THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT (A SOCIAL WELFARE APPROACH)

Similar documents
LABOUR MARKET. People in the labour market employment People in the labour market unemployment Labour market policy and public expenditure

Did the Social Assistance Take-up Rate Change After EI Reform for Job Separators?

Test Bank Labor Economics 7th Edition George Borjas

Gender Differentials in Unemployment Ins and Outs during the Great Recession in Spain

T-DYMM: Background and Challenges

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

Remain, Retrain or Retire: Options for older workers following job loss

Full file at

Balancing Cross-sectional and Longitudinal Design Objectives for the Survey of Doctorate Recipients

Usage of Sickness Benefits

CHAPTER 2. Hidden unemployment in Australia. William F. Mitchell

Women s pay and employment update: a public/private sector comparison

Alternative Measures of Labour Underutilisation:

The minimum wage debate: whatever happened to pay equity?

ANNEX 1: Data Sources and Methodology

Subject Index. Bankruptcy costs, See also Leverage-related

Gender wage gaps in formal and informal jobs, evidence from Brazil.

A longitudinal study of outcomes from the New Enterprise Incentive Scheme

The Moldovan experience in the measurement of inequalities

CYPRUS FINAL QUALITY REPORT

THE PERSISTENCE OF UNEMPLOYMENT AMONG AUSTRALIAN MALES

The social and budgetary impacts of recent social security reform in Belgium

An analysis of the compatibility between disability pensions and employment in Spain * Host Country Report. Introduction HOST COUNTRY REPORT

The labor market in Australia,

The Interaction of Workforce Development Programs and Unemployment Compensation by Individuals with Disabilities in Washington State

Continued slow employment response in 2004 to the pick-up in economic activity in Europe.

Poverty After 50 in Canada: A Recent Snapshot

LABOUR MARKET DEVELOPMENTS IN THE EURO AREA AND THE UNITED STATES SINCE THE BEGINNING OF THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS

Economically Active Population Survey (EAPS) Fourth quarter 2015

$1,000 1 ( ) $2,500 2,500 $2,000 (1 ) (1 + r) 2,000

Intermediate Quality Report for the Swedish EU-SILC, The 2007 cross-sectional component

The impact of the current crisis on the Italian labour market

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES,

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

CYPRUS FINAL QUALITY REPORT

Joint Retirement Decision of Couples in Europe

European Employment Observatory. EEO Review: Employment policies to promote active ageing, Sweden. Dominique Anxo CELMS HB.

17 January 2019 Japan Laurence Boone OECD Chief Economist

Answers To Chapter 7. Review Questions

Unemployment and economic crisis: stress

Economic Standard of Living

STATISTICS ON INCOME AND LIVING CONDITIONS (EU-SILC))

WHO S LEFT TO HIRE? WORKFORCE AND UNEMPLOYMENT ANALYSIS PREPARED BY BENJAMIN FRIEDMAN JANUARY 23, 2019

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

Alice Nabalamba, Ph.D. Statistics Department African Development Bank Group

Alamanr Project Funded by Canadian Government

AGE Platform Europe contribution to the Draft Report on an Adequate, Safe and Sustainable pensions (2012/2234(INI)) Rapporteur: Ria OOMEN-RUIJTEN

Chapter 02. Labor Supply. Multiple Choice Questions. 1. Who is not counted in the U.S. labor force?

Perspectives on the Youth Labour Market in Canada

The Province of Prince Edward Island Employment Trends and Data Poverty Reduction Action Plan Backgrounder

Pensions, Economic Growth and Welfare in Advanced Economies

The Changing Participation Rate of Canadians: New Evidence from a Panel of Demographic Groups

Optimal Progressivity

Economic Standard of Living

Reemployment after Job Loss

Public Finance and Public Policy: Responsibilities and Limitations of Government. Presentation notes, chapter 9. Arye L. Hillman

Monitoring the Performance of the South African Labour Market

Workforce participation of mature aged women

Harmonized Household Budget Survey how to make it an effective supplementary tool for measuring living conditions

Wage Progression in the UK

The Effect of Pension Subsidies on Retirement Timing of Older Women: Evidence from a Regression Kink Design

DRAFT. A microsimulation analysis of public and private policies aimed at increasing the age of retirement 1. April Jeff Carr and André Léonard

