The Effects of Macroeconomic Policies on Crime. Abstract

Similar documents
Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

Public Investment in Basic Education and Economic Growth

Collateralized capital and news-driven cycles. Abstract

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Volume 29, Issue 1. Juha Tervala University of Helsinki

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Money in an RBC framework

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Working Paper No. 241

Collateralized capital and News-driven cycles

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Conditional versus Unconditional Utility as Welfare Criterion: Two Examples

Public Investment, Life Expectancy and Income Growth

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Competitiveness, Income Distribution and Economic Growth in a Small Economy

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Topic 6. Introducing money

On the 'Lock-In' Effects of Capital Gains Taxation

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Mixed Motives of Simultaneous-move Games in a Mixed Duopoly. Abstract

Project Evaluation and the Folk Principle when the Private Sector Lacks Perfect Foresight

B r i e f T a b l e o f C o n t e n t s

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Income Inequality and Economic Growth: A Simple Theoretical Synthesis *

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

Is a Threat of Countervailing Duties Effective in Reducing Illegal Export Subsidies?

Fiscal policy: Ricardian Equivalence, the e ects of government spending, and debt dynamics

Overlapping Generations Model: Dynamic Efficiency and Social Security

Final Exam Solutions

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

1 No capital mobility

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics

Volume Title: The Demand for Health: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation. Volume URL:

1 Continuous Time Optimization

Bubbles and the Intertemporal Government Budget Constraint

Standard Risk Aversion and Efficient Risk Sharing

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

An Economical Business-Cycle Model

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Credit, externalities, and non-optimality of the Friedman rule

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Asset Prices in Consumption and Production Models. 1 Introduction. Levent Akdeniz and W. Davis Dechert. February 15, 2007

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

Funded Pension Scheme, Endogenous Time Preference and Capital Accumulation

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

Advanced Macroeconomics 6. Rational Expectations and Consumption

Monopoly Power with a Short Selling Constraint

Review: objectives. CHAPTER 2 The Data of Macroeconomics slide 0

On the general equilibrium costs of perfectly anticipated inflation

Online Appendix: Extensions

Volume 31, Issue 3. The dividend puzzle and tax: a note. Frank Strobel University of Birmingham

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb

FINANCIAL REPRESSION AND LAFFER CURVES

Wage discrimination and partial compliance with the minimum wage law. Abstract

Public-private Partnerships in Micro-finance: Should NGO Involvement be Restricted?

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Welfare Evaluations of Policy Reforms with Heterogeneous Agents

Notes on Obstfeld-Rogoff Ch.1

For students electing Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) & Micro (8703/Prof. Glewwe) option

Macroeconomics. A European Text OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS SIXTH EDITION. Michael Burda and Charles Wyplosz

National Debt and Economic Growth with Externalities and Congestions

The Costs of Losing Monetary Independence: The Case of Mexico

Directed Search Lecture 5: Monetary Economics. October c Shouyong Shi

The n-dimensional Bailey-Divisia Measure as a General-Equilibrium Measure of the Welfare Costs of In ation

Price Discrimination As Portfolio Diversification. Abstract

Current tax law allows workers to opt out, either partially

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Search, Moral Hazard, and Equilibrium Price Dispersion

Inflation & Welfare 1

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

License and Entry Decisions for a Firm with a Cost Advantage in an International Duopoly under Convex Cost Functions

Documento de Trabajo. ISSN (edición impresa) ISSN (edición electrónica)

Social Common Capital and Sustainable Development. H. Uzawa. Social Common Capital Research, Tokyo, Japan. (IPD Climate Change Manchester Meeting)

X. Henry Wang Bill Yang. Abstract

Università degli Studi di Roma Tor Vergata Facoltà di Economia Area Comunicazione, Stampa, Orientamento. Laudatio.

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Transcription:

The Effects of Macroeconomic Policies on Crime Vladimir K. Teles University of Brasília (UnB) Abstract This paper investigates whether monetary and fiscal policies, such as lump sum taxes, distortionary taxation and monetization of public deficit, have criminal impacts. We address this question extending the neoclassical monetary growth model. We have demonstrated that fiscal policies affect crime through government spending. Conversely, the effect of monetary policy, especially inflation, on crime depends on the separability of the utility function. We would like to thank Joaquim P. Andrade, Adolfo Sachsida, João Ricardo Faria, Jorge Saba Arbache and José Coelho Matos Filho for valuable comments and insights. The usual disclaimer applies. Citation: Teles, Vladimir K., (2004) "The Effects of Macroeconomic Policies on Crime." Economics Bulletin, Vol. 11, No. 1 pp. 1 9 Submitted: October 28, 2003. Accepted: January 5, 2004. URL: http://www.economicsbulletin.com/2004/volume11/eb 03K00002A.pdf

