Production, Revenue, and Cost

Similar documents
Economics 101 Section 5

CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

Unit 3: Production and Cost

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

FUNCTIONS. Revenue functions and Demand functions

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 9 THE COSTS OF PRODUCTION

First page. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson

1. The advantage of sole proprietorship over partnership is that: A) it is easier to finance a business where there is only one owner.

The Costs of Production

Dr. Barry Haworth University of Louisville Department of Economics Economics 201. Midterm #2

Welcome to Day 8. Principles of Microeconomics

Date: Jan 19th, 2009 Page 1 Instructor: A. N.

ECON 102 Boyle Final Exam New Material Practice Exam Solutions

How Perfectly Competitive Firms Make Output Decisions

ECON 102 Brown Exam 2 Practice Exam Solutions

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 3 Production and Costs 3.1 PRODUCTION FUNCTION

8a. Profit Maximization by a competitive firm: a. Cost and Revenue: Total, Average and Marginal

Final Review questions

Measuring Cost: Which Costs Matter? (pp )

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Economics 101 Fall 2013 Homework 5 Due Thursday, November 21, 2013

First Quiz Solutions Managerial Economics: Eco 685. a. (a) The production function is Cobb-Douglas. Therefore we can use the output elasticity

Long-Run Costs and Output Decisions

Lecture notes: 101/105 (revised 9/27/00) Lecture 3: national Income: Production, Distribution and Allocation (chapter 3)

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

Quadratic Modeling Elementary Education 10 Business 10 Profits

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 7 of the text.

The Theory of the Firm

The Costs of Production

Paul Krugman and Robin Wells. Microeconomics. Third Edition. Chapter 11 Behind the Supply Curve: Inputs and Costs. Copyright 2013 by Worth Publishers

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Chapter 21: The Cost of Production

! Continued. Demand for labor. ! The firm tries to maximize its profits:

of Production and the Financing of a Firm

Production Theory. Lesson 7. Ryan Safner 1. Hood College. ECON Microeconomic Analysis Fall 2016

EC202 Macroeconomics

ANSWERS To next 16 Multiple Choice Questions below B B B B A E B E C C C E C C D B

The Costs of Production

13 The Costs of Production

Chapter 7. The Cost of Production. Fixed and Variable Costs. Fixed Cost Versus Sunk Cost

Chapter 7. The Cost of Production. ΔVC Δq. ΔTC Δq. Fixed and Variable Costs. Fixed Cost Versus Sunk Cost. Measuring Costs

Commerce and Economics

AGGREGATE DEMAND, AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AND INFLATION. Chapter 25

0 $50 $0 $5 $-5 $50 $35 1 $50 $50 $40 $10 $50 $15 2 $50 $100 $55 $45 $50 $35 3 $50 $150 $90 $60 $50 $55 4 $50 $200 $145 $55 $65

7. The Cost of Production

Test Review. Question 1. Answer 1. Question 2. Answer 2. Question 3. Econ 719 Test Review Test 1 Chapters 1,2,8,3,4,7,9. Nominal GDP.

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

a) A Giffen good is a type of inferior good and therefore demand decreases as consumer s real income increases.

Lecture # 14 Profit Maximization

Open Math in Economics MA National Convention 2017 For each question, E) NOTA indicates that none of the above answers is correct.

The Theory behind the Supply Curve. Production and Costs

Review of General Economic Principles. Review Notes from AGB 212

*** Your grade is based on your on-line answers. ***

4) Economists usually assume that is a fixed input in the run. A) labor; short B) capital; short C) labor; long D) capital; long

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Time Value of Money Toolbox CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION CASH FLOWS

ECONOMICS 207 SPRING 2008 LABORATORY EXERCISE 6 KEY. 12x 16 x 2 2x

Business 33001: Microeconomics

This is Appendix B: Extensions of the Aggregate Expenditures Model, appendix 2 from the book Economics Principles (index.html) (v. 2.0).

Theory of Cost. General Economics

Lecture 19 Monday, Oct. 26. Lecture. 1 Indifference Curves: Perfect Substitutes. 1. Problem Set 2 due tomorrow night.

Problem Set 5 Answers. A grocery shop is owned by Mr. Moore and has the following statement of revenues and costs:

Homework Assignment #6. Due Tuesday, 11/28/06. Multiple Choice Questions:

Costs. Lecture 5. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 7 1 / 63

PART II CLASSICAL THEORY. Chapter 3: National Income: Where it Comes From and Where it Goes 1/64

Model Question Paper Economics - I (MSF1A3)

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Problem Set #8

IV. THE FIRM AND THE MARKETPLACE

DEMAND AND SUPPLY ANALYSIS: THE FIRM

Notes On IS-LM Model Econ3120, Economic Department, St.Louis University

Short Run Competitive Equilibrium. Figure 1 -- Short run Equilibrium for a Competitive Firm

Finance Solutions to Problem Set #4: Production and Cost Analysis

FARM MANAGEMENT Lecture.5 Costs, Returns and Profits on the Output Side

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Economics 101 Section 5

EconS Cost Functions

Summer 2016 ECN 303 Problem Set #1

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 7: Producer Theory - costs and competition revisited

Leader: Shealyn Course: Econ 101 Instructor: Peter Orazem Date: April 17, 2012

Unit 3: Costs of Production and Perfect Competition

Lecture 7 - Locational equilibrium continued

11 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans1

Economics 326: Pro t Maximization and Production. Ethan Kaplan

CMA Part 2 Financial Decision Making

LINES AND SLOPES. Required concepts for the courses : Micro economic analysis, Managerial economy.