MONITORING POVERTY AND SOCIAL EXCLUSION IN SCOTLAND 2015

MACROECONOMICS THROUGH A GENDER LENS

Unemployment, Intervention and Capabilities

2000 HOUSING AND POPULATION CENSUS

WELFARE REFORM AND THE BEHAVIOUR OF THE UNEMPLOYED. Sarah Brown and Karl Taylor Department of Economics University Of Sheffield InstEAD and IZA

Who earns minimum wages in Europe? New evidence based on household surveys

CYPRUS FINAL QUALITY REPORT

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

The Optimal Tax on Capital is Greater than Zero. Joseph E. Stiglitz Columbia University Seminar in Memory of Anthony B. Atkinson

Financial security of elders in China

MEMORANDUM. Gloria Macdonald, Jennifer Benedict Nevada Division of Health Care Financing and Policy (DHCFP)

Older workers: How does ill health affect work and income?

Labour. Overview Latin America and the Caribbean EXECUT I V E S U M M A R Y

The number of unemployed people

Economically Active Population Survey (EAPS) Third quarter of 2013

YOUTH UNEMPLOYMENT IN THE MEMBER STATES OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries

INEQUALITIES IN ACCESS TO PAID MATERNITY & PATERNITY LEAVE & FLEXIBLE WORK

LABOUR MARKET TRENDS IN HUNGARY, 2005

Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan

Trends in Retirement and in Working at Older Ages

L Évolution récente des comportements de retraite au Canada

Quantifying Economic Dependency

Explaining Dualism in a Gender Perspective: Gender, Class and the Crisis

The at-risk-of poverty rate declined to 18.3%

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 PENSION REFORM AND THE LABOUR MARKET. Walpurga Köhler-Töglhofer *

Civil Service Statistics 2008: a focus on gross annual earnings

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

NAP-Inclusion Annex I Diagnosis of the situation of poverty and social exclusion in Spain. Main tendencies.

CASEN 2011, ECLAC clarifications Background on the National Socioeconomic Survey (CASEN) 2011

Dennis Essers. Institute of Development Management and Policy (IOB) University of Antwerp

INSTITUTO NACIONAL DE ESTADÍSTICA. Descriptive study of poverty in Spain Results based on the Living Conditions Survey 2004

Retire Later or Work Harder?

Intermediate Quality report Relating to the EU-SILC 2005 Operation. Austria

The economic impact of increasing the National Minimum Wage and National Living Wage to 10 per hour

HEALTH CAPACITY TO WORK AT OLDER AGES IN FRANCE

Labour Market Resilience

Transcription:

THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT (A SOCIAL WELFARE APPROACH) Lucía Gorjón Sara de la Rica Antonio Villar Ispra, 2018 1

INDICATORS What we measure affects what we think 2

INTRODUCTION 3

BEYOND UNEMPLOYMENT RATES The crisis has generated large numbers of unemployed in many countries. Yet unemployment has hit asymmetrically the various types of workers, depending on their education, age, sex, sector of activity, type of contract, etc. Those asymmetries involve differences in: the incidence (unemployment rates); the severity (unemployment duration and income losses); and the hysteresis (likelihood of remaining unemployed). 4

THE CASE OF SPAIN Spain is one of the countries that suffered most the crisis. Nowadays it exhibits high rates of growth and a substantial reduction of unemployment. Yet, the data show that the reduction in unemployment goes together with: An increase in the average length of the long-term unemployed. An increasing share of unemployed workers without access to unemployment benefits (about 60% in 2015 without any compensation). An increasing probability of remaining unemployed for long term unemployed. In other words: the incidence is declining while the severity and the hysteresis are increasing. 5

THE KEY MESSAGES Those elements point out the conformation of a progressively marginalised group of workers that will have extreme difficulties to become employed again. And also makes it clear that the unemployment rates are far from capturing the social cost of unemployment. 6

THE APPROACH Measuring the social cost of unemployment requires: (i) Taking properly into account the three aspects involved: incidence, severity and hysteresis; and (ii) Paying attention to the diversity existing between the different types of workers. We propose to deal with this evaluation problem in terms of a social welfare function that captures the society s welfare loss derived from the disutility of the unemployed. Since unemployment entails a welfare loss for society it is sensible to compute the size of that loss and not only the incidence of unemployment. 7

