An Equilibrium Model of the Crash

Similar documents
10. Dealers: Liquid Security Markets

Should we fear derivatives? By Rene M Stulz, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Summer 2004

Journal of Applied Corporate Finance

WHAT S HAPPENING IN THE STOCK MARKETS

Overview. Stanley Fischer

Expectations and market microstructure when liquidity is lost

Binary Options Trading Strategies How to Become a Successful Trader?

Notes 6: Examples in Action - The 1990 Recession, the 1974 Recession and the Expansion of the Late 1990s

Oxford Energy Comment March 2009

The Efficient Market Hypothesis

Private Information I

Reference-Dependent Preferences with Expectations as the Reference Point

Economics 103 Summer II 2014 International Monetary Relations. Problem Set 3. August 28, Thu, Thu, September 4, before 2:00pm

Derivation of zero-beta CAPM: Efficient portfolios

Prof. Bryan Caplan Econ 812

Racial Discrimination in Mortgage Lending Is There a Problem Here?

Economics of Money, Banking, and Fin. Markets, 10e

Do Changes in Asset Prices Denote Changes in Wealth? When stock or bond prices drop sharply we are told that the nation's wealth has

II. Determinants of Asset Demand. Figure 1

Effect of Health on Risk Tolerance and Stock Market Behavior

THE EFFECT OF LIQUIDITY COSTS ON SECURITIES PRICES AND RETURNS

Normalizing Monetary Policy

Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 17 Sections 17.1 and 17.2 Asymmetric information can cause a competitive equilibrium allocation to be inefficient.

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits

The Goods Market and the Aggregate Expenditures Model

International Finance. Investment Styles. Campbell R. Harvey. Duke University, NBER and Investment Strategy Advisor, Man Group, plc.

Market Resiliency: Evidence from Money Market Mutual Fund Reform

The Structure of the Federal Reserve System

Thoughts about the Outlook

Module 19 Equilibrium in the Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply Model

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Outlook for the Chilean Economy

The Productivity to Paycheck Gap: What the Data Show

FIN 355 Behavioral Finance.

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 55

Reforming the Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy in China

Effect of Trading Halt System on Market Functioning: Simulation Analysis of Market Behavior with Artificial Shutdown *

Business Analysis for Engineers Prof. S. Vaidhyasubramaniam Adjunct Professor, School of Law SASTRA University-Thanjavur

Disclaimer: <b>disclaimer:</b> All rights reserved to MTE-Media.

Consumption. Basic Determinants. the stream of income

UNCERTAINTY AND INFORMATION

Online Appendix for Overpriced Winners

A BOND MARKET IS-LM SYNTHESIS OF INTEREST RATE DETERMINATION

PART THREE. Answers to End-of-Chapter Questions and Problems

chapter: Savings, Investment Spending, and the Financial System Krugman/Wells 1 of Worth Publishers

Fundamental Analysis is the study of Financial Statements and Ratios which help evaluate a company s overall Value and Growth potential.

ECON Microeconomics II IRYNA DUDNYK. Auctions.

TWO VIEWS OF THE ECONOMY

PAPER No.14 : Security Analysis and Portfolio Management MODULE No.24 : Efficient market hypothesis: Weak, semi strong and strong market)

Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply

Forex Illusions - 6 Illusions You Need to See Through to Win

Shyam Sunder, Yale University

Implications of the Bank Stress Tests

AFM 371 Winter 2008 Chapter 14 - Efficient Capital Markets

Christiano 362, Winter 2006 Lecture #3: More on Exchange Rates More on the idea that exchange rates move around a lot.

How to Graph Short-Run Phillips Curves

THE SHORT-RUN TRADEOFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

A Short Perspective: Mutual Fund Growth in the US and Globally, and Reassuring Lessons during Periods of Stock Market Turmoil

COMMENTS ON SESSION 1 AUTOMATIC STABILISERS AND DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY. Adi Brender *

Chapter 19: Compensating and Equivalent Variations

KiwiSaver advice. 7 November This guidance note is for advisers and. financial firms advising on KiwiSaver products.

