Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles March. Sciences Po

Similar documents
Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Macroeconomics. Basic New Keynesian Model. Nicola Viegi. April 29, 2014

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Introducing nominal rigidities.

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

The Basic New Keynesian Model

On the new Keynesian model

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

The New Keynesian Model

State-Dependent Pricing and the Paradox of Flexibility

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

Simple Analytics of the Government Expenditure Multiplier

Economics 502. Nominal Rigidities. Geoffrey Dunbar. UBC, Fall November 22, 2012

Monetary Economics Basic Flexible Price Models

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

Examining the Bond Premium Puzzle in a DSGE Model

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Technology shocks and Monetary Policy: Assessing the Fed s performance

Satya P. Das NIPFP) Open Economy Keynesian Macro: CGG (2001, 2002), Obstfeld-Rogoff Redux Model 1 / 18

Microfoundations of DSGE Models: III Lecture

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

The new Kenesian model

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Monetary Economics. Money in Utility. Seyed Ali Madanizadeh. February Sharif University of Technology

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

DSGE Models with Financial Frictions

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

Dual Wage Rigidities: Theory and Some Evidence

The Long-run Optimal Degree of Indexation in the New Keynesian Model

Menu Costs and Phillips Curve by Mikhail Golosov and Robert Lucas. JPE (2007)

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Updated 10/30/13 Topic 4: Sticky Price Models of Money and Exchange Rate

A Model of Financial Intermediation

Monetary Economics. Lecture 11: monetary/fiscal interactions in the new Keynesian model, part one. Chris Edmond. 2nd Semester 2014

Household Debt, Financial Intermediation, and Monetary Policy

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

Macroeconomic Theory Lecture 7. October 23, 2014

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Eco504 Spring 2010 C. Sims MID-TERM EXAM. (1) (45 minutes) Consider a model in which a representative agent has the objective. B t 1.

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

Problem set 5. Asset pricing. Markus Roth. Chair for Macroeconomics Johannes Gutenberg Universität Mainz. Juli 5, 2010

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Models of Wage-setting.. January 15, 2010

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

Topic 5: Sticky Price Models of Money and Exchange Rate

Alternative theories of the business cycle

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

A dynamic model with nominal rigidities.

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

1.3 Nominal rigidities

Introduction. The Model Setup F.O.Cs Firms Decision. Constant Money Growth. Impulse Response Functions

The Bond Premium in a DSGE Model with Long-Run Real and Nominal Risks

Macroeconomics Field Exam August 2017 Department of Economics UC Berkeley. (3 hours)

Quadratic Labor Adjustment Costs and the New-Keynesian Model. by Wolfgang Lechthaler and Dennis Snower

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

GHG Emissions Control and Monetary Policy

Does Calvo Meet Rotemberg at the Zero Lower Bound?

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Problem set Fall 2012.

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

Endogenous Trade Participation with Incomplete Exchange Rate Pass-Through

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Fiscal and Monetary Policy in a New Keynesian Model with Tobin s Q Investment Theory Features

Monetary Economics. Financial Markets and the Business Cycle: The Bernanke and Gertler Model. Nicola Viegi. September 2010

Lecture Notes. Petrosky-Nadeau, Zhang, and Kuehn (2015, Endogenous Disasters) Lu Zhang 1. BUSFIN 8210 The Ohio State University

Extended DSGE Model of the Czech Economy

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

The design of the funding scheme of social security systems and its role in macroeconomic stabilization

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Money in an RBC framework

Real Wage Rigidities and Disin ation Dynamics: Calvo vs. Rotemberg Pricing

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Microfoundation of Inflation Persistence of a New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Reforms in a Debt Overhang

Science of Monetary Policy: CGG (1999)

Real Business Cycle Theory

A MODEL OF SECULAR STAGNATION

Transcription:

Macroeconomics 2 Lecture 6 - New Keynesian Business Cycles 2. Zsófia L. Bárány Sciences Po 2014 March

