Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals

Similar documents
Free school meals under universal credit

Autumn Budget 2018: IFS analysis

Personal tax and benefit measures. Tom Waters

Incomes and inequality: the last decade and the next parliament

Taxes and benefits: the parties plans

Simplifying the Formal Structure of UK Income Tax

THE IMPACT OF TAX AND BENEFIT CHANGES BETWEEN APRIL 2000 AND APRIL 2003 ON PARENTS LABOUR SUPPLY

Estimating the Cost to Government of Providing Undergraduate and Postgraduate Education

Spring Budget IFS Director Paul Johnson s opening remarks

POLICY BRIEFING. ! Institute for Fiscal Studies 2015 Green Budget

The impact in of the change to indexation policy

Credit crunched: Single parents, universal credit and the struggle to make work pay

THE CHANCELLOR S CHOICES

Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries

Tax revenues: where does the money come from and what are the next government s challenges?

Options for reducing the interest rate on student loans and introducing maintenance grants

PPI analysis of Aviva proposals for a single rate of pensions tax relief

Taxes and benefits: the parties plans

PPI analysis of Friends Life proposals for a single rate of pensions tax relief

GETTING THE MOST FROM YOUR PENSION SAVINGS

The impact of tax and benefit reforms by sex: some simple analysis

10. The (changing) effects of universal credit

Living standards during the recession

IFS Green Budget Press Release

Helping your loved ones. Simple steps to providing for your family and friends

Where we have identified any third party copyright information you will need to obtain permission from the copyright holders concerned.

AFFORDABILITY: EXPENDITURE DRIVERS. No Control. Largely Fixed Commitments. Policy Commitments. Partial Control

Income Tax in Scotland: 2017 update

THE TAX AND BENEFIT SYSTEM AND THE DECISION TO INVEST IN A STAKEHOLDER PENSION

IFS. Options for a UK 'flat tax' Some simple simulations. The Institute for Fiscal Studies. Stuart Adam James Browne. IFS Briefing Note No.

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

7. Tax and welfare reforms planned for

Crisis Policy Briefing Universal Credit: Frequently Asked Questions. March 2017

ANDREW MARR SHOW 12 TH MARCH 2017 REBECCA LONG-BAILEY

Spring Statement 2018: more difficult choices ahead

Income Tax Rates, Rate Limits and Personal Allowances for

Estimating the Distortionary Costs of Income Taxation in New Zealand

Department for Education Northern Ireland

60 MINS CPD COURSE THE TAX ASPECTS OF PENSION FUNDING

Child and working-age poverty in Northern Ireland over the next decade: an update

The Melbourne Institute Report on the 2004 Federal Budget Hielke Buddelmeyer, Peter Dawkins, and Guyonne Kalb

Labour Supply, Taxes and Benefits

A PROGRESSIVE FUTURE FOR INCOME TAX IN SCOTLAND?

Tax and benefit reforms

Your guide to Inheritance Tax (IHT)

An ex-ante analysis of the effects of the UK Government s welfare reforms on labour supply in Wales

Ending austerity? July 2017

The (changing) effects of universal credit

Poverty Alliance Briefing 23

Labour Supply and Taxes

Review of the Automatic Enrolment Earnings Trigger and Qualifying Earnings Band for 2019/20: Supporting Analysis

B r i e f i n g. 2 9 O c t o b e r

LOCALISING COUNCIL TAX SUPPORT: A BRIEFING NOTE ON LOCAL AUTHORITIES PLANS Sam Popper and Peter Kenway

Scrutiny Timetable The Scottish Government s Draft Budget is subject to scrutiny by the Scottish Parliament Finance Committee, before being

Conservative manifesto tax policy and Universal Credit

Economic Perspectives

AF1 Income Tax Part 4: Adjusted Net Income

HEALTH AND COMMUNITIES AND LOCAL GOVERNMENT SELECT COMMITTEES JOINT INQUIRY INTO LONG-TERM FUNDING OF SOCIAL CARE Written Evidence submitted by

IFS Post-Budget Briefing 2015

C3.01: INDIVIDUAL PENSIONS ELIGIBILITY, LIMITS AND TAX RELIEF

The effect of UK welfare reforms on the distribution of income and work incentives

Do the UK government s welfare reforms make work pay?

