Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation

Similar documents
Introductory remarks by Thomas Jordan

Hong Kong s Fiscal Issues

How Successful is China s Economic Rebalancing?*

Jean-Pierre Roth: Recent economic and financial developments in Switzerland

Meeting with Analysts

Meeting with Analysts

Antonio Fazio: Overview of global economic and financial developments in first half 2004

Implications of Fiscal Austerity for U.S. Monetary Policy

CRS Report for Congress

Economic Projections :1

ECFIN/C-1 Fourth quarter 2000

Gauging Current Conditions:

Structural Changes in the Maltese Economy

BANK OF FINLAND ARTICLES ON THE ECONOMY

Canada s Economic Future: What Have We Learned from the 1990s?

CRS Report for Congress

Structural changes in the Maltese economy

The Federal Budget: Sources of the Movement from Surplus to Deficit

Macroeconomic and financial market developments. March 2014

REPORT ON THE B ALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Macroeconomic and financial market developments. February 2014

FOREWORD THE JAPANESE CAPITAL MARKETS

1. Inflation target policy how does it work?

DEVELOPING COUNTRIES AND THE DOLLAR. C. P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh

Maneuvering Past Stagflation: Prospects for the U.S. Economy In

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES

The expansion of the U.S. economy continued for the fourth consecutive

INFLATION AND THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK By Darryl R. Francis, President. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

WikiLeaks Document Release

FISCAL POLICY* Chapt er. Key Concepts

Minutes of the Monetary Policy Committee meeting, August 2016

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Trade Deficits; Currency Manipulation

The Forex Market in March 2007

Economic Outlook, January 2015 January 9, Jeffrey M. Lacker President Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

How costly is for Spain to be in the EURO?

The international environment

Midsummer Examinations 2013

PubPol 201. Module 1: International Trade Policy. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Class 3 Outline. Definitions. Definitions. Class 3

Atradius Country Report

Normalizing Monetary Policy

This is Policy Effects with Floating Exchange Rates, chapter 10 from the book Policy and Theory of International Finance (index.html) (v. 1.0).

Corporate and Household Sectors in Austria: Subdued Growth of Indebtedness

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast June 2014

Economic Outlook, January 2016 Jeffrey M. Lacker President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

FIRST LOOK AT MACROECONOMICS*

Czech monetary policy: On a way to neutral interest rates

Economic projections

1. Which one of the following is NOT an example of the use of government fiscal policy? A change in

The Exchange Rate and Canadian Inflation Targeting

CRS Report for Congress

Eurozone. EY Eurozone Forecast September 2014

5+1 charts on how Hungary can catch up with France

Monthly Bulletin of Economic Trends: Review of the Australian Economy

Fiscal Dimensions of Inflationist Monetary Policy. Marvin Goodfriend Carnegie Mellon University and National Bureau of Economic Research

Asia/Pacific Economic Overview

Making the Right Investments Now Is Key to Future Productivity

1 World Economy. Value of Finnish Forest Industry Exports Fell by Almost a Quarter in 2009

BCC UK Economic Forecast Q4 2015

TREASURY AND FEDERAL RESERVE FOREIGN EXCHANGE OPERATIONS

DEVELOPMENTS IN THE COST COMPETITIVENESS OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, THE UNITED STATES AND JAPAN MAIN FEATURES

INTERMEDIATE OPEN ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS - WINTER

The Conduct of Monetary Policy

Economic Policy Objectives and Trade-Offs

The real change in private inventories added 0.22 percentage points to the second quarter GDP growth, after subtracting 0.65% in the first quarter.

China: The Long and Short of Economic Reform

Investment Insights. International Strategy: Understanding Currency Movements

Fallacies Behind the RMB Predictions

II. Underlying domestic macroeconomic imbalances fuelled current account deficits

ABSTRACT. Exchange Rates and Macroeconomic Policy with Income-sensitive Capital Flows. J.O.N. Perkins, University of Melbourne

FISCAL COUNCIL OPINION ON THE SUMMER FORECAST 2018 OF THE MINISTRY OF FINANCE

Ten Lessons Learned from the Korean Crisis Center for International Development, 11/19/99. Jeffrey A. Frankel, Harpel Professor, Harvard University

Erdem Başçi: Recent economic and financial developments in Turkey

Analysis of CBO s Budget Outlook: Fiscal Years

Appendix: Analysis of Exchange Rates Pursuant to the Act

China quarterly real GDP growth (year on year %)

