Integrated Equilibrium in a Four-good Heckscher-Ohlin-Ricardo model

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

1. If the consumer has income y then the budget constraint is. x + F (q) y. where is a variable taking the values 0 or 1, representing the cases not

CAPITAL CONSTRAINTS, TRADE

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

Macroeconomics IV Problem Set 3 Solutions

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

International Economics B 9. Monopolistic competition and international trade: Firm Heterogeneity

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 7 of the text.

2. Find the equilibrium price and quantity in this market.

Integrated Equilibrium in a Four-good Heckscher-Ohlin-Ricardo model

Fuel-Switching Capability

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

Kwok Tong Soo Lancaster University. Abstract

Lecture 7. The consumer s problem(s) Randall Romero Aguilar, PhD I Semestre 2018 Last updated: April 28, 2018

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid May Microeconomics Grade

Dundee Discussion Papers in Economics

Macroeconomics and finance

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Transcription:

Product Di erentiation Introduction We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade. Now we see how product di erentiation can provide a basis for trade due to consumers valuing variety. When trade occurs due to product di erentiation, even identical countries will trade by exchanging di erent varieties of the same good. The value consumers place on variety generates another source of gains from trade.

IRS due to a xed cost of producing each variety limits the number of varieties produced by a country. Two key versions of modeling preferences for the di erentiated products are the love of variety approach and the ideal variety (bliss point or spatial) approach. Both provide a subutility function that increases in the number of varieties available, but the love of variety approach is easier to employ.

2 Product Di erentiation (Helpman and Krugman 985) The CES utility function has proved very useful in models of product di erentiation. The typical form of modeling preferences is to assume an upper-tiered utility function u(x 0 ; V ) = U (x 0 ; V (x ; :::; x n )) where x 0 is consumption of some homogeneous numeraire good, x ; :::; x n are consumptions of n di erentiated goods, and V is a sub-utility function for a set of differentiated products. Utility is separable between the set of di erentiated goods and the numeraire. Apply a two stage budgeting procedure to allocate spending across di erentiated products and then between the set of di erentiated products and the numeraire.

We assume that preferences are homothetic between the numeraire good x 0 and the set of di erentiated goods x : : : x n so consumers spend a xed share of their income on the two categories of goods. Suppose the upper tier utility function is Cobb-Douglas in the numeraire good and the set of di erentiated goods u(x 0 ; V ) = x 0 V so the elasticity of substitution between the di erentiated goods and the numeraire good equals one. Normalizing the price of the numeraire good to one p 0 =, the consumer s budget constraint sets expenditure equal to income x 0 + nx i= p i x i = I where p i is the price of good i and I is income in terms of the numeraire good.

When preferences are homothetic, the consumer spends a xed proportion of income I on the two set of goods: x 0 = I on the numeraire good and P n i= p i x i = ( )I on all the di erentiated goods. Let E I x 0 = ( )I be expenditure on the set of di erentiated products. Budget constraint for spending on di erentiated goods is nx i= p i x i = E

2. Love of Variety Suppose the sub-utility function is a symmetrical CES function V = 0 nx @ x A i i= ; < This subutility function has several nice properties: Every pair of varieties is equally substitutable: = >! = Degree of substitution does not depend upon the level of consumption of the goods.

Variety has value. Suppose n varieties are available at the same price p. Then the consumer buys equal amounts of all goods. Subutility can be written as V = 0 @ X i x A i = (nx ) = " n E np! # = n E np = n E p and increases as the number of varieties n increases. @V @n =! V n > 0

If the number of di erentiated goods is large, the set of di erentiated goods may be represented by a continuum, so the sum is then replaced by an integral in the subutility function, V = Z n 0 x i di The goal is to maximize subutility V subject to the budget constraint Z n 0 p ix i di = E Given an expenditure E on the di erentiated goods (from the rst stage), the consumer s problem becomes max Z n 0 x i di + E Z n 0 p ix i di The rst order condition for good i is Z n 0 x i di x i p i = 0

and similarly for another good j Z n 0 x i di x j p j = 0 The above two rst order conditions imply x i x j = " pj p i # = " pj p i # If goods are equally priced, then they will be equally demanded p i = p j! p j p i =! x i x j =! x i = x j For a CES utility function, the elasticity of substitution between two di erent varieties is =. Using demand functions, E = Z n x jp i 0 p j di = x jp j Z n 0 p i di

implies x j = Ep j R n0 pi di = Ep R n0 pi j di An individual rm views R n 0 p i di as xed and thus faces a constant elasticity demand curve where k x j = kp j E R n0 p i with demand elasticity equal to the elasticity of substitution between a pair of the di erentiated goods. di Each rm chooses the price of its variety to maximize its pro ts, taking as given the price charged by other rms. Assume that every variety is produced with the same production function.