Where we have identified any third party copyright information you will need to obtain permission from the copyright holders concerned.

All you need to know about the Government s plans to restrict finance cost relief for individual landlords

Motoring taxation today and the case for change

Publication will no doubt be overshadowed by the ongoing Brexit debate. But it s important not to lose sight of the domestic policy agenda.

Scottish Independence - Pensions Introduction Credentials Current UK position

Tax policy and inequality

UK public finances and the financial crisis

Introductory remarks. Paul Johnson 4/12/14. Some of yesterday s biggest announcements were not from the Chancellor

PERSONAL INCOME TAXES

THE AURUM COMPANY PENSION GROUP PERSONAL PENSION. A guide to help you prepare for the retirement you want

PPI PENSIONS POLICY INSTITUTE. Automatic enrolment contribution scenarios post Commissioned by the TUC

The short- and long-run impact of the national funding formula for schools in England

Modelling the impact of policy interventions on income in Scotland

Adjusting Scotland s Block Grant

Income Tax and Small Businesses in Scotland

Summary of ideas to kick-start some pre-funding for social care. Using pensions for care now possible following Budget reforms

A Summer Budget 2015 policy measures

UK Summer Budget Briefing

Can the changes to LHA achieve their aims in London s housing market?

Government tax, spending and debt a decade on from the financial crisis

Comparison of the Coalition Federal Budget Income Tax Measures and the Labor Proposal

Taxes and Benefits: The Parties Plans

~~L-~ ~at. Impact Assessment (la) Summary: Intervention and Options. RPC Opinion: RPC Opinion Status. < 20 No

Working paper No.14. Devolved income tax: forecasting by tax bands

R03 Income tax. Her Majesty s Revenue and Customs (HMRC) seek to tax an individual s income in the tax year which runs from April 6 to April 5.

The Elasticity of Taxable Income and the Tax Revenue Elasticity

PENSIONS POLICY INSTITUTE. The impact of opting-out of private pension saving at younger ages

Scotland's Fiscal Framework: Assessing the agreement

Broad shoulders and tight belts: Options for taxing the better-off

The economic impact of increasing the National Minimum Wage and National Living Wage to 10 per hour

Public sector pay: still time for restraint?

Collective Retirement Account

Child and working tax credits

Devolved tax and spending forecasts

Living Standards: Recent Trends and Future Challenges

Scotland s new Budget Framework

Living standards, poverty and inequality in the UK: to Andrew Hood Tom Waters

A3.01: INCOME TAX AND NI

Transcription:

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals IFS Briefing Note BN209 Stuart Adam Andrew Hood Robert Joyce David Phillips

Labour s proposed income tax rises for high-income individuals Stuart Adam, Andrew Hood, Robert Joyce and David Phillips Published by Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2017 1 ISBN 978-1-911102-54-0 1 IFS Election 2017 analysis is being produced with funding from the Nuffield Foundation as part of its work to ensure public debate in the run-up to the general election is informed by independent and rigorous evidence. For more information, go to http://www.nuffieldfoundation.org. The authors would like to thank Carl Emmerson and Paul Johnson for useful comments. All errors are the authors own.