Corporate Exposure to Exchange Rates

Problem Set Suggested Answers. These answers were thought out as a guide of what a correct answer could have been. Do not consider them exhaustive.

Money & Capital Markets Exam 1: Chapters 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 & 6. Name. Multiple Choice: 4 points each

Remarks by James K. Galbraith at the Economists for Peace and. Security Bernard Schwartz Symposium on Jobs, Investment and Energy.

10 AGGREGATE SUPPLY AND AGGREGATE DEMAND* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Aggregate Supply1

Chapter 13: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis

Low Inflation and the Symmetry of the 2 Percent Target

EXAMPLE OF FAILURE OF EQUILIBRIUM Akerlof's market for lemons (P-R pp )

Assessing Client Risk: A Two-Dimensional Approach

Commentary on 'Exchange Rate Volatility and Misalignment: Evaluating Some Proposals for Reform'

Economic Outlook, January 2015 January 9, Jeffrey M. Lacker President Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Ian Macfarlane: Economic developments at home and abroad

Shiller versus Siegel: Are Stocks Too High?

CHAPTER TWENTY-SEVEN BASIC MACROECONOMIC RELATIONSHIPS

The Financial System. Sherif Khalifa. Sherif Khalifa () The Financial System 1 / 52

15 Week 5b Mutual Funds

Forex Trader Job Description

SHORT SELLING. Menachem Brenner and Marti G. Subrahmanyam

Accounting for Employee Stock Options

So let s get into the meat of the matter. Here s how you are going to become the most successful and profitable Forex trader you know.

Working Paper No China s Structural Adjustment from the Income Distribution Perspective

The Economy, Inflation, and Monetary Policy

Kevin Christ Associate Professor of Economics Rose-Hulman Institute of Technology. How s it going? An appraisal of the current economic recovery

Goal-Based Monetary Policy Report 1

The Government s Plan to Revitalize the KOSDAQ Market: Post-announcement Market Conditions and Challenges Ahead

Discounting the Benefits of Climate Change Policies Using Uncertain Rates

Since the commercials have always succeeded in the past in rigging prices low

Objectives for Chapter 24: Monetarism (Continued) Chapter 24: The Basic Theory of Monetarism (Continued) (latest revision October 2004)

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Macroeconomics. Based on the textbook by Karlin and Soskice: Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial System

Do Leveraged ETFs Increase Volatility

Do We Invest with Our Hearts or Minds? How Behavioral Finance Can Dramatically Affect Your Wealth

In this model, the value of the stock today is the present value of the expected cash flows (equal to one dividend payment plus a final sales price).

Expectations are very important in our financial system.

Technical analysis & Charting The Foundation of technical analysis is the Chart.

INFLATION, JOBS, AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE*

PAGE 42 THE STERN STEWART INSTITUTE PERIODICAL #10 JAMES GORMAN: NAVIGATING THE CHANGING LANDSCAPE OF FINANCE

Transcription:

Fischer Black An Equilibrium Model of the Crash 1. Summary Presented in this paper is a view of the market break on October 19, 1987 that fits much of what we know. I assume that investors' tastes changed before the crash, and that their beliefs changed both before and during the crash. Before the crash, investors' tastes became more and more flexible. (Their tastes are "flexible" if they become more risk tolerant with rising wealth.) Also before the crash, investors' estimates of mean reversion grew much more slowly than actual mean reversion, so that the bias in their estimates increased. ("Mean reversion" is a change in expected return that moves in the opposite direction from a change in the market level after that change occurs.) In this view, the major trigger for the crash was the sudden awareness that actual mean reversion was higher than investors thought. This realization caused them to reduce their expected return estimates for markets around the world. Prices fell until expected returns were high enough that investors were willing to hold the existing supplies of common stocks. The turmoil that followed led investors to cut back their willingness to hold stocks at given expected returns, which pulled down the market's equilibrium level even more. 2. What Happenedl On October 19, 1987, the U.S. stock market showed its largest percentage decline on record for a single day. Other world stock market showed large declines, too. Volatility rose sharply and market maker spreads widened dramatically. No sensational headline triggered the break. Some have pointed to the progress of legislation in creating tax barriers to takeovers, and indeed takeover candidates did decline more than other stocks on October 19. But 1. These events are reported in Brady, et al. (1988).

