Arindam Das Gupta Independent. Abstract

Similar documents
Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

Mathematical Economics Dr Wioletta Nowak, room 205 C

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Endogenous Protection: Lobbying

FINANCIAL REPRESSION AND LAFFER CURVES

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Options for Fiscal Consolidation in the United Kingdom

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Economic Growth and Development : Exam. Consider the model by Barro (1990). The production function takes the

Environmental Policy in the Presence of an. Informal Sector

Optimal Taxation Policy in the Presence of Comprehensive Reference Externalities. Constantin Gurdgiev

Mathematical Economics

Advanced Microeconomic Theory EC104

VERTICAL RELATIONS AND DOWNSTREAM MARKET POWER by. Ioannis Pinopoulos 1. May, 2015 (PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE) Abstract

Indirect Taxation of Monopolists: A Tax on Price

Public Good Provision: Lindahl Tax, Income Tax, Commodity Tax, and Poll Tax, A Simulation

Journal of College Teaching & Learning February 2007 Volume 4, Number 2 ABSTRACT

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Non welfare-maximizing policies in a democracy

Privatization and government preference. Abstract

Non-monotonic utility functions for microeconomic analysis of sufficiency economy

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Microeconomics 2nd Period Exam Solution Topics

CEREC, Facultés universitaires Saint Louis. Abstract

Measuring Sustainability in the UN System of Environmental-Economic Accounting

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

Econ Homework 4 - Answers ECONOMIC APPLICATIONS OF CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION. 1. Assume that a rm produces product x using k and l, where

The supply function is Q S (P)=. 10 points

Advanced Microeconomics

The Effects of Specific Commodity Taxes on Output and Location of Free Entry Oligopoly

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Trade Agreements and the Nature of Price Determination

Endogenous Leadership with and without Policy Intervention: International Trade when Producer and Seller Differ

Volume 31, Issue 3. The dividend puzzle and tax: a note. Frank Strobel University of Birmingham

Introductory Mathematics for Economics MSc s: Course Outline. Huw David Dixon. Cardiff Business School. September 2008.

Antino Kim Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, Bloomington Bloomington, IN 47405, U.S.A.

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Tourism and welfare enhancing export subsidies

Working Paper No. 241

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Smooth pasting as rate of return equalisation: A note

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

THE UNIVERSITY OF THE WEST INDIES, MONA ECON3016: Public Finance

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

MICROECONOMICS II. Author: Gergely K hegyi. Supervised by Gergely K hegyi. February 2011

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Coordinating tariff reduction and domestic tax reform under imperfect competition Keen, M.; Ligthart, J.E.

Modern Public Economics

Factor market oligopsony and the location decision of free entry oligopoly. Abstract

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

Search, Moral Hazard, and Equilibrium Price Dispersion

Answer ALL questions from Section A and ONE question from Section B. Section A weighs 60% of the total mark and Section B 40% of the total mark.

The theory of taxation/3 (ch. 19 Stiglitz, ch. 20 Gruber, ch.15 Rosen) Desirable characteristics of tax systems (optimal taxation)

Ninth ARTNeT Capacity Building Workshop for Trade Research "Trade Flows and Trade Policy Analysis"

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

Pass-Through Pricing on Production Chains

International Trade Lecture 5: Increasing Returns to Scale and Monopolistic Competition

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups

What Industry Should We Privatize?: Mixed Oligopoly and Externality

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Zhiling Guo and Dan Ma

IS TAX SHARING OPTIMAL? AN ANALYSIS IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT FRAMEWORK

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Optimal Progressivity

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

UNIVERSITY OF NOTTINGHAM. Discussion Papers in Economics

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

MONOPOLY (2) Second Degree Price Discrimination

ECONOMICS PUBLIC SECTOR. of the JOSEPH E. STIGUTZ. Second Edition. W.W.NORTON & COMPANY-New York-London. Princeton University

Universidad Carlos III de Madrid June Microeconomics Grade

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

FIRST PUBLIC EXAMINATION

MS&E HW #1 Solutions

Exercise 1. Jan Abrell Centre for Energy Policy and Economics (CEPE) D-MTEC, ETH Zurich. Exercise