hhhh Key findings 1. Labour proposes to increase income tax for the 1.3 million people with taxable income exceeding 80,000 per year: the highest-income 2% of adults, or 4% of income taxpayers. Currently this small group receive more than 20% of all taxable income and pay more than 40% of all income tax. 2. The tax revenue that Labour s proposal would raise is highly uncertain. If no one changed their behaviour in response, it would raise around 7 billion per year. But some of those affected would respond by reducing their taxable incomes, reducing the amount raised. The size of the response is highly uncertain and the revenue raised is highly sensitive to the size of the response. Labour expects the policy to raise in the region of 4.5 billion per year. Based on the available evidence this looks a little on the optimistic side, but it is entirely possible. However, it is also possible that the policy would raise nothing. 3. High-income individuals could respond to the policy in a number of ways. One straightforward response for many would be to increase their contributions to private pensions, which bring up-front income tax relief. They could also work less, make greater efforts to avoid or evade tax, emigrate, or not come to the UK in the first place. 4. Losses in cash terms would be highly concentrated on those with the highest incomes. If no one changed their behaviour then the 500,000 people with income between 80,000 and 100,000 would lose an average of 400 a year, while 50,000 people with income over 500,000 would all lose at least 22,900 a year. 5. Labour s proposal would be the latest in a series of income tax increases for this group. Since April 2010 the introduction of the 50% rate (later reduced to 45%), the withdrawal of the personal allowance from those with incomes above 100,000, and a succession of restrictions to tax relief on pension contributions have all increased the income tax paid by those with the highest incomes. 6. The proposals would miss an opportunity to rationalise the income tax system for those on higher incomes. The planned overhaul of the taxation of those on higher incomes would have been an obvious chance to remove the absurd and arbitrary marginal income tax band between 100,000 and 123,000, which arises from the policy described as withdrawing the personal allowance. Instead Labour s proposals would leave this in place, and would increase the marginal income tax rate from 60% to 67.5% within that band - or 66.6% to 73.2% once employer and employee National Insurance contributions, as well as income tax, are included. 2 Institute for Fiscal Studies

Marginal income tax rate 0. Appendix Labour proposes substantial increases in income tax rates for those on higher incomes Figure 1. Income tax schedule in 2017 18 with and without proposed Labour reforms 80% 70% Bottom 98% of adults Top 2% of adults 60% 50% 40% 30% Labour plan Current 20% 10% 0% 0 50,000 100,000 150,000 200,000 Annual taxable income Source: Authors calculations using HMRC income tax statistics. See Appendix for details. The Labour Party proposes to increase income tax for individuals with a taxable income exceeding 80,000 per year. Throughout this Briefing Note we assume that the changes would apply immediately across the UK, though income tax on non-dividend and non-savings income is now devolved to the Scottish Parliament, which might choose a different policy. 2 Labour s proposal would affect 1.3 million people a relatively small group but one that is already a very important source of revenue. Between them they have over 20% of all of the income of income tax payers, and they pay over 40% of all income tax. 2 Estimates of the revenue raised for the UK exchequer, based on the assumption that the policy applies across the whole of the UK, provide a very close approximation to the revenue that would accrue to the UK government even if the policy were not applied in Scotland. This is because the block grant paid to the Scottish Government would be adjusted based on the change in revenues in the rest of the UK. Hence the Scottish government's decision in this regard would affect its revenues, but not those of the UK exchequer. Institute for Fiscal Studies 3

hhhh Figure 1 illustrates the proposed tax increases. The green line shows the marginal rate of income tax (that is, the rate applied to the next 1 of income) currently levied at different levels of taxable income. The red line shows how this would change if Labour s proposals were in place now. The current system works as follows: The basic rate of income tax is 20% and it kicks in at 11,500 a year. Around 24 million people pay that marginal rate: around half of adults, or over 80% of income tax payers (since almost 45% of adults do not have income high enough to pay income tax). The higher marginal rate of income tax is 40% and it kicks in at 45,000 per year. About 4 million people pay that marginal rate (8% of adults, or 15% of income tax payers). There is effectively a marginal income tax rate of 60% on income between 100,000 and 123,000. This is the opaque consequence of a policy described as the withdrawal of the personal allowance from individuals on more than 100,000. 3 About 300,000 of the 4 million formally paying the headline 40% marginal rate are in fact paying this effective 60% marginal rate. An additional rate of 45% kicks in at 150,000 per year. A further 350,000 people pay that (0.6% of adults, or 1.1% of income tax payers). What does Labour propose? A new marginal income tax rate of 45%, starting from 80,000 per year. This means a tax rise for the 1.3 million people with an income above that level: the highest-income 2% of adults (or 4% of those who pay income tax) A new marginal rate of 50% starting from 123,000 (the point at which the personal allowance has been fully withdrawn). About 500,000 people have income above this level so will pay this new marginal rate (1% of adults, or 2% of those paying income tax). 3 For each 1 above 100,000, individuals lose 50p of their tax-free allowance. In other words they are liable for income tax at 40% on an extra 50p of income, which equates to an extra 20p of tax. Adding that to the headline 40p marginal rate means a 60p marginal rate overall. 4 Institute for Fiscal Studies