1 Introduction Crime is an extremely important political and economic issue in our day. The considerable costs imposed by crime on its victims and society greatly exceed the private benefits of crime (Becker, 1968; Fender 1999). However, there is definitely no consensus among policy-makers or scholars on how to deal with this problem. This lack of agreement has undoubtedly been brought about by the complexity of the phenomenon, and research on this issue is being conducted in many areas. In light of this fact, since the seminal article by Becker (1968) 1, crime has been formally dealt with by economists through the construction of microfundaments in order to better understand the reasons why agents take part in illicit activities. Becker s original approach introduces a type of rational behavior in which agents compare their expected returns with the costs of committing a crime, so that the criminal activity will be engaged in if the expected returns surpass the legal alternatives. Therefore, the criminal, as well as the other agents, are considered economic agents who respond to stimuli in a market setting, and whose behavior may be studied by way of an equilibrium study in an optimizing framework. This article follows the tradition of economic models used to study crime founded by Becker in order to construct an intertemporal general equilibrium model that will allow us to study the relation between macroeconomic policies and crime. In this sense, several articles have recently observed that problems such as unequal distribution of income, poverty, and unemployment have effects on crime (e.g. Hunag et. al., 2002; Burdett et. al., 2003). It is therefore possible to expect that, in certain circumstances, monetary and fiscal policies also affect crime. Also, the monetary and growth literature has indicated a relation between crime and inflation, if the real effects of inflation are considered. In this context, if the Tobin effect (Tobin, 1965) is verified, then inflation would have a positive effect on production (negative on unemployment), which could have a negative effect on crime. On the other hand, if the anti-tobin effect is verified (e.g. Stockman, 1981) then inflation may be criminally friendly. The goal of this article is to investigate, in a neoclassical monetary growth context à la Sidrauski (1967), how fiscal and monetary policies affect crime. Policies such as the monetization of the public deficit, lump-sum taxation, and distortionary taxation are evaluated with regard to their impact on economic 1 Other articles that have dealt with the issue of crime in the economic literature are Fleisher (1966), Tullok (1967) and Rotemberg (1968), among others (see Ehrlich, 1996) 1

agents decision to engage in criminal activity. Special attention has been given to the inflation effects on crime. Section 2 outlines the standard model in which crime is inserted in the Sidrauski (1967) model, where the effects of the monetization of the public deficit are investigated. Section 3 covers the relation between fiscal policy and crime, and Section 4 offers concluding remarks. 2 Monetary Policy and Crime The relation between monetary policy and crime shall be considered according to the hypothesis by which the government emits money to finance its deficit. This means that crime is incorporated in the Sidrauski (1967) model in order to make it possible to consider the consequences that the monetization of the public deficit have on crime. The modeling of the relation between the several variables and fiscal and monetary policy, according to the Sindrauski model, is habitual in economic literature. In that sense the model adopted in this study follows closely Faria (1998). In order to incorporate crime in the Sidrauski (1967) monetary growth model we initially consider that criminal activity is a diseconomy to production, since negative externalities are generated, thus following the rationale of Becker (1968). This takes place because productive resources are allocated towards an unproductive activity such as crime, having adverse effects on agents well being. This hypothesis may be directly inserted in the Sidrauski model by introducing crime in the economy s production function. While agents are stimulated to engage in criminal activities according to the expected positive returns, they are also subject to the effects of crime, with loss in income. According to this idea, we may argue that the total income of a representative agent of this economy will be given by (1). Y = f (k, o) [1 + φ (k, o, ō)] (1) where = 0, if o = ō φ (k, o, ō) > 0, if o > ō < 0, if o < ō 2

Thus, f(k, o) represents the production function, where k is the initial capital stock, with f k > 0, and o the number of hours spent on criminal activity, with f o < 0. On the other hand, φ(k, o, ō) represents the net income function of the criminal activity, where the agent chooses the number of hours that will be dedicated to crime, when faced with the average number of hours of the other agents, ō. This type of function is commonly used in illicit activity models such as in Ehrlich and Lui (1999). It must also be pointed out that k appears here in the criminal activity returns function. This is done in order to represent the increase in the expected returns from crime as the economy grows, increasing its capital stock. This hypothesis is widely supported by stylized facts, such as the evident difference between big city crime rates and the crime rates in small towns and/or rural areas, making it clear that in locations with greater capital stocks (e.g. big cities) there is a significantly greater incidence of crime per capita. As pointed out by Glaeser and Sacerdote (1999) these facts may be explained by several arguments, such as the decrease in the probability the criminal will be punished, the lower costs of criminal activity, or eventhe increase in the expected returns from crime in locations with a high capital stock. In Sidrauski s model, the representative agent maximizes the current value of his/her utility function subject to a budget constraint where income is allocated between a physical asset and a monetary asset. If we consider that criminal activity directly affects the well-being of an agent, and if we incorporate this in his or her utility function, the Sidrauski model then becomes, Max U (c, m, o) e ρt dt c,m,o 0 (2) s.t. k + ṁ = Y c + x π m Therefore, assuming there is no population growth, m represents the real monetary balance of the economy, where c is consumption, x are the government lump-sum transfers, ρ is the temporal preference rate, and π is the rate of inflation. All the variables are defined in per capita terms. By substituting (1) in (2) and solving the problem, the following first-order conditions are obtained, u m u c = π (3) u o + λ {f o + f o φ + f φ o } = 0 (4) λ λ = ρ {f k + f k φ + f φ k } (5) Since all agents are considered identical, and are confronted with the same 3