Principles of Optimal Taxation

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Noncooperative Oligopoly

A SECOND-BEST POLLUTION SOLUTION WITH SEPARATE TAXATION OF COMMODITIES AND EMISSIONS

THEORIES OF TAX EVASION AND THE HIDDEN ECONOMY

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

SAMPLE QUESTION PAPER 2 ECONOMICS Class XII BLUE PRINT

Solutions to Assignment #2

Growth and Welfare Maximization in Models of Public Finance and Endogenous Growth

Transcription:

With non competitive firms, a turnover tax can dominate the VAT Arindam Das Gupta Independent Abstract In an example with monopoly final and intermediate goods firms and substitutable primary and intermediate inputs, it is shown that there exist turnover taxes that yield more revenue than any feasible value added tax. Second, simultaneously higher welfare, revenue and output are possible with the turnover tax. I thank Dilip Mookherjee and Kunal Sengupta for comments while this paper was being written and my wife, Sadhna Marwaha, for helping check the algebra and spreadsheet programming. I also thank the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy for supporting an earlier draft of the paper via a visiting faculty position. All errors are mine. Citation: Das Gupta, Arindam, (005) "With non competitive firms, a turnover tax can dominate the VAT." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 8, No. 9 pp. 1 6 Submitted: September 8, 005. Accepted: September 13, 005. URL: http://www.economicsbulletin.com/005/volume8/eb 05H0003A.pdf

1. Overview and motivation Conjectured efficiency and administrative advantages of the Value-Added Tax (VAT) have led to it being introduced or replacing other taxes on production and sales, often a general sales or turnover tax (TT), in over 10 developed, developing and transition economies over the past 50 years (Ebrill et. al., 001). A major exception, the United States, has retail sales taxes (RST) in most states, which, like the VAT, does not tax intermediate goods. An important theoretical argument favouring the consumption type VAT/RST over a TT stems from the Diamond and Mirrlees (1971) demonstration that a necessary condition for welfare maximizing second best taxes on competitive firms, given a fixed revenue requirement, is that there be no taxation of productive inputs. Dasgupta and Stiglitz (197) extend this result to nonconstant returns to scale. However, Stiglitz and Dasgupta (1971) show that the Diamond and Mirrlees result does not hold if the government's choice of fiscal instruments is constrained or if some producers are monopolists. 1 In this case, the difference between price and marginal cost should be subsidised, with the subsidy being financed by distortionary input taxes if a 100 percent profit tax is insufficient for budget balance. Stiglitz and Dasgupta (1971) do not examine if input taxation is optimal when, given constraints, there is a tax rather than a subsidy on monopoly producers, as obtains in most real world tax systems. Direct analytical comparison of the VAT/RST with the TT and other taxes on production or sales have, however, affirmed the superiority of the VAT in terms of welfare, tax revenue, output or productive efficiency. These comparisons of the VAT/RST with the TT have either assumed a production technology with fixed intermediate input requirements per unit of final output or competitive firms or both. I construct an example here to illustrate the following straightforward intuition. A part of the tax base under a TT, the turnover of intermediate goods firms, is excluded from the base of the VAT. With competitive intermediate input and primary factor markets this does not actually result in any shrinking of the potential tax base since intermediate input firms must shift the tax burden forward or incur long run losses. However, with imperfect competition or monopoly, surplus accruing to intermediate firms escapes taxation under the VAT. If this causes enough VAT base narrowing, distortion from high output tax rates needed to raise a given amount of revenue may more than offset the production efficiency loss from input taxation under the TT and make it superior to the VAT in welfare, revenue and output terms. In fact I find in the example that at some tax rates the TT yields more revenue than any feasible VAT. In the example, a monopoly final goods firm buys intermediate inputs from a monopoly intermediate goods firm. Primary and intermediate inputs are substitutes. The final goods firm chooses its output to maximize profits and the intermediate goods firm chooses the price of intermediate goods, with each firm taking the other firm's choice of strategic variable as given. I identify a set of numerical parameters for which the TT dominates the VAT/RST. 1 Other situations where input taxes can be optimal are where there is non-constant returns and limited profits taxation or where the government faces a budget constraint. For the case of nontaxable sectors, see also Newbery (1986). Das-Gupta and Gang (1996) compare welfare and output under revenue neutral VAT/RST and TT under fixed proportions and competitive intermediate good but not final good industries. Friedlaender (1967) and Bhatia (199) examine price distortions. 1