THE APPROACH This perspective is similar to the Dalton-Atkinson-Sen approach to normative inequality measurement. It also shares the spirit of those poverty indices that combine incidence and intensity measures. The social cost of unemployment is evaluated by a utilitarian social welfare function that takes as arguments the disutility of the unemployed. 8

DISUTILITIES We model individual agents disutility of being unemployed, at a given point in time, as a function of the income loss, the unemployment duration, and the probability of remaining unemployed. Our approach takes explicitly into account the severity of unemployment depending on the access to unemployment benefits or some social subsidy and the duration of the unemployment. We also allow for a non-linear impact of the unemployment length on disutility as long-term unemployed suffer not only because of the accumulation of low income periods but also from a reduction in the probability of leaving their condition, together with a whole array of personal and social difficulties that affect self-respect, social involvement, and social inclusion. 9

THE BASIC MODEL 10

UTILITY AND DISUTILITY We start from a very simple model in which the worker s utility per period is a Cobb-Douglas function of income and leisure, u(.) = kyr (where k is a constant that defines the units in which we measure utility, y corresponds to income and r to leisure). The worker maximises utility under a time constraint (e.g. hours available per month). The optimal choice obtains by dividing equally the available time, T, between labour and leisure. Then, we have: u* = k(t/2)w(t/2), where (T/2)w = y, w being the monthly wage. 11

UTILITY AND DISUTILITY By choosing properly the units, we can express the value function as u* = w (i.e. the the wage w is a measure of the agent s utility in equilibrium). Consequently, the disutility per period of an unemployed can be measured by the lost income, being that the difference between his wage and the compensation he gets, if any. We call c(.) this cost function, which will be (w-s) if he gets an unemployment benefit s, (w-z) if he gets a social subsidy z, or w if he gets nothing. 12

UTILITY AND DISUTILITY The disutility of a worker h unemployed per q h months is given by: d h = c h (.)q h. For a given population N we can write the per capita utility loss due to unemployment as: D = 1 n n å h=1 c h (.)q h 13

SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT We can express the former equation in a slightly different way as follows: D = nu n n å h=1 c h (.)q h I.e. the per capita social cost of unemployment is given by the product of the unemployment rate and the average disutility of the unemployed. The first term corresponds to the incidence whereas the second one provides a measure of the severity of unemployment. n U 14

CONVEX DISUTILITY One may consider that an extra month of unemployment hurts more the longer the previous unemployment (i.e. a disutility convex in duration). That is, substituting q h by f(q h ), with f > 0, f > 0 The reasons for that include the cumulative effect of the income loss on living standards, the reduction of the probability of finding a new job (deterioration of human capital, signalling effect), and the increasing difficulties of personal fulfilment and social inclusion. 15

CONVEX DISUTILITY The degree of convexity of the duration is related to the curvature of the duration function f (i.e. to its second derivative, which corresponds to the behaviour of the marginal impact of duration). The simplest restriction to control for the degree of convexity is assuming a constant elasticity of the marginal impact of duration. In this way we can parameterize the impact of unemployment duration by a single number: the value of the elasticity of marginal disutility, v. 16

CONVEX DISUTILITY The function that performs this task can be expressed as, f (x) = x 1+n Where v stands for the elasticity of the marginal impact of duration. Therefore we would have: d h = c h (.)q h 1+n h 17

CONVEX DISUTILITY Our proposal here is taking v h as the probability that agent h remains unemployed for one additional period. The degree of convexity of the disutility function is thus governed by the probability of remaining unemployed. This probability is a measure of the unemployment hysteresis. Note that with this formulation we establish a clear bound on the admissible degree of convexity, as the exponent of the individual disutility function varies between 1 and 2. 18

SOCIAL (CONVEX) COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT From this we obtain the following formula for the social cost or unemployment: D = nu n c h (.)q h 1+n h h=1 n U å n U That is, as the product of the incidence and the severity adjusted by the hysteresis. 19