Economic Projections :2

Other similar crisis: Euro, Emerging Markets

The U.S. Current Account Balance and the Business Cycle

The Economic Situation of the European Union and the Outlook for

PROJECT LINK FALL MEETING NEW YORK, OCTOBER 2015 COUNTRY REPORT : SWITZERLAND

Philip Lowe: Changing relative prices and the structure of the Australian economy

Estimating Key Economic Variables: The Policy Implications

CRS Report for Congress

15 th. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson. First page. edition Gwartney Stroup Sobel Macpherson

China s Currency: A Summary of the Economic Issues

Global Imbalances and the U.S. Current Account Deficit. Economics 826 January 2009

Bruce Greenwald: The Crisis Bigger than Global Warming

Global Imbalances and Current Account Imbalances

Economic ProjEctions for

Fund Management Diary

Fallacies Behind the RMB Predictions

Report Documentation Page Form Approved OMB No Public reporting burden for the collection of information is estimated to average 1 hour per re

ISRAEL. Economic and Financial Review. Summary. Portfolio Strategy. February 7,2013 / Issue No. 268

o c t o b e r H-1054 BUDAPEST, SZABADSÁG TÉR 9.

The grass is greener to the East

COMMENTARY NUMBER 462 June Trade Balance, Consumer Credit. August 9, Bernanke Bemoans GDP Not Reflecting Common Experience

Lars Heikensten: Monetary policy and the economic situation

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY IS THE DOLLAR SO HIGH? Martin Feldstein. Working Paper

Minutes of the Monetary Policy Council decision-making meeting held on 2 September 2015

Lars Heikensten: The Swedish economy and monetary policy

Transcription:

Learning the Right Lessons from the Current Account Deficit and Dollar Appreciation Alan C. Stockman Wilson Professor of Economics University of Rochester 716-275-7214 http://www.stockman.net alan@stockman.net Prepared for the Shadow Open Market Committee Meeting November 13 th, 2000.

1 United States trade and current-account deficits have risen sharply in recent years. The current account deficit reached 4.27 percent of GDP in the second quarter of 2000, and will probably exceed that slightly in the third quarter. The U.S. trade deficit reached 4.06 percent of GDP in the second quarter of 2000 and grew slightly to 4.08 percent of GDP in the third quarter. Despite rapid growth in GDP, trade and current account deficits have risen even faster. Meanwhile, the dollar has appreciated against most major currencies in the past two years, rising about 30% against the Euro, and rising by 10% to 20% against many other currencies (including the British pound, the Australian dollar, the New Zealand dollar, and the Swiss franc). In contrast to the prognosticators' claims, repeated for more than a decade, that U.S. currentaccount deficits would lead to dollar depreciation, the evidence refuses to cooperate with their predictions. It is time for a new look at the lessons to be learned from the current account and the exchange rate, and their implications for U.S. economic policy. Under some circumstances, current-account deficits can signal economic problems that call for changes in economic policies. However, current account deficits at best provide mixed and ambiguous evidence about appropriate economic policy changes because the current account agglomerates a large array of underlying economic factors. Current-account deficits sometimes result from new investment opportunities created by technical change, leading countries to engage in net borrowing on world markets to finance those investments. At other times, current-account deficits result from reductions in net national savings rates, due to changes in consumer confidence that lead to changes in consumer expenditures, or due to changes in tax rates that affect after-tax savings rates, or due to changes in government fiscal positions that affect national savings. U.S. current-account deficits today, as for the past two decades, reflect three main factors. Two of these factors have important implications for economic policies; though neither involves monetary policy directly. These factors are (1) increases in investment opportunities in the United States; (2) low rates of (conventionally-measured) saving in the United States; and

2 (3) economic disruptions and distortions in other countries, ranging from the Asian financial crises to the deep structural problems that continue to haunt the European economies. Analysts have repeatedly misinterpreted current-account deficits and misread their lessons for economic policy. Beginning in the 1980s, it became popular to claim that the U.S. current-account deficit was the direct result of the rising U.S. government budget deficit. This twin-deficits view became dominant in academic papers, conferences, policy analyses, and media reports. However, the twin-deficits claim was incorrect. The claim started to become less common in public pronouncements after U.S. government budget deficits began to decline in 1984 without a corresponding decline in the current account deficit, but it remained the dominant view nonetheless. The twin-deficits view became obviously untenable only as rapid economic growth, reductions in government purchases (mainly on defense), and tax increases have eliminated budget deficits and created budget surpluses, without any major impact on the current-account deficit. What is, then, responsible for the current-account deficits, reaching $331 billion in 1999, that the United States has experienced since 1982 (with the sole exception of a $4 billion surplus in 1991)? What lessons for economic policy did the United States miss, and fail to learn, by clinging incorrectly to the twin-deficits view? The main factor behind U.S. current account deficits lies in the robust economic growth that the United States has experienced for nearly two decades, beginning with recovery from the 1982 recession, and with the sole exception of the 1990-91 recession. Indeed, 1990-1991 marks the only time since 1981 that the U.S. has experienced a current-account surplus. (All the while, large federal budget deficits continued, increasing in 1990 and 1991 as the currentaccount deficit fell.) Note that the current-account deficit results from rapid U.S. economic growth; it does not hinder that growth. Quite the contrary: the ability of the United States to borrow on international markets (that is, to run current account deficits) enhances U.S. economic growth by allocating resources efficiently and providing lower-cost financing for investment.