DUOPOLY MODELS. Dr. Sumon Bhaumik ( December 29, 2008

Lecture 9(i) Announcements. Effects. oe with. and

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis November 13, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 2

CASE FAIR OSTER PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N. PEARSON 2012 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

ECON Micro Foundations

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

HARVEST MODELS INTRODUCTION. Objectives

Economics 431 Final Exam 200 Points. Answer each of the questions below. Round off values to one decimal place where necessary.

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Principles of Macroeconomics 2017 Productivity and Growth. Takeki Sunakawa

Chapter 8a: Growth Accounting

BEE1024 Mathematics for Economists

Cost Functions. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

The level of consumption and saving in the United States is higher today than a decade ago because real GDP and income are higher.

Lecture 3: National Income: Where it comes from and where it goes

2) Using the data in the above table, the average total cost of producing 16 units per day is A) $ B) $5.00. C) $5.55. D) $2.22.

Transcription:

Production, Revenue, and Cost All businesses are formed to produce a set of goods and/or services for sale at a profit. Business can be classified into proprietorships, partnerships, and corporations. The types of business organization chosen will be determined by how complicated the production and sale processes are for the good or service. In this chapter, we want to look at the fundamental aspects of producing and selling a good and how profits are determined. We will also want to explain why profits are important by emphasizing the function profits play in the economy. Production is a technical relation between inputs and outputs. Over time this technical relation can be expected to change. However, the manner of change in technology is quite evolutionary and cannot be predicted well. A general principle would be that technological change is a response to the relative cost of the inputs used to produce the good or service. The more expensive an input is, the more likely a technological breakthrough will be achieved to reduce this input cost. For the most part, we will assume that technology is unchanged and inputs produce outputs according to a fixed rule. It will be convenient to think of this fixed rule relating inputs to outputs as a function, in which case we focus on multiple inputs and one output. This function is referred to as the production function. In studying the broad aspects of production, cost, revenue, and profit, one typically looks at two important inputs (labor and capital) and one sees how these are combined by the firm to produce an output for sale. Here we mean machines, tools, equipment, plant, etc. when we used the term capital. Labor is measured in terms of labor hours of employment, while capital is also measured in terms of the time used or employed. It will be simpler if we assume capital is fully utilized at some fixed level. Thus, in the short run, only labor can be varied and thus output will respond entirely to this change in the employment of labor. In fact, this is not how things work in the real world, even in the short run. A firm will always be able to reduce the usage of its capital (i.e. machines and plant) and hence save on its energy costs (another variable factor in the short run we are failing to consider). The firm will not be able to escape the full cost of its capital however. While the cost of labor is a variable wage bill depending on labor hours and the wage rate, capital costs are fixed in the short run regardless of how much of the firm s capital stock is used. Let s take a simple example of a production function in the short run to see how things work. Suppose we let L = labor employed and K = capital employed (fixed). Next, call Y the level of output created using L and K. Suppose further that the relationship between the inputs (L&K) and the output Y is given by Y F( L, K) 100 LK Furthermore, we can just let the fixed level of capital be equal to 1 to simplify things. Therefore, we have Y F( L,1) 100 L We can draw a graph showing this production technology (i.e. production function).

Figure 1 -- A Simple Production Function Note how that in Figure 1 above the level of output rises as L increases, but the rate it rises decreases. The slope of the production function is decreasing as L increases. This is called diminishing marginal productivity of labor. This occurs because we have a fixed level of capital (machines) and therefore as we add more and more labor to a fixed level of machinery we get higher output at a falling rate. Just think of a room as the fixed level of capital and then keep adding more and more workers to the room. Eventually things get pretty crowded and it will be natural that the congestion causes less output to be produced. It may be that these congestion effects do not immediately kick-in. In that case, we can get a graph for our production function that looks like Figure 2 below. Output first rises at an increasing rate and then changes to a decreasing rate. This gives it the distinctive S-shape. Figure 2 -- A Production Function with Delayed Diminishing Marginal Productivity