IMPLEMENTATION (THE SPANISH CASE) 20

DATA BASES Our empirical work relies on the use of two different databases, one regarding employed workers and the other the unemployed ones. The first dataset corresponds to the Spanish Earnings Structure Survey (SESS), and contains detailed micro-data on the characteristics of the employed workers and their wages. The demographic characteristics included are gender, age, educational attainment and nationality. The labour market characteristics contain information about the type of contract, tenure in the firm, occupation and activity sector, hours worked (including the extra hours), and detailed information on wages, such as the base wage, overtime pay and other complements. 21

DATA BASES The sample consists of 169,062 full-time workers in the 2014 wave and the survey includes a weighting factor that enables the sample to be weighted to give population figures. We use this database to get estimates of the gross hourly wages for the different types of workers. The range of the hourly wage was set between 2 and 60 euros. 22

DATABASES Our second dataset consists of monthly longitudinal information on all individuals registered with the Spanish Public Employment Service (SPES) from January 2011 to September 2017. The database includes all the information provided by each individual when registering at the Employment Office, including standard demographic characteristics (gender, age, education level, nationality, postcode and residence, knowledge of other languages), as well as labour market information (previous employment experience, occupational and geographical searches, unemployment duration, etc.). The SPES also provides exact information on the unemployment benefits individuals are receiving or the last received and the date of starting and ending of the entitlement. Our dataset contains all unemployed individuals in January 2015 (5,520,253). 23

COMPUTING THE INCOME LOSS The first step to approach the social cost of unemployment is to estimate the lost wage. To do so we find the set of characteristics that are common in both databases and define a set of types of workers (either employed or unemployed). Those characteristics are: gender (2 groups), age (10 groups), level of education (10 groups), a dummy indicating whether the individual is foreign or native, sector of activity (19 groups) and 2 digit sector of occupation (58 groups). We estimate the predicted hourly wages for the different types of employed workers and impute them to the unemployed individuals of the same type. According to the imputed wage, the individual information on the type of unemployment benefit and the unemployment duration, we compute the average cost of unemployment for each unemployed (the c(.) function). 24

THE HYSTERESIS Next we estimate the probability of finding a job next month (from January 2015 to February 2015). To perform this calculation we take into account all observable variables that may affect the employability of those registered with the Public Employment Service: demographic characteristics: gender, age, nationality, disability, education and language skills; job characteristics: unemployment duration, requested occupations, experience, activity in the previous field of work, geographical scope of the new job search and region of registration. 25

COMPENSATIONS Once we have estimated the imputed wage and the probability of being unemployed for one more month, depending on her/his characteristics for each unemployed individual (4,988,632 agents in our dataset in January 2015), we consider three different groups of unemployed workers: (1) Those who receive unemployment benefits (UB); (2) Those who receive social subsidies (SS); and (3) Those who do not receive any income (N). 26

DISTRIBUTION OF THE UNEMPLOYED DEPENDING ON COMPENSATIONS 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% Enero Junio Enero Junio Enero Junio Enero Junio Enero Junio Enero Junio Enero Junio 2011 2011 2012 2012 2013 2013 2014 2014 2015 2015 2016 2016 2017 2017 None Unemployment benefit Social subsidy 27

PRELIMINARY RESULTS 28

THE MOST FAVOURABLE CASE We analyse here the most favourable case, in order to obtain a lower bound for the social cost of unemployment. This case is built according to the following simplifications: Ignoring the hysteresis (that is, setting v = 0 for all h), which makes the disutility linear in duration. Assuming that all unemployed workers with duration q < q* that receive a social subsidy have been receiving the subsidy from the very beginning. And also that those unemployed receiving a subsidy, with a duration q > q*, have received previously unemployment benefits. Assuming that those unemployed for more than two years who receive no compensation have received unemployment benefits for 24 months. 29

MAIN FINDINGS The average probability of remaining unemployed is extremely high (0.957 for the whole population of unemployed, with values above 0.9 for all types of unemployed). The average unemployment duration is very high in general (more than 20 months) with extreme values for those unemployed for more than two years (more than 50 moths), which represent almost one third of all unemployed. Unemployment duration varies substantially between the different types of unemployed. Women s duration is about 22% higher than that of men. Much larger are the differences by national origin (72% higher in natives) and by age (older unemployed almost triplicate the duration of the younger). Differences by level of studies are relatively small. 30