270 BLACK. this may have been due to the crash itself. Any large decline will increase the chance that an announced or prospective takeover deal will fall through.2 There were a few very large sellers on October 19. It seems that all of them were using dynamic strategies that call for increasing stock holdings after the market goes up, and decreasing stock holdings after the market goes down. Mutual funds were using these strategies because their shareholders were using them. Some of these strategies are called "portfolio insurance." A number of large investors adopted portfolio insurance in the months and years before October 19. Many of them used futures contracts to change their market exposure. During the week of the 19th, futures prices went far below their theoretical values just when portfolio insurers wanted to sell. As a result, many managers dropped their portfolio insurance strategies on October 19th, or in the weeks that followed.3 3. Dynamic Strategies A dynamic strategy is any strategy that changes exposure to the market after changes in the market level. We can use the term "portfolio insurance" to describe a strategy where buying and selling are consistently related to market moves. An investor who consistently buys after a market rise and sells after a market fall is "buying" portfolio insurance. The reverse activity is "selling" portfolio insurance.4 Portfolio insurance sellers must exist to balance portfolio insurance buyers. The sellers may call themselves "value investors," or users of "dividend discount models," or "tactical asset allocators." But whatever name is used, someone must sell portfolio insurance if anyone is to buy it. When we analyze the behavior of the market, we often speak of the "typical investor." We say, for example, that the market acts as if the typical investor were risk averse. A model with only one class of investor may be easier to understand than a model with two or more classes. But, the typical investor cannot use a dynamic strategy. In equilibrium, he maintains his position; he neither buys nor sells. 2. Shiller (1987) reports that most investors reacted more to the crash itself than to outside news. 3. "66% Drop in Portfolio Insurance." Pensions and Investment Age, January 25, 1988, p. 2. 4. Brennan and Schwartz (1988), Brignoli (1988), Kling (1988), Leland (1987), Rubinstein (1988), and Shiller (1988) discuss the relationship between portfolio insurance and the crash. Their analyses are similar to mine, except that they generally assume that one group of investors is optimizing, while another group is using dynamic strategies. In my analysis, all investors act alike.

4. Flexible Tastes 1987 Stock Market Crash 271? In a model with several classes of investors, differences in taste for risk will not cause any of them to use dynamic strategies. We need investors whose tastes for risk increase with wealth at different rates.5 We will say that an investor whose taste for risk increases rapidly with wealth has more "flexible" tastes than one whose taste increases less rapidly. Investors with more flexible tastes will buy portfolio insurance, while those with less flexible tastes will sell portfolio insurance, all else equal. Even though the typical investor is neither a buyer nor a seller of portfolio insurance, he can have more or less flexible tastes. A change in the typical investor's tastes will affecthe market equilibrium. 5. Mean Reversion The market's "mean reversion" is the change in the market's expected return following a change in the market level. It is measured by the negative of the percentage point change in expected return per percentage point return in the market. The change in the market level may cause the change in expected return, or the change in expected return may cause the change in the market level. Causation flows in both directions. The change in expected return associated with a change in the market need not be permanent. In fact, it is likely to disappear over time if there is no other change in the market. I believe that there is normally considerable mean reversion in the market-but it's very hard to estimate how much.6 And it is doubly hard to detect a change in the market's mean reversion by looking only at stock returns. A long series of stock returns tells us mostly about the average expected return and the average mean reversion over the period. 6. Equilibrium In this model, the factor that moves to bring the market into equilibrium is mean reversion. The inputs to the model are investors' tastes for risk and 5. Leland (1980) shows that investors with rapidly increasing taste for risk will be more likely to use portfolio insurance than other investors. 6. Fama and French (1986) and Poterba and Summers (1987) try to estimate the average mean reversion in the market. French, Schwert, and Stambaugh (1987) estimate mean reversion indirectly: they relate expected return to volatility, and volatility is negatively related to past return. Merton (1980) shows how difficult it is to find the exact relation between expected return and volatility. A similar argument would show how difficult it is to find the exact relation between expected return and market level. Black (1986) discusses observable and unobservable variables in general.