Focus on a representative rm (producing a unique variety), whose problem is to pick its price to maximize its pro ts = px C (x) Suppose the cost function takes the forms of a xed cost plus a constant marginal cost C (x) = b + cx Then pro ts are = (p c) x b = (p c) kp b The rst order condition for pro t maximization is p = c which implies that all varieties are priced equally at p = c

and in the limit as elasticity becomes in nite, price equals cost and lim! p = c. With all varieties priced equally, the budget constraint nxp = E implies that consumers evenly spread consumption over all available varieties x = E np A zero pro t condition = 0 then pins down the measure of varieties available. n = E b The measure of varieties available decreases in the elasticity and the xed cost of variety b @n @ = E @n b2, @b = E b 2 as intuitively should happen based on cost and bene t.

3 Krugman AER 980 Explanation for trade between countries with similar (even identical) factor endowments (same technology and tastes too). Having a large domestic market operates as a source of comparative advantage (export goods for which have a larger domestic market than other goods relative to ROW). Model derived from the famous Dixit and Stiglitz (977) model of monopolistic competition (horizontal product di erentiation).

3. Consumers A large number of potential goods enter symmetrically into utility according to the utility function U = nx i= where c i is consumption of good i. c i ; 0 < < () Utility exhibits love of variety. Preferences exhibit a constant elasticity of substitution between any two goods. Consumers choose their consumptions c i to maximize their utility () subject to the budget constraint nx i= p i c i = I where p i is the price of good i and I is income.

Consumers solve 0 X n max c c i + @I i i= nx i= p i c i where is the shadow price on the budget constraint (the marginal utility of income). A The rst order conditions (FOC) are c i p i = 0; i = ; : : : ; n which can be rearranged to give individual consumer s demand p i = c i Since everyone is identical, consumption of each good equals production x i of each good per consumer c i = x i L where L is the labor supply (measure of consumers as each consumer has one unit of labor supply).

Substituting for c i, we get the market demand function for good i xi (2) p i = L Firms face a CES demand function with elasticity. No strategic interdependence among rms as the number of available varieties is assumed to be large. Each good i will be produced by only one rm: all rms di erentiate their product from all products offered by other rms.

3.2 Producers Suppose there is only one factor, labor. Let the cost function for each good be given by l i = + x i ; > 0; > 0 (3) where l i is the labor needed to produce x i units of good i. gives the xed cost and the marginal cost (in terms of labor). IRS internal to the rm: average cost declines with output (at a decreasing rate).

Each producer chooses its output x i to maximize its pro ts i = p i x i wl i where w is the wage paid to labor. Substituting the demand function (2) for p i and the cost function (3) for l i, the rm picks its output x i to maximize its pro ts i = x i L w( + x i ): The rst order conditions are! @ i = 2 x @x i i w = 0; i = ; : : : ; n L which can be rearranged to read xi L = w

The left-hand side is recognized as p i from the demand function, so the FOC implies p = p i = w where > is the markup over marginal cost w: price is a xed mark up over marginal cost re ecting the substitutability of varieties. Clearly, the price increases with the marginal cost parameter and decreases with @p @ = w > 0; @p @ = w 2 < 0 Pro ts can be expressed as i = (p w) x i w = x i w

Free entry drives equilibrium pro ts to zero. Solving i = 0 for x i gives x = x i = p w = ( ) Equilibrium output increases in the xed cost of variety and but decreases in the marginal cost parameter @x @ = ( ) @x @ = > 0; @x @ = 2 ( ) < 0 ( ) 2 > 0 Equilibrium output is constant across goods and independent of the resources in the economy. An increase in resources L increases only the number of varieties n that are produced (see below), not the output of each variety x.

3.3 Full Employment Full employment requires that labor demand nl i equal labor supply L L = n( + x) = n where n is the number of varieties actually produced. Solving the full employment condition for n gives n = L + x = L( ) The above equations provide a complete description of the autarkic equilibrium in an economy. As resources L increase, the number of available varieties n increases. dn dl = > 0

An increase in the substitutability of goods decreases n. dn d = L < 0 An increase in the xed cost of variety decreases n. dn L ( ) = d 2 < 0 The gains from trade are related to expanded resources L and imperfect substitutability of goods <.

3.4 International Trade Assume two countries (alike in every way except size) engage in free trade (with zero transportation costs). What does trade do? Fixed costs in the production of each good create an incentive to concentrate production within a rm. Increasing returns to scale imply that concentration is e cient so that two identical countries will specialize in the production of di erent sets of goods and intraindustry trade will occur in similar but differentiated products. Gains from trade stem from the increased diversity of goods available under free trade due to market expansion.

Full employment determines the varieties produced in each country under free trade n = L + x = L( ) (4) n = L + x = L ( ) Each country produces the same number of varieties under free trade as under autarky, but under free trade, consumers can consume all n + n varieties. Since consumers love variety, they gain from trade. The simplifying assumptions of this model imply that free trade does not alter the prices charged by rms or their output levels. Under free trade, consumers solve the same problem but now distribute their expenditures over n + n goods so that they enjoy greater variety.