3 Current accounts involve intertemporal trade -- a U.S. current-account deficit means that the U.S. trades claims on its future production for current goods and services. Commentators often suggest that a current-account deficit threatens future economic problems if current spending falls on consumption rather than investment. That is not the case in the United States today, where current-account deficits have financed an investment boom. Even if those deficits were to finance consumption spending, however, there would be little reason to regard them as problems. After all, the current-account would be merely the symptom of some underlying problem, not its cause. The root problem, if there were one, would lie in the choices that people and business firms made on consumption vs. savings, and on investment in new capital. Of course, there is no a priori reason to regard consumption spending as bad and investment spending as good. After all, the main point of the economy is to provide consumption. Investment is merely a means toward the goal of even more consumption, at the cost of its postponement. Economic efficiency requires, that the intertemporal tradeoffs that consumers (and business firms) face when they make their consumption and investment decisions reflect the available intertemporal opportunities. However, economic policies affect the extent to which these tradeoffs and opportunities diverge, and thereby the efficiency with which the economy operates and the rate at which it grows. As a matter of pure accounting, we can divide factors affect the U.S. current-account deficit into those affecting investment in the United States and those reflecting national savings. The major factor responsible for the deficit is the high rate of investment in the United States. A secondary factor is the low (measured) U.S. savings rate. Evidence over many countries and time periods shows that growth rates of exports and imports are procyclical, rising and falling with the growth rate of real GDP. However, exports typically vary less than imports; consequently, the trade deficit is distinctly procyclical. Trade and current account deficits, as shares of GDP, rise and fall with the growth rate of GDP. Given the strong investment-led growth of the U.S. economy, resulting from rapid technical change that has increased productivity and opened a vast spectrum of new investment opportunities, it would be very

4 surprising if the United States did not have large trade deficits. Although investment has been the main factor behind U.S. current-account deficits, it is not the sole factor. The personal savings rates in the United States, which has been low for many years, fell from 2.2 percent of disposable income in 1999 to an average of 0.1 percent over the first three quarters of 2000. Two factors affect the inferences that should be drawn from these savings data. First, government budget surpluses have helped to offset the effects on national savings of the fall in personal savings. Second, the measured personal savings significantly misstates relevant personal savings by ignoring changes in the market value of existing capital (mainly through stock-market swings). Those valuation changes also imply that standard measures of investment misstate economically-relevant investment. Nevertheless, the low personal savings rate in the United States serves as one indicator of the (potentially large) economic inefficiencies created by the current U.S. tax system and social-security system. Economists widely agree that taxation of savings and investment income creates economic inefficiency and should be replaced by taxes that fall more on consumption; they also widely agree that the social security system has, as a pay-as-you-go system, reduces personal and national savings. Changes in these policies would raise national savings, reducing the current account deficit while adding to U.S. investment, reduce economic distortions and inefficiencies, and raise the long-run U.S. capital stock and U.S. GDP. While U.S. current-account deficits result partly from U.S. conditions and policies, they also reflect conditions and policies in other countries. Structural economic problems in Europe and, more recently, slow economic growth in Japan, have contributed to the U.S. current account deficit. Those factors have also contributed to appreciation of the U.S. dollar on foreign exchange markets. That result has surprised many analysts. After all, the European central bank has apparently succeeded in establishing its ability to pursue its mandate and to establish goals of low inflation and a stable monetary environment. Nevertheless, the Euro has fallen from a high of $1.20 in January 1999 to recent lows below $0.85. Moreover, the exchange rate has resisted any long-lived response to concerted central bank intervention (as