272. BLACK their beliefs about mean reversion. All else equal, when investors have more flexible tastes, actual mean reversion will be greater. Likewise, when the downward bias in investors' beliefs about mean reversion is bigger, actual mean reversion will be greater. In fact, we may have a lot of trouble distinguishing the effects of tastes and beliefs about the equilibrium. More flexible tastes and a larger bias in beliefs about mean reversion will have similar or identical effects on the equilibrium. In this model, a small shift in tastes can have a large impact on actual mean reversion and volatility. Suppose that investors' beliefs about mean reversion remain constant, while their tastes for risk become more flexible. There will be no equilibrium. Actual mean reversion cannot be high enough to create equlibrium. What brings the market to equilibrium is the fact that beliefs about mean reversion must eventually change. As actual mean reversion rises, it will become clear that the bias in investors' beliefs about mean reversion is large. Thus a shifto more flexible tastes must give an increase in expected mean reversion, though there may still be a difference between actual and expected mean reversion. 7. The Crash Stock prices declined sharply on a day when there were no major headlines. In the absence of big news in the ordinary sense, the price decline may have reflected changing interpretations of past news or changing tastes for risk. If investors had become more risk averse, their reaction would have made prices drop. The big sellers were using dynamic strategies, which suggests that the decline was at least accelerated by them. The increasing use of dynamic strategies was a signal that the typical investor's tastes or beliefs had been changing. To me, the most important fact in sorting through the story behind October 19 is the termination of portfolio insurance strategies after the crash. That suggests that the crash was not triggered solely by news plus the normal operation of dynamic strategies. Instead investors' beliefs, especially those of large investors using dynamic strategies, changed. Here is a story that I find plausible: In the months leading up to October 19, investors' tastes were changing. They were becoming more flexible. This led to a moderate increase in volatility while the market was rising, whereas normally volatility falls when the market rises.7 As investors' tastes became more flexible, the market's mean reversion increased. But the typical investor's expected mean reversion increased less. As the market rose during 1986 and 1987, 7. Black (1976) looks at the relation between market return and volatility change.

1987 Stock Market Crash 273. the true expected return on the market was falling, but investors thought it was falling less. This means the market rose more than it would have if they had seen the expected return clearly. By the morning of October 19, investors had become aware of how the typical investor's tastes had changed. Some people had added up the assets used in portfolio insurance strategies and realized that lots of sell orders were due that day. The market's behavior during the day gave further clues to the typical investor's tastes. As investors became aware that the typical investor had more flexible tastes than they thought, they increased their estimates of the market's mean reversion and reduced their estimates of the market's expected return. This made them less willing to hold stocks. The market fell sharply. As estimates of expected return fell for the U.S. market, they fell for other world markets. Equilibrium could be restored only after world markets fell. The decline increased estimates of expected return again, to the point where investors were willing to hold existing quantities of common stock. What makes this story consistent with equilibrium, in my view, is that expected return and mean reversion are both unobservable. It is very hard to estimateither one of them. So investors can have incorrect beliefs about these factors without violating normal equilibrium conditions. The story is not consistent with rational expectations, but standard statistical tests won't show this, because investors can do those same tests. The clues that lead us to believe that investors' tastes had become more flexible could not have been derived from observing the path of the stock market alone. Note that the equilibrium I describe is fragile.8 A small change in tastes or beliefs gives a large change in mean reversion and volatility. This is consistent with the fact that only a small proportion of investors had adopted formal portfolio insurance strategies, and their trading played a mino role in the market activity of October 19. 8. Noise Trading This can be viewed as a noise trading story.9 Noise traders, as I define them, trade on noise as if it were news. An example would be buying stock on news that has already been discounted in the price. There is no general way of finding out whether a given piece of news has been discounted. That fact is unobservable, in the same sense that expected return or mean reversion are unobservable. 8. Kling (1988) has another model with fragilequilibria. Both models may have played a role in the crash. Leland (1987) describes a fragil equilibrium model related to mine. 9. It seems consistent with the story told by De Long, et al. (1987).