3.5 Results. Both countries gain from trade because of increased diversity of goods. To see the gains from trade, compare (domestic) utility under autarky! x! w U A = n = n = n (5) L np to utility under free trade, U T = (n + n )! (6) Utility under free trade is higher U R U T = n +!! n = + n > U A n n (7) due to the greater availability of variety n + n > n as n > 0 due to L > 0 and <. Furthermore, the gains from trade decrease with as the goods become closer substitutes so variety is less important du R d = n + n! ln n +! n < 0 (8) n n

Considering the two extremes is illustrative of the vital role of the goods being di erentiated lim U R = ; lim U R = + n!!0 n (9) Gains from trade vanish as goods become perfect substitutes (lose love of variety). 2. Direction of trade is indeterminate, but nothing important depends on which country produces (and thus exports) which good as the goods are symmetric. Of the n+n goods consumed, n are imported by the home country. The value of home country imports measured in wage units equals value of foreign country imports, so trade is balanced. Thus, the volume of trade is determinate. 3. One peculiarity of the model is that the output of each good remains the same even under trade. Krugman (JIE 979) develops a more general (but more tedious) model where the scale of production of each variety does increase with trade.

4. When there are transportation costs, bigger country has the higher wage. Iceberg type transportation costs are assumed: when send one unit of any good abroad, only g arrives as the rest melts on the way. The higher wage in the bigger country gives a production cost advantage in the smaller country to o set the higher total transportation costs paid to reach consumers. 5. Transportation costs lead to the home market e ect countries export those products for which they have bigger markets at home.

4 Ethier AER 982 A large proportion of world trade involves exchange of similar products between industrialized countries. These products are typically intermediate production goods rather than consumption goods as in Krugman s models. Ethier (982) constructs a model in which two kinds of IRS coexist. One is the usual external IRS (as the number of intermediate goods expands, nal output increases). The second is IRS internal to the rm due to the presence of xed costs involved in the production of each intermediate good.

Full general equilibrium model with two goods and two factors of production. Allows us to examine the fate of the traditional HOS theory in the presence of international IRS. Most of the traditional theorems of the HOS model survive quite well. Intra-industry trade is complementary to international factor mobility. Lastly, while IRS are essential to obtain intra-industry trade, the degree of IRS is not of much consequence in determining the magnitude of intra-industry trade.

4. Model Two goods: wheat W and manufactures M Two factors: capital K and labor L Wheat has CRS technology Manufactures has IRS. De ne M = km where k is an index of scale economies and m is the size of operation in the M industry. Let W = T (m) de ne the transformation curve between W and m. M has two sub-sectors: component production and assembly of nished components.

Each components rm produces one type of input x i using m as an input. Let n be the (endogenous) number of components produced m = X m i i=::n where m i is the factor use in component i: Cost function m i = b + ax i ) m = nb + a X i x i Component producers are monopolistic competitors and under free entry (so zero pro ts).

4.2 Final Good All components are assembled through a symmetric CES production function M = n 0 @ X i x i A ; > ; 0 < < Every pair of varieties is equally substitutable. The degree of substitution does not depend upon the level of usage.

Variety is valued. Suppose n varieties are available at price q. Then nal producer buys equal amounts of all components. If x equals the quantity purchased of each component, then M = n ( X i x ) = n (nx ) = n x = n [nx] Clearly, output increases as n increases. Since >, there are IRS in n. These represent the productivity gains that accrue from an increased division of labor. These IRS are external to the nal good producer who cannot control n. M displays CRS with respect to x. Let q i be the price of component i in W units.

Minimize cost of producing each unit min X i q i x i such that n ( X i x ) = First order conditions n 2 3 nx 4 x 5 i i= Take another good j and we have n 2 3 nx 4 x 5 i i= x i q i = 0 x j q j = 0 The above two conditions imply constant elasticity demand curve facing the producer of component i x i x j = " qj q i #

4.3 Components Price of component j is a markup over marginal cost, where the markup equals. Total cost in terms of numeraire good W is given by C(x i ) = T 0 (m)(b + ax i ) The above cost function implies that any given rm is too small to in uence T 0 (m); the opportunity cost of a small amount of m in terms of W. Marginal cost for producer i equals c(x i ) = C 0 (x i ) = T 0 (m)a Pro t maximization requires marginal revenue equal marginal cost q = q j = T 0 (m)a

Since in equilibrium, all components will have the same price q i = q, i = qx + T 0 (m)(b + ax) Free entry implies x = T 0 (m)b q + T 0 (m)a Substituting for price of components x = T 0 (m)a T 0 (m)b + T 0 (m)a = b a( ) Total resources devoted to component production are given by m = n(b + ax) This implies n = m( ) b

Index of IRS can be rewritten by noting that so that n x = M = km k = ( ) b! a m k has the property that it increases in m and decreases in a and b.

4.4 Autarky Set P W = and let P = P M PW = P M : Zero pro ts in supply of M requires that which gives P S M = qnx! P S n x = qnx P S = qn which can be rewritten using values of q and k and n as P S = T 0 (m)m M = T 0 (m) k(m) Note that due to IRS, the supply function is downward sloping.

On the demand side, assume homothetic preferences U(M; W ) = M W Constant expenditure shares imply P D M = (W + P D M) where equals the fraction of income spent on M and W + P D M equals total expenditure of consumers. This implies the demand price equals P D = T (m) k(m)m Intersection of the two curves gives autarkic equilibrium.