Main idea: introduce nominal rigidities Why? in classical monetary models the price level ensures money market clearing: M P = L(Y, i) = C L 0(i) = C L 0 (r + π e ) for example if money demand is specified as (Cagan): m t p t = αe t (p t+1 p t ) we can solve this forward and get p t = 1 1 + α i=0 the price level is like an asset price α i Tt (m t+1 ) 1 + α

the price level in reality is not like an asset price it comes from the aggregation of many prices, set by individual price setters, at different points in time P adjusts more slowly as a reaction to an increase in M the nominal interest rate will have to fall, and so will probably the real interest rate the Euler equation then implies an increased current demand for consumption output dynamics depend on how the price setters respond to the shift in demand older fixed price (wage) models: output given by the minimum of supply and demand at the given price in imperfect competition firms have an incentive to accommodate these shifts as long as P > MC demand affects output

A static model of price-setters simplified Blanchard-Kiyotaki (1987) model continuum of households all produce one differentiated good Y i = ZN i consume all differentiated goods U ( C i, M ) i P, N i = ( ) ( α Mi Ci P α 1 α where consumers have Dixit-Stiglitz preferences ) 1 α N1+γ i 1 + γ ( 1 C i 0 ) θ C θ 1 θ 1 θ ij dj θ > 1

the price index is: ( 1 P 0 ) 1 P 1 θ 1 θ j dj the budget constraint is 1 0 P j C ij dj + M i = P i Y i + M i where M i is initial money holdings household needs money for transactions, now MIU rather than CIA budget constraint short cut to a dynamic budget constraint

Demand for household j s product for now assume that each household spends a nominal amount X i on consumption goods the household s problem is then ( 1 max {C ij } 1 j=0 0 then we get that ) θ C θ 1 θ 1 θ ij dj C ij = X i P subject to 1 ( ) θ Pj and C i P = X i P 0 P j C ij dj = X i since P is the price index we wrote earlier, the demand for good j by household i can be written as C ij = C i ( Pj P ) θ given overall consumption, C i, the demand for each good depends on its relative price P j /P

Choice of consumption and money using the demand for goods, the household s choice between money and consumption can be written as: max C i,m i ( ) ( ) α Mi 1 α Ci P s.t. PC i + M i = P i Y i + M i α 1 α given Y i and M i the optimal consumption and money balances are C i = α P iy i + M i P and M i P = (1 α)p iy i + M i P hhs allocate their initial wealth in α and 1 α proportion to consumption and money balances (not surprising given Cobb-Douglas utility)

from the two FOCs we can get: C i = α M i 1 α P the demand for the good j by hh i is: ( ) θ Pj C ij = C i = α M i P 1 α P ( ) θ Pj P using the two FOCs in the utility function, the indirect utility can be written as: P i P Y i N1+γ i 1 + γ + M i P

Pricing and output decision the hh finally chooses output (equivalently hours: N i = Y i /Z) and its price: P i max P i,y i P Y i Y 1+γ i Z (1+γ) 1 + γ the price it charges and the demand for its product is connected through the overall demand for good i: Y i = 1 0 C ji dj = α M 1 α P ( ) θ Pi P where M = 1 0 M jdj is the total desired money holding in the economy & money demand must equal money supply M = M: Y i = α M 1 α P ( ) θ Pi P

the maximization yields: P i P = θ θ 1 Y γ i Z (1+γ) price equals marginal cost times a markup plugging in Y i once more gives: ( ) 1 P i θ P = θ 1 X γ Z (1+γ) 1+θγ α M where X 1 α P an increase in real money supply leads to an increase in the optimal relative price magnitudes depend on θ and γ, as γ 0 the effect gets smaller

Equilibrium all hhs are identical besides that they produce different goods i.e. their preferences for all goods are identical and the hhs preferences are identical in equilibrium the relative price must be 1 output by each hh: 1 = θ ( ) 1 θ 1 θ 1 Y γ Z (1+γ) Y = Z 1+γ θ ( γ θ 1 N = θ ) 1 γ Z lower equilibrium output than under perfect competition due to the markup (homework: check!) output lower than first best technological shock Y, N, the effect is bigger if γ is closer to 0

Price level determination closing the model: the price level must be such that the level of demand is right Y = α M 1 α P P = α M 1 α Y output determined by marginal cost and markup nominal money neutral - moves price one-for-one this does not seem like much progress