0. Appendix In addition to these changes in headline rates, Labour would retain the current policy of withdrawing the personal allowance from individuals on more than 100,000. In combination with the increase in the headline rate from 40% to 45% between 80,000 and 123,000, this increases the current bizarre 60% rate to an even higher 67.5%. Figure 1 focuses on income tax to highlight the changes Labour is proposing. But it is important to bear in mind that the income tax system sits alongside National Insurance contributions (NICs) made by both employees and employers. For those on higher incomes, the marginal rate of employer NICs is 13.8% and the marginal rate of employee NICs is 2%. It is these taxes in combination with income tax which determine how much of what an employer pays out actually reaches the pockets of its workers. Using that more comprehensive measure of the marginal tax rate for earned income, Labour s proposals would increase it from: 49.0% to 53.4% for those with earnings between 80,000 and 100,000; 66.6% to 73.2% for those between 100,000 and 123,000; 49.0% to 57.8% for those between 123,000 and 150,000; 53.4% to 57.8% for those on more than 150,000. 4 The income tax system for higher-income people has become increasingly opaque and complex in recent years, due to the withdrawal of child benefit, tapering of annual pension contribution limits, cliff-edge withdrawal of the new transferable married couples allowance, and the withdrawal of the personal allowance from 100,000. A restructuring of the income tax system for those on the highest incomes would have been an obvious opportunity to get rid of the bizarre and opaque 60% marginal income tax rate band that occurs because of the last policy. It is disappointing that Labour s proposal does not take that opportunity. 4 This excludes the impact of Labour s proposed excessive pay levy on the employers of those on at least 330,000. Institute for Fiscal Studies 5

Annual loss Number of people in each 5,000 band (000s) hhhh Labour has not been explicit about whether the new 80,000 threshold would be uprated over time. Income tax thresholds should relate to something economically meaningful like prices, earnings or taxable incomes. But in recent years both main parties have displayed an increasing and worrying habit of proposing or implementing nominal freezes to important parts of the tax and benefit system, including the 100,000 point at which the current effective 60% rate (which would become 67.5% under Labour) kicks in and the 150,000 point where the current 45% rate kicks in. This means that the numbers affected by higher rates increase over time at an arbitrary rate that depends on the rate of inflation as well as the rate of real income growth. If the new 80,000 threshold were frozen in nominal terms and all taxable incomes were to grow in line with the Office for Budget Responsibility s forecasts for average earnings 5, about half a million more people would be affected by Labour s changes (i.e. would have income above 80,000) by 2021 22. There is no economic rationale for keeping thresholds fixed in nominal terms in this way. It would be a good habit to kick. Who would lose and by how much? Figure 2. Annual losses from Labour s proposed income tax rises 10,000 200 9,000 180 8,000 7,000 Losses (left axis) 160 140 6,000 5,000 Number of people (right axis) 120 100 4,000 80 3,000 60 2,000 40 1,000 20 0 0 Annual taxable income Source: Authors calculations using HMRC income tax statistics. See Appendix for details. 5 See Office for Budget Responsibility (2017), Economic and Fiscal Outlook (http://budgetresponsibility.org.uk/efo/economic-fiscal-outlook-march-2017/). 6 Institute for Fiscal Studies