Both curves, those in Figures 1 and 2, represent the combining of inputs to produce output. In fact, the curve marks the largest output that can be produced using those inputs. The only way to raise the curve upwards is to get more and better capital or find a better way of combining the inputs to produce output. In the short run, we feel this will not happen, or at least will not be significant. The output, Y, being produced may be a service and not a good. For example, in the short run, a taxi ride (measured in distance or time) could be the output. The car used would represent the capital, K, of the firm and the driver s labor time would be labor, L. Technology in this case would be the driving rules and skills that the driver has that are used to start the car, put it in gear, and navigate the best possible route. The roads and bridges are social capital which society provides this firm (not entirely free) and which augment and improve the private capital including the car, gas, motor oil, home base, and communications gear. Production by firms, even simple enterprises, can be quite detailed and complex. What creates order out of this mess of details? The answer is that the consumer is guided by getting the best value for his or her money spent. The firm is similarly guided by producing at optimum levels producing the highest profits to the owners of the firm. But how do we define profit? To answer this, we note that profit is defined as total revenue minus total cost. This can be written as TR TC Consider total revenue first. The firm will sell its output Y at price P. Thus, its total revenue can be written as TR = PY. The firm will not receive any other revenue. That s it. Now, we must turn to cost. Total costs are more complicated. In the short run, some costs are fixed and must be paid regardless of how much output is produced. Produce 1 unit of output or a million units of output, fixed costs do not change. Let s call these costs TFC, for total fixed costs. TFC include things like the rent paid on the buildings used, any interest on debts that have been incurred, the salaries that must be paid to administration, pensions to retirees, depreciation charges on the capital of the firm and well, just about any expense that is unavoidable in the short run. Next, add all costs that depend on the level of production. We call these total variable costs, or TVC. Any expense that depends on how much Y is produced is part of TVC. Think of the wages paid to labor and the cost of raw materials including energy costs. Remember, in the real world, running a fixed number of machines a variable amount of time involves a variable cost due to the energy expended. We will not consider these complications here, but they should be kept in the back of our minds at all time. In simple treatments of cost, we have TFC (interest on the debt of the firm and possibly depreciation charges) and TVC (mainly the wage bill determined by multiplying the wage rate times the number of hours worked). Thus, short run profit can be written as

TR TC PY ( TVC TFC) PY wl rk PF( L, K) wl rk There are numerous problems with this simple formulation (e.g. we have equated nominal and real capital), but let s set these aside to better understand the basic structure of profits. Substituting in our simple example of a production function we have PF( L, K) wl rk P L wl r We have drawn this profit function in Figure 3 below (using Wolfram Alpha to plot the profit function) where P = 10, w = 2, and r = 5. Figure 3 The Profit Function for F( L,1) L Note that maximum profit, the highest point on the graph in Figure 3, occurs at a level of employment of labor, L = 25/4 = 6.25. You can see this again by using your phone and Wolfram Alpha. Here is the way you do it.

You will also see this after it computes the roots This means that profit maximizing production occurs where Y 6.25 2.5. Total revenue will be TR = PY = (10)(2.5) = 25 and total cost will be TC = TVC + TFC = (2)(2.5) + 5 = 10. Profit = π = TR TC = 25 10 = 15. We can conceivably do the process above for any type of production process. We can also make it more complicated and complete by adding other factors in addition to labor and capital. The basic logic remains. We are determining the level of output that produces the highest profit and we are relating this outcome to the price of the product and the level of the wage rate. In fact, the production function we have chosen allows us to write the short run supply curve for any level of price and wages. How can we do that? Maximization of profit can be written as ( L) P L wl TFC At the point of maximum profit, it should be true that raising or lowering the level of L should result in no change in the profit (since we are at the top of the profit curve in Figure 3. Now we know that Y L which means that 2 Y L. This implies that 2Y Y L and therefore

Y 1 when Y L it is true that L 2 L changes in L at the maximum point.. It is easy now to see how that profits change with Y 1 P w 0 L 2 L 2 * P So, the optimum level of labor is easily seen to be L and the supply of Y is 2 4w * P Y L. Of course, given a fixed wage and variable price P, the supply curve is easy to 2w draw. Note how that a rise in the wage rate reduces supply, just as we would have supposed. Lastly we might want to ask why there are profits? Why not simply distribute profits to labor? The usual explanation for profits is that before one enters the market there must be an incentive to invest and risk one s wealth in a business. Labor does not risk its wealth. Of course, a laborer can at anytime lose his or her job, but they nevertheless retain the wealth they have. It is only when they take their own capital and invest it in the business that they are subject to the same risk as the owner. The riskier the business the more profit will be required for the owner to risk part of his wealth. Remember that in modern economies, investors include huge pension funds and insurance companies managing the small funds of literally millions of people. It is the small investors that require a compensation of the risk they take on. Not all wealth is so concentrated as is sometimes asserted. Billions of dollars in insurance and pension funds may be concentrated in a relatively small number of owners of an insurance company or investment fund, but these funds are not real net wealth. They only represent assets covering enormous liabilities and potential payouts. To truly understand the distribution of wealth and thus risk, one must look at the distribution of liabilities as well. Profits are the compensation for the risking of one s wealth and everyone with wealth understands this. (P1) What is the definition of profit? (P2) What is the definition of total revenue? (P3) Why are there fixed and variable costs in total cost? (P4) Give an example of a variable cost. Now do the same for fixed cost. (P5) What is a production function and what are the usual factors we find in production? (P6) Why do we have profits in business? P (P7) Draw the supply curve Y where w = 3. 2w