But this is progress! think about an increase in nominal money supply the equilibrium requires a proportional change in the price index, but no change in the relative prices how will this happen? who is in charge of the price level? nobody each price setter has to increase the prices individually, i.e. modify his relative price, if γ not far above 0, then each firm only adjusts its price by a little the price adjustment can be very slow

Introducing nominal rigidities hh have to set nominal prices, they might want to do these at discrete time intervals (rather than continuously). why? menu costs: a small deviation from the optimum price has only second order effects on profits, but it has a first order effect on output and welfare - diagram depending on the MC curve, the desired change in price might be really small (if γ is very small) modify the timing of the model as follows: 1. each hh chooses the price of its product before the nominal money supply and the productivity is realized 2. consumption decisions are taken after observing the realization of M and Z

The choice of production and relative price of the hh is now: ( ) P i max E P i,y i P Y i Y 1+γ i Z (1+γ) 1 + γ subject to Y i = α M 1 α P ( ) θ Pi = X P ( ) θ Pi P Now M (or X ) and Z are random variables, the FOC is: ( ( ) θ ( ) ) (1+γ)θ 1 Pi E X (1 θ) + θx 1+γ Z (1+γ) Pi = 0 P P rearranging: P i P = ( θ θ 1 E ( X 1+γ Z (1+γ)) E(X ) ) 1 1+θγ higher E(X ) higher relative price

In equilibrium the relative prices must all be 1. The price level is implicitly defined by: 1 = θ E ( X 1+γ Z (1+γ)) θ 1 E(X ) α remember that X = 1 α if MC < P, then demand and output will be: M P and employment will be: Y = α M 1 α P N = Y Z

Implications: unanticipated movements in the nominal money supply affect the real money supply one-for-one, as prices are already set the real money supply affects output and consumption one-for-one demand affects output as long as MC < P holds (diagram) the relative prices will not change welfare moves together with Y and M increase money unexpectedly in order to increase welfare? unanticipated technological shocks do not affect demand nor output and they initially decrease employment introduce a more realistic price setting & dynamics New Keynesian model

A basic New Keynesian DSGE model take the imperfect competition model from last week assume Φ = 0, i.e. constant returns to scale there are profits in the steady state assume that the aggregation function f takes the Dixit-Stiglitz form: the price index is then ( 1 Y t = 0 0 ) ( ) θ θ 1 θ 1 Y i θ t di ( 1 ) 1 P t = (Pt) i 1 θ 1 θ di

Let the utility function be: U (C, H) = The consumer s problem is: subject to max {C t,h t,k t+1 } t=0 ( ) C 1 σ H1+γ 1 σ 1 + γ E 0 β t U(C t, H t ) t=0 P t C t + P t K t+1 = W t H t + (U t + P t (1 δ)) K }{{} t + Π t R t and let Λ t β t be the multiplier associated with the time t BC

the FOCs: C t : C σ t = Λ t P t H t : H γ t = Λ t W t K t+1 : Λ t P t = βe t (Λ t+1 R t+1 )

Calvo pricing in each period a fraction (1 η) of firms have the possibility to reset their prices the other η fraction keep their previous price η [0, 1] is the index of price stickiness the implied average price duration is 1 1 η completely unrealistic, but easy to handle don t have to keep track of the history of the firms, when they last changed prices does not matter not connected to the micro foundations of price rigidity, which is very history dependent

What price do the price-setters choose? firm sets its price to maximize expected profits however, the price it sets in period t might remain for several periods has to take into account the probability that the same price stays for 1, 2,.., n,.. periods the problem can be written as: max E t η j β j Λ t+j Π t+j (P Pt t ) Λ t j=0 Starting from the Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator, as before, it can be shown that the demand for good i is: Y i t = ( ) P i θ t Y t P t

Using the demand, the per period profit function is: ( P t ) θ Y t+j TC ( ( P t ) θ Y t+j) Π t+j (P t ) = P t P t+j P t+j assuming the Cobb-Doulas production function Y i t = (H i t) α (K i t ) 1 α the producers of the differentiated goods take wages and rental rates as given the total cost can be expressed as TC(Y ) = YW α t U 1 α t (1 α) 1 α α α