0. Appendix Figure 2 shows the consequences of these proposed changes for the income tax liabilities of higher-income individuals. There are many fewer people at the highest income levels shown in the figure than there are at a little above 80,000: the income distribution thins out very quickly at the top. To illustrate this, we overlay on the figure the estimated number of people with taxable income of different levels (in 5,000 bands). Remember also that about 98% of adults would see no change in income tax at all. Because everyone above 80,000 would face a higher marginal income tax rate under Labour, the absolute sizes of the losses from this package of changes get indefinitely higher the further above 80,000 you look. Hence, although the 1.3 million affected individuals would see an average tax rise of 5,300 per person if they did not change their behaviour, these extra payments are heavily skewed. For example, the 500,000 people (about a third of the losers) between 80,000 and 100,000 would lose an average of 400 per year; the 150,000 people between 150,000 and 200,000 would lose an average of 6,400. Table 1 picks out some key information about the magnitudes of the losses and how many people would experience such losses, and extends the analysis to even higher-income individuals than shown in the Figure. Table 1. Annual losses from Labour s proposed income tax rises Range of taxable income ( 000s) Number of people in range Range of losses 80-100 500,000 0-1,000 100-123 300,000 1,000-2,725 123-150 150,000 2,725-5,425 150-200 150,000 5,425-7,925 200-500 150,000 7,925-22,925 500+ 50,000 22,925- Source: Authors calculations using HMRC income tax statistics. See Appendix for details. Institute for Fiscal Studies 7

hhhh All the analysis above considers the impact of the proposals on individuals with different levels of taxable income. However, when considering the distributional impact of tax and benefit reforms, it is usually preferable to look at the effects on households with different levels of net (post-tax and benefit) income, after adjusting for the different needs that households of different sizes have, as this is a better proxy for living standards. Measured this way, as you would expect Labour s proposals would mostly affect the highest-income 10% of households (the top decile ). Over four-fifths of the households who would be affected are in the top decile, and over 97% of the revenue would come from the top decile. The 20% minority who are not in the top household income decile are largely households with children (placing them further down the distribution once we account for their higher needs). Indeed, 70% of those households have at least two dependent children (as opposed to 26% of all households affected). This high-income group of households has already seen large income tax rises in the years since the financial crisis. Between January 2010 and May 2015 the top decile lost the most from tax and benefit changes as a percentage of their income, while the rest of the richer half of households were remarkably well protected from austerity. Tax and benefit changes since 2015 have had little impact on the incomes of the top decile on average. 6 Revenue and behavioural effects A key issue when changing tax rates, and a key area of uncertainty here, is the size of any effects on people s behaviour. These behavioural effects matter for the amount of revenue that tax rises bring in, which we discuss in some detail in this section. Most fundamentally from an economic point of view, they matter for the size of the economic inefficiency created per pound of revenue raised. The more people reduce their taxable incomes in response to a higher tax rate, the greater the economic inefficiency or deadweight cost of the tax, i.e. the greater the amount by which the welfare loss to taxpayers exceeds the revenue generated for the Exchequer. Labour has indicated that it expects to raise around 4.5 billion per year from the changes. 7 As we stress below, there is a lot of uncertainty about how the policy 6 See Figures 4 and 5 of A. Hood and T. Waters (2017), The impact of tax and benefit reforms on household incomes (https://www.ifs.org.uk/publications/9164). 7 http://www.express.co.uk/news/uk/804674/john-humphrys-roasts-labour-jon- Ashworth-over-37bn-NHS-pledge-jeremy-corbyn-election. 8 Institute for Fiscal Studies