5 expected from evidence on previous interventions in foreign exchange markets around the world). The appreciation of the U.S. dollar in terms of the Euro, and many other currencies, has not reflected inflation differentials between United States and those countries. Nor does it reflect expected future inflation differentials. The rise of the dollar in terms of the Euro reflects four main factors. First, the United States has experienced faster economic growth in Europe, and markets expect this difference in the rate of economic growth to continue in the future. Evidence indicates that international differences in rates of economic growth, by themselves, are not strongly associated with changes in exchange rates. However, a second factor involves the source of this growth differential -- more rapid technical progress and productivity growth in the United States. The difference in rates of economic growth between the United States and Europe has been associated with differences in productivity and aggregate supply, rather than differences in aggregate demand. The relatively greater degree of economic freedom in United States, as compared to Europe, and the associated difference in economic flexibility and opportunity for pursuing innovation, has made the United States a relatively more attractive location for real investment. This has been the major factor behind U.S. current-account deficits. It has also helped to prevent the U.S. dollar from depreciating in response to faster U.S. growth (and the associated increase in the relative supply of American goods and services). The third major factor involves the stagnation of European policy reforms and continuation of a European legal and regulatory infrastructure that raises costs of production, reduces economic flexibility, inhibits risk-taking and entrepreneurship, and discourages innovation and growth. High unemployment rates in Europe are one visible symptom of these problems. The fourth and most important factor involves the greater risks that investors must take to invest in Europe rather than the United States. These risks are associated less with normal ECB policies than with fiscal and regulatory policies, and the ultimate responses of the ECB to

6 the possibility of a European recession. Increases in the relative risk of European investments, as compared to U.S. investments, have led financial markets to reduce the value of the Euro to a level at which investors holding Euro-denominated assets take less risk of additional depreciation and are compensated by a greater possibility of appreciation. This development implies that the Euro is not likely to rise until markets perceive a fall in the risks they would take on European investments, or until changes in U.S. economic conditions lead to in increase in the risks of investments in the United States. This lesson has important implications for U.S. economic policy. Some analysts have argued that the combination of more rapid U.S. economic growth, a current-account deficit, and an appreciating U.S. dollar shows that U.S. economic growth has been fueled by aggregate demand rather than by aggregate supply. Productivity increases alone, they argue, would lead to greater U.S. output, a U.S. trade surplus, and a fall in the relative price of American products through real dollar depreciation. If that scenario were true, then the Federal Reserve might rightly concern itself with the implications for inflation of those increases in aggregate demand. However, productivity increases in the United States have not taken the simple form of a greater supply of American-made products. Instead, technical change and entrepreneurship in United States have increased investment opportunities in United States, raising real U.S. investment by more than the increases in supplies of American-made products. This has resulted in a sustained U.S. current-account deficit without dollar depreciation, and with the recent appreciation. Consequently, the strength of the dollar and the persistence of current-account deficits are not reasons to alter U.S. monetary policy. Instead, they signal strong U.S. economic performance and a monetary policy that has not hindered it. If robust U.S. economic growth continues over the long term, the future production that will be required to finance the U.S. international debt position, that will have resulted from its current-account deficits, will not prevent rapid growth in U.S. consumption. Markets currently expect those increases, as indicated by the performance of the stock market, rapid consumption growth, and a low savings rate. Monetary policy can best contribute to continued long-run

7 economic growth by creating an environment with a stable price level or a low, and predictable, rate of inflation, and by using all means at its disposal to ensure that it will continue to provide that environment in the future. It is easy to draw incorrect inferences from international trade deficits and changes in exchange rates, because a large set of factors influence them and isolating those individual factors can be difficult. Nevertheless, evidence clearly indicates the fallacies contained in some common interpretations of the current account deficit. And evidence supports the view that U.S. trade deficits are the result of two decades of (mostly) rapid U.S. economic growth and that, with certain caveats, they reflect economically-efficient responses of the U.S. economy. Consequently, the behavior of the current account and exchange rates should not lead U.S. economic policy to stray from the goal of promoting long-run economic growth. The United States should seize the opportunity afforded by this period of strong economic performance to remedy the main inefficiencies and distortions that hold back even stronger economic performance and that loom on the future horizon. Those policy changes should include reducing the strong disincentives to save created by the U.S. tax system and the social security system; reducing the disincentives to invest created by government regulations and the wide absence of cost-benefit analysis in their formulation and administration; and beginning institutional changes that would facilitate a credible long-run commitment to maintaining stable monetary environment, with a low and predictable rate of inflation, that has been achieved by the Federal Reserve under the leadership of Alan Greenspan but that cannot be credibly promised for the long-run under current institutional arrangements.