The optimum Pt satisfies: E t j=0 η j β j Λ ( ) t+j (1 θ)(pt ) θ Y t+j Pt+j θ + θy t+j S t+j (Pt ) θ 1 Pt+j θ = 0 Λ t where the nominal marginal cost is: S t+j = U1 α t+j W 1 α t+j (1 α) 1 α α α the optimal P t can be expressed as: what is a t? Pt = θ 1 θ E t j=0 ηj β j Λ t+j Λ t Y t+j Pt+j θ S t+j E t j=0 ηj β j Λ t+j Λ t Y t+j Pt+j θ =a t θ 1 θ Y tp θ t S t + (1 a t )E t P t+1

The price index The price index is: ( 1 ) 1 P t = (Pt) i 1 θ 1 θ di = (η(p t 1 ) 1 θ + (1 η)(pt ) 1 θ) 1 1 θ 0 where P t 1 is the price index in the previous period note the role of η if η = 0 prices are fully flexible if η = 1 prices are fixed

Closing the model Money demand M t P t = Y γm t ln M t ln P t = γ m ln Y t ad hoc money demand function, which an be derived from different assumptions direct link between the real and the nominal side of the economy: Y i t = ( Mt P t ) 1 γm ( P i t P t ) θ if prices were flexible, any change in M t would be fully absorbed by a proportional change in P t and all the P i ts Money supply ln M t ln M t 1 = ρ(ln M t 1 ln M t 2 ) + e t

Log-linearization in the non-stochastic BGP: π t = Pt P t 1 > log-linearization of the optimal relative price p t = ln P t P t ln P t P t = 1 and P t P t = 1 = (1 ηβ)ŝ t + ηβe t ( π t+1 + p t+1) > log-linearization of the inflation, using the price index: π t = ln π t ln π t = 1 η η combining the two we get the New Keynesian Phillips curve: p t π t = 1 η (1 ηβ)ŝ t + βe t π t+1 η inflation depends on real marginal cost and is forward looking due to price stickiness

Results - Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan response to a 1 percent money shock (with fairly inelastic labor supply) contemporary output increases, since P t is not responding one-for-one price level adjusts quickly: returns to equilibrium level those who adjust, adjust very aggressively lack of persistence hours respond too much factor prices respond too much as well prices adjust very rapidly nominal interest rate increases

Refine the model 1. material inputs besides choosing K and N, firms choose material inputs, which are units of the composite good 2. variable capacity utilization of K at a cost of faster depreciation, capital can be used more intensively during booms 3. more elastic labor supply add an extensive margin: people can decide whether to join the workforce at a fixed cost

Results of the more refined model hours per worker response in right range employment responds a lot aggregate hours response is bigger persistent, hump-shaped and larger output response factor prices move less slower price adjustment nominal interest rate still increases

Understanding the results Adjusting firms trade-off: loss in sales if adjusting the price too much increase in marginal cost if adjusting too little The marginal cost depends on factor prices: if factor prices move a lot, then the marginal cost moves a lot, firms will find it optimal to adjust aggressively lots of price adjustment leads to low persistence

In the CKM specification capital constant, no materials need a large labor supply response to the demand shock but labor is quite inelastic large increase in the wage as the capital/labor ratio drops, the rental rate increases the marginal cost increases a lot in booms the firms that can adjust do adjust a lot in booms, more than one-for-one

In the complete model variable capacity utilization, materials labor supply needs to respond less moreover, labor supply is more elastic, since there is an extensive margin wage rate does not have to go up that much the capital/labor ratio also moves much less the rental rate does not increase that much either the marginal cost is less pro-cyclical firms find it optimal to adjust their prices less

inflexible economy steep MC curve adjustment through aggressive price change & small output change get to the same equilibrium price level faster flexible economy flatter MC curve adjustment through smaller price change & larger output change get to the same equilibrium price level in many smaller steps

the nominal interest rate has to go up in all cases due to the expected inflation this is a bit embarrasing look at interest rate based monetary rules mark-ups are counter-cyclical prices respond less this had to be the case: employment and wage move the same way and there are no technology shocks

State-of-the-art NK DSGE models canonical model by Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (JPE 2004) key additional elements: Calvo nominal price and wage rigidities habit formation in consumption adjustment costs in investment best quantitative match with the empirical IRFs so far instead of calibration of parameters one by one: joint calibration by Method of Moments formal estimation of parameters also with MoM or ML