0. Appendix would actually raise. Below we discuss the sources of uncertainty and illustrate the sensitivity of the answer to different plausible assumptions. If there were no change in taxpayers (pre-tax) incomes as a result of Labour s proposed income tax rises, they would raise around 7 billion per year. That s the easy bit of the calculation. However, in reality it is highly likely that the changes would raise less than this as some high-income individuals would respond to the higher tax rates by working less (e.g. retiring earlier), increasing the extent to which they (legally) avoid or (illegally) evade taxes, or even emigrating (or not moving here in the first place). These kinds of potential responses vary in their likely frequency, but some are relatively straightforward for many individuals to do. For example, someone with a taxable income of 100,000 a year could, under Labour s proposals, get up-front income tax relief on any additional pension contributions at 45% (rather than 40% currently). The question, then, is how much of the potential 7 billion the Exchequer would lose to behavioural responses. A sizeable international literature finds evidence of such responses to income tax changes, particularly among high income individuals. 8 In the UK, the official HMRC analysis of the introduction (in 2010 11) of the short-lived 50% tax rate on incomes above 150,000, 9 and ongoing work by IFS researchers using updated data and different methods, 10 finds evidence of significant responses to that change. The magnitudes of the responses are highly uncertain, however, and even relatively small changes in the sizes of responses can have large impacts on the revenue raised. Hence, the most important thing to understand is the degree of uncertainty about impacts on revenue. The relevant measure of responsiveness can be summarised by the taxable income elasticity (TIE). This tells you by what percentage the income reported to the taxman changes when the marginal net-of-tax rate changes by 1% (the net-oftax rate is just the percentage of the income that is not taxed away, i.e. 100% minus the marginal tax rate). The higher this TIE, the more responsive are taxpayers to changes in tax rates and the less revenue increases in tax rates would raise. And when the TIE is high enough, increases in the tax rate can actually reduce revenues, as the losses from taxpayers reducing the amount of income they declare can more than offset the money raised as a result of higher tax rates: the so-called Laffer curve effect. 8 E. Saez, J. Slemrod and S. Giertz (2012, The Elasticity of Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax Rates: A Critical Review, Journal of Economic Literature, 50(1), pp3-50. 9 HMRC (2012), The Exchequer effect of the 50% additional rate of income tax, available online at the UK National Archives. 10 https://www.ifs.org.uk/publications/7675. Institute for Fiscal Studies 9

hhhh HMRC s central estimate of the TIE for taxpayers with incomes above 150,000 (i.e. those affected by the introduction of the 50% tax rate in 2010) was 0.48. However, the statistical uncertainty surrounding this central estimate was very large; and in addition, relatively modest changes to HMRC s methodology can lead to big changes in the central estimate. One particular difficulty is distinguishing temporary shifts in the timing of income around the moment that tax rates change (in particular, bringing income forward so that it is taxed at the lower, pre-reform rate) from permanent effects on behaviour. A TIE estimated for those with incomes above 150,000 also seems unlikely to be the best estimate of the level of responsiveness for the 950,000 people between 80,000 and 150,000, who would also be affected by Labour s proposals. We have no recent estimates of the TIE for this latter group of taxpayers. But the evidence we do have suggests it is reasonable to assume that this group is less responsive than those with the very highest incomes. In Budget 2012, for instance, following a review of the evidence, HM Treasury assumed a TIE of just 0.03 for those individuals affected by cuts to the higher rate tax threshold (affecting those with incomes of more than around 43,000). IFS analysis of responses to the 50% tax rate suggests that the TIE for those close to the 150,000 threshold was 0.1 to 0.2 the much higher 0.48 figure being driven by the high level of responsiveness of those with the very highest incomes. 11 To give a sense of how important the scale of these behavioural responses is to the revenues that would be raised from Labour s plans, we can examine the sensitivity of revenue estimates to assumptions about the relevant TIEs, drawing on the evidence available. Figure 3 shows our estimates of how much revenue Labour s plans would raise in three different plausible scenarios for degrees of responsiveness; along with the revenue estimate in the implausible scenario of no behavioural responses at all. In the first scenario ( low responsiveness ) we assume the TIE for those between 80,000 and 150,000 is 0.03, and that the TIE for those above 150,000 is 0.28. These elasticities are below the central estimates in each case, but well within the bounds of possibility. 11 The 0.1 and 0.2 figures are based on analysis of statistical data from HMRC which is Crown Copyright. The research datasets used may not exactly reproduce HMRC aggregates. The use of HMRC statistical data in this work does not imply the endorsement of HMRC in relation to the interpretation or analysis of the information. The analysis was cleared for publication in July 2015 in order for a work-in-progress presentation at the European Economic Association Annual Conference in Mannheim. Updated versions of this analysis are currently being finalised and will be published in due course. 10 Institute for Fiscal Studies