274 - BLACK In this model, the noise is the bias in estimated mean reversion. Though we have direct evidence of a change in tastes, the market's volatility could just as well have been caused by a change in the bias. Probably, it was a mix of a change in tastes and a change in the bias. 9. The Psychological Factor There is one more elementhat may play a part in an equilibriu model of the crash: psychology. The level of the market is affected by the public's confidence in the market and the breadth of its participation. The market will be higher when participation is broad instead of narrow. When more people are willing to share in the risk of the market, each one bears less risk. This means tha the expected return on the market can be lower and the market level higher. We might call this element "liquidity." Liquidity often refers to the breadth of interest a specific stock. When a stock has a liquid market, you can buy or sell a relatively large amount in a relatively shor time without affecting the price too much. Here we are applying a similar concepto the market as a whole. When there is broad public participation in the stock market, the level of the market will be high, and a change in one group's desired holdings won't cause a big change in price; other groups will take up the slack. Such a market will be less volatile than one with narrow participation, all else equal. The problem is that breadth of participation is affected by things that are hard to capture in a model. This is what I mean by "the psychological factor." People may avoid trading because they have little confidence in the market. They may feel that the market is "too volatile;" that it may close unexpectedly just when they want to trade; that it may be so congested at high volume times that trading will be hard; or that traders with computers have an unfair advantage. Feelings that have no apparent factual basis can affect liquidity too. An increase in volatility can scare people off, even when it is due to a change in tastes or technology. Since the causes of volatility are not observable, even economists may decide that an increase is capricious, and they may urge investors to be cautious. Whatever the original reasons for the crash, it frightened people. The sharp decline, the high volatility, the mispriced securities, and the congestion caused people to withdraw from the market. This led to a decline in the equilibrium level of the markethat was greater than the decline a model would have figured-unless it accounted for the psychological factor.

1987 Stock Market Crash - 275 REFERENCES Black, F. 1976. Studies of stock price volatility changes. Proceedings of the 1976 Meetings of the American Statistical Association, Business, and Economics Section, 177-181. Black, F. 1986. Noise. Journal of Finance 41: 529-543. Brady, N. F., et al. 1988. Report of the Presidential Task Force on Market Mechanisms. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. Brennan, M. J., and E. S. Schwartz. 1988. Portfolio insurance and financial market equilibrium. Mimeo. Brignoli, R. 1988. Portfolio insurance and the deterministic event. Investment Management Review 2: 20-26. De Long, J. Bradford, A. Schleifer, L. H. Summers, and R. J. Waldmann. 1987. The economic consequences of noise traders. Mimeo. Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1988. Permanent and temporary components of stock prices. Journal of Political Economy 95. 96: 246-273. French, K. R., G. W. Schwert, and R. F. Stambaugh. 1987. Expected stock returns and volatility. Journal of Financial Economics 19: 3-29. Kling, A. 1988. Fragile equilibria. Mimeo. Leland, H. E. 1987. On the stock market crash and portfolio insurance. Mimeo. Leland, H. E. 1980. Who should buy portfolio insurance? Journal of Finance 35: 581-596. Merton, R. C. 1980. On estimating the expected return on the market: An exploratory investigation. Journal of Financial Economics 8: 323-361. Poterba, J. M., and L. H. Summers. 1987. Mean reversion in stock prices: Evidence and implications. Mimeo. Rubinstein, M. 1988. Portfolio insurance and the market crash. Financial Analysts Journal 44: 38-47. Shiller, R. J. 1987. Investor behavior in the October 1987 stock market crash: Survey evidence. Mimeo. Shiller, R. J. 1988. Portfolio insurance and other investor fashions as factors in the 1987 stock market crash. Mimeo.