. The example A profit maximizing monopoly, the C-firm, produces consumer goods (Q) using an intermediate input (M) and a primary factor (L). The inverse demand for the consumer good is P = f gq, where f and g are positive constants. The cost function for the consumer good firm is assumed to be derived from a linear homogeneous CES production function with elasticity of substitution equal to. That is, as in Varian (1984), write the production function as Q(M,L) = [(am) ρ +(bl) ρ ] 1/ρ, where a, b are positive constants and the constant ρ < 1 is related to the 1 elasticity of substitution (ES) by ES =. Then the associated cost function is 1 ρ 1 θ θ r w θ ρ C(Q,r,w) = Q +, θ. a b ρ 1 In the expression, r and w are respectively the unit price of the intermediate input and primary factor. Setting ρ= 0.5, so that θ = 1, implies that 1 a b C(Q,r,w) = Q + r w = Q rw br. + aw Since factor prices other than r are held fixed in this example, extension to additional primary and intermediate factors is straightforward. From Shephard's Lemma, the derivative of C with respect to r gives the C-firm's derived demand for the intermediate input as aw M = Q. (br + aw) Therefore the cost of the primary factor is wbr C-rM = C P = Q. (br + aw) A second profit maximizing monopoly, the I-firm, produces the intermediate input using a primary factor which is assumed to be available at a constant unit cost according to the function C I = cm, c > 0. The cost function is compatible with any linear homogeneous production technology, given fixed factor prices. Choosing the primary factor as the numeraire, c is set to unity. Extension to many primary factors is trivial. Proportional sales taxes at rate u > 0 and s 0 are levied on the C-firm and I-firm respectively. So a VAT/RST is where s = 0, u = v. This is to be compared with a single rate TT levied at rate s = u = t. In the example, value-added (VA) is PQ. Tax revenue (G), is upq + smr. Welfare (W) is the sum of consumer surplus + producer surplus + G. This is equivalent, in the absence of fixed factors, to the area under the demand curve for consumer goods less the cost of primary inputs used in both consumer and intermediate goods production: W = fq ½gQ C P C I

The profits of the two firms are given by π C = (fq gq rw )(1-u) Q (1) br + aw and raw aw π I = Q (1-s) Q. (br + aw) (br + aw) () It is easily verified that, if consumer goods and intermediate goods prices are constrained to equal marginal costs, as with competitive firms, then for any valid set of parameters and TT rate, a VAT rate can be found at which output, value added, tax revenue and welfare with the VAT are higher than with the TT. From (1) and () the first order conditions for profit maximization of the two firms are (second order conditions can be shown to hold): rw (f gq)(1-u) br + aw = 0 (3) and ( aw + br)(1 s) b[r(1 s) 1] aw 3 (aw + br) Q = 0. (4) Condition (3) and (4) each imply the usual property that optimal output is where demand is elastic. This implies, first, that VA is increasing in Q. Second, elastic demand immediately points to a technological restriction on the nature of strategic interaction: If the intermediate input to output ratio is fixed then no equilibrium is possible when the input firm takes output of the consumer good as given. Solving the first order conditions simultaneously gives the equilibrium values Q* and r*: aw(1- s) + b r* = (5) b(1- s) f w [aw(1 s) + b] Q* = (6) g 4gb(1 u) [aw(1- s) + b] Equilibrium values of M, P, G, VA and W can be found from (5) and (6). Setting s = 0 and u = v, equilibrium values with a VAT can be found. Similarly, setting s = u = t, equilibrium values with a TT can be found. The possibility of a TT dominating a given VAT and of there being no revenue neutral VAT for some rates of the TT can be illustrated with the parameters (a,b,f,g,w) = (0.4, 0.6, 000, 3, 00). In Figure 1, welfare and revenue are compared at feasible TT and VAT rates yielding nonnegative profits, output and costs, for v = 0.004n, n = 1,, and also at v = 0.000001. Some variables turn negative for v > 0.916. For each VAT rate, welfare, revenue and output are higher with a TT levied at t = 0.96v. Furthermore, revenue at any feasible VAT rate is below TT revenue to the left of both Laffer curve peaks for TT rates above 67.13%: There does not exist a 3