Annual revenue ( bn) 0. Appendix In the second scenario ( medium responsiveness ) we assume the TIEs are 0.13 and 0.48 respectively approximately central estimates. In the third scenario ( high responsiveness ) we assume the TIEs are 0.23 and 0.68 above the main central estimate in each case but again well within the bounds of possibility. Figure 3. Uncertain revenues from Labour proposal 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0-1 Increasing the marginal rate above 150,000 Increases in marginal rates between 80,000 and 150,000 Total -2 No response Low responsiveness Medium responsiveness High responsiveness Source: Authors calculations using HMRC income tax statistics. See Appendix for details. The Figure shows quite how uncertain the revenues from this proposal are. While in the medium responsiveness scenario the policy raises around 2½ billion per year, in the low responsiveness scenario it raises around 4½ billion a year (as Labour expect) and in the high responsiveness scenario it raises next to nothing. It is important to remember that these are illustrative scenarios, not upper and lower bounds on what is possible: the revenue yield could be greater than 4½ billion a year, or the policy could actually reduce the tax take. On the basis of the available evidence it does seem more likely than not that the proposal would raise money, but the amount is very uncertain. The yellow bars in the Figure also illustrate that the revenue from raising the marginal tax rate above 150,000 is particularly uncertain a gain of over 1½ billion in the low responsiveness scenario but a loss of around 1 billion in the high responsiveness scenario. In fact, the greater responsiveness of this group means that in all three of our scenarios, the majority of the revenue is raised as a result of changing marginal rates between 80,000 and 150,000 (though most of the revenue would still be coming from those with incomes above 150,000: this group would lose most from higher marginal rates between 80,000 and 150,000 as well as facing the increase in their marginal rate from 45% to 50%). Institute for Fiscal Studies 11

hhhh Appendix This appendix sets out the method we use in this briefing note to estimate the distribution of taxable income in 2017 18. It involves the following four steps: 1. Tables 2.4 and 2.5 of HMRC s income tax statistics and distributions provide projections of percentiles of the total income distribution among taxpayers, along with the number of taxpayers above certain income thresholds, in 2016 17. 12 2. We then uprate these percentiles and thresholds to 2017 18 in line with the OBR s March 2017 forecast for average earnings growth. 13 3. We then scale down the proportion of individuals above each threshold in 2017 18 by around 10%. This is to adjust for the fact that the percentiles and thresholds provided by HMRC are for total income, rather than taxable income (e.g. individual pension contributions are not excluded). The adjustment is based on a comparison of the number of people with total income over 150,000 and the number of people paying the additional rate of income tax (the number of people with taxable income above 150,000). 4. Finally, we use a Pareto distribution (assuming a Pareto parameter of 2) to interpolate between the thresholds provided by HMRC to approximate the full distribution of taxable incomes above 80,000. This method provides a good approximation when used as a predictor of known thresholds provided by HMRC. 12 See https://www.gov.uk/government/collections/income-tax-statistics-anddistributions. 13 See http://budgetresponsibility.org.uk/efo/economic-fiscal-outlook-march-2017/. 12 Institute for Fiscal Studies