maximization problem, we have that o = ō becomes an equilibrium condition. At the same time, we have that in a steady state, the lump-sum government transfer is, x σm = πm σ = π (6) meaning that the rate of monetary growth (σ) is equal to the rate of inflation. The impact of monetary policy may then be captured by inflation. At the same time, since in this model s steady-state the per capita variables remain constant, meaning that the shadow-price of capital remains constant, we have that the following equations complete the steady-state condition. u o + λ (f o + f φ o ) = 0 (7) ρ = (f k + f φ k ) (8) c = f(k, o) (9) Therefore, the steady-state equilibrium is characterized by equations (3), (7), (8) and (9). Equation (3) supplies us with the marginal rate of substitution between currency and consumption, and equation (7) supplies us with the optimal rule for the construction of a marginal rate of substitution between crime and consumption and/or money, since λ may be easily related to its marginal utilities. Equation (8) concludes, as foreseen by the golden rule, that the temporal preference rate will be different than the marginal product of capital, and Equation (9) demonstrates that the product will be entirely consumed. The relationship between monetary policy and crime may be determined from these equations, as stated in Proposition 1. Proposition 1 Monetary policy affects crime if the agents utility function is not additively separable. Proof: If the utility function is additionally separable the system is block recursive, so that equations (7), (8) and (9) may then be used to obtain the optimal levels of k, c and o, regardless of m, whose optimal level may be obtained, as a consequence, from (3). On the other hand, if the utility function is not additionally separable, the (3), (7)-(9) system becomes simultaneous, and the real and nominal variables are no longer independent. Inflation will particularly affect the optimal level of crime. Proposition 1 states that if the quantity of money held by an agent does not affect the marginal utility of crime, then inflation will not affect the incidence 4

of crime in the economy. Thus, the link between monetary policy and crime that is constructed with this model is the relation between currency and crime in its utility function. In this context, it is important to remember that both the number of hours spent engaging in criminal activity and the quantity of currency are the ingredients of a choice between income and leisure that an agent must make, for if the agent opts for more money, he or she will have more leisure time, while more hours spent engaging in an illicit activity would mean less leisure time, compensated by greater income. Thus, criminal activity is directly related to an increase in an agent s consumption. If we consider that currency plays a role in minimizing transaction costs, or that it is necessary for consumption, then there will be no reason for currency and hours spent on crime to be separable in the utility function. An alternative rationale would be to imagine a money-less economy, in which all negotiations are conducted through bartering. In this case, criminal activity would involve a series of costs, since the transport and exchange of stolen goods would create additional costs for said activity. This illustrates that money may lead to a reduction in the costs of crime, since there would a disutility in criminal activity, making it possible to support the idea of non-separability between currency and crime. 3 Fiscal Policy and Crime 3.1 Lump-Sum Taxation In order to evaluate the impacts of fiscal policy on crime in this model, the Turnovsky (1995) approach has been adapted. This approach introduces a new argument to the utility function, g (government spending). In the current context, said spending could be related to the government s law enforcement policy. The other modification of the model would a budget restriction, in which the representative agent pays a lump-sum tax (T ): Max U (c, m, o, g) e ρt dt c,m,o 0 (10) s.t. k + ṁ = Y c T π m From the first-order conditions, we obtain the following steady-state condition, c + g = f(k, o) (11) 5

along with equations (3), (7) and (8). It must be pointed out that equation (11) arises from the fact the government finances its deficit by printing money: g T = ṁ + πm (12) It is now possible to study the impacts of fiscal policy on crime, according to what is stated in propositions 2 and 3. Proposition 2 If the utility function is additively separable, then only fiscal policy will affect crime. Proof: If the utility function is additively separable, then the (3), (7), (8) and (11) system is block recursive, and equations (7), (8) and (11) may be used to obtain the optimal levels of k, c and o, regardless of m, whose optimal level may be obtained from (3). On the other hand, changes in g affect the real variables, especially crime. Proposition 3 If the utility function is not additively separable, then both fiscal and monetary policy will affect crime. Proof: If the utility function is not additively separable, the system (3), (7), (8), and (11) becomes simultaneous, the real and nominal variables become non-independent, and monetary policy then affects crime, for inflation will affect the optimal choice of hours spent on an criminal activity. Fiscal policy continues to affect crime