revenue neutral VAT at these TT rates. The Laffer curve peaks for the VAT and TT are respectively at v L, 76.789% < 100v L % < 76.790% and at t L, 75.849% < 100t L % < 75.850%. 3 On the other hand, the VAT dominates the TT if final goods firms or consumers capture a greater proportion of available surplus, for example with (a,b,f,g,w) = (0.984, 0.016, 10000, 1, 0.07) Value Added Indices Revenue Welfare VAT Rate (t = 0.96v) Figure 1: VAT Dominated by a Turnover Tax: Welfare, Revenue and Output Indices (VAT: Dotted lines) 3 Data plotted in the graph are for indexes rather than actual data for clarity. Each variable (say x V for the VAT and x T for the TT), x V is replaced by x W = (1 0.8D 0.D max )x T, where D > 0 is a fraction defined by x V = (1-D)x T. D max is the maximum gap between x T and x V pairs in the graph. This leads to exaggeration of all but the maximum gap between VAT and TT indices. xi min(x W, xt ) Data are then normalised using the transformation xi = J + max(x W, xt ) min(x W, xt ) i = W,T. J = 0,1 or respectively for welfare, revenue and output indices causing them to lie in the intervals [0,1], [1,] and [,3] respectively permitting plotting without overlap. 4

3. Concluding comment The possibility of a TT dominating a VAT, along with earlier negative results relating to the optimality of input taxation in the presence of constraints, cast further doubt on whether a VAT really is superior to other production and sales taxes such as the turnover tax it has often replaced. Recent empirical evidence on the output or revenue impact of the VAT in comparison with production or sales taxes it has replaced, in a major cross-country study of the VAT by Ebrill et. al. (001), also does not clearly establish the superiority of the VAT though the authors point to serious difficulties in drawing robust conclusions form cross-country data. The example given here suggests that a possible partial explanation for the VAT not being clearly dominant is market power of firms along with the possibility of input substitution. References Bhatia, K. B. (199) "Indirect Taxes and Output Prices in Hierarchical Production", Public Finance/ Finances Publiques, 47, 347-66. Dasgupta, P. and J. Stiglitz (197) "On Optimal Taxation and Public Production" Review of Economic Studies, 39, 87-103. Das-Gupta, A. and I. N. Gang (1996) "A Comparison of Sales Taxes", Public Finance/Finances Publiques, 51, 17-5. Das-Gupta, A. and I. N. Gang (003) "Value Added Tax Evasion, Auditing and Transactions Matching" in Institutional Elements of Tax Design and Reform by J. McLaren, Ed., Technical Paper No. 539, Washington D.C: The World Bank. Diamond, P. and J. Mirrlees (1971) "Optimal Taxation and Public Production I: Production Efficiency", American Economic Review, 61, 8-7. Ebrill, L., M. Keen, J. Bodin and V. Summers (001) The Modern VAT, Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund. Friedlaender, A. F. (1967) "Indirect Taxes and Relative Prices", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 81, 15-39. Newbery, D. (1986) "On the Desirability of Input Taxes", Economics Letters, 0, 67-70. Stiglitz J. and P. Dasgupta (1971) "Differential Taxation, Public Goods and Economic Efficiency", Review of Economic Studies, 38, 151-174. Varian, H. R. (1984) Microeconomic Analysis, Second Edition, New York: W.W. Norton. 5