MAIN FINDINGS The estimated (gross) income loss per month exhibits the expected pattern and reflects the differences in wages and other features of the labour market for the types of workers. Women income loss is 6% lower than that of men. Foreigners loss is 27% smaller than that of natives. Younger loss is some 36% lower than that of the older. Low educated unemployed suffer a loss 44% smaller than those with higher education. Almost 60% of the unemployed population do not receive any compensation. 31

DURATION, INCOME LOSS AND PROBABILITY OF REMAINING UNEMPLOYED BY DEMOGRAPHIC GROUPS (SPAIN, 2015) Shares of Duration Income Probabilit population (months) loss ( /month) y v subgroups Total 100,0% 23,13 1766,48 0,966 Gender Female 51,1% 25,18 1717,76 0,970 Male 48,9% 20,98 1827,51 0,961 y Nationalit Native 88,6% 24,23 1801,46 0,966 Foreign 11,4% 14,54 1312,78 0,968 Age < 25 5,7% 9,69 1193,92 0,956 25-45 46,8% 16,69 1630,69 0,955 > 45 47,5% 31,08 1859,89 0,978 Education Low 46,2% 23,98 1503,32 0,972 Medium 39,0% 23,36 1781,40 0,964 32 High 14,7% 19,80 2719,56 0,954

DURATION, INCOME LOSS AND PROBABILITY OF REMAINING UNEMPLOYED BY DEMOGRAPHIC GROUPS (SPAIN, 2015) Shares of Duration Income Probabili population (months) loss ( /month) ty v subgroups Unemp. duration Unemp. benefits < 1year 1-2 years > 2 years UB SS None 46,9% 4,27 1627,72 0,946 17,3% 16,96 1626,26 0,976 35,8% 50,84 1804,45 0,987 16,6% 10,42 1337,96 0,940 25,1% 28,43 1558,83 0,975 58,3% 24,46 1922,50 0,970 33

SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT IN THE MOST FAVOURABLE CASE Value Relative value Total 40.852 100,0 Gender Female 43.249 105,9 Male 38.349 93,9 Nationality Native 43.647 106,8 Foreign 19.089 46,7 Age < 25 11.574 28,3 25-45 27.224 66,6 > 45 57.812 141,5 Education Low 36.054 88,3 Medium 41.622 101,9 High 53.860 131,8 34

SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT IN THE MOST FAVOURABLE CASE Value Relative value Unemp. duration Unemp. benefits < 1year 1-2 years > 2 years UB SS None 6.953 17,0 27.576 67,5 91.736 224,6 13.939 34,1 44.310 108,5 47.030 115,1 35

SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT Female workers, natives, older workers, those with high education, those with longer duration, and those without unemployment subsidies face the greatest social costs of unemployment relative to their reference groups. In relative terms, there are some 12 points of difference between men and women, about 60 between natives and foreign, 113 between older and younger, about 44 between high and low educated workers, more than 207 points between those unemployed more than two years and those unemployed less than one year, and 81 points between those with unemployment subsidy and those without any income. 36

SHARES OF THE TOTAL COST Cost Share Difference cost and population share Total 100% 0,0% Gender Female 54% 8,3% Male 46% -8,3% Nationality Native 95% 8,0% Foreign 5% -8,0% Age < 25 2% -5,0% 25-45 31% -23,8% > 45 67% 28,8% Education Low 41% -4,3% Medium 40% 1,8% High 19% 2,5% 37

SHARES OF THE TOTAL COST Cost Share Difference cost and population share Unemp. duration Unemp. benefits < 1year 1-2 years > 2 years UB SS None 8% -46,1% 12% -13,9% 80% 60,0% 6% -12,4% 27% 3,8% 67% 8,6% 38

SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT Most of the burden of the social cost of unemployment is supported by natives who have been unemployed for more than two years, most of which are above 45 years old and receive no compensation. It is also interesting going beyond the average values of the different types of workers and look at how those costs are distributed within the types. We shall consider now this aspect by comparing the cumulative distributions of the types. 39

CD OF THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYED MEN AND WOMEN (SPAIN 2015) 40

CD OF THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYED BY AGE (SPAIN 2015) 41

CD OF THE SOCIAL COST OF UNEMPLOYMENT BY DURATION (SPAIN 2015) 42

THANKS FOR YOUR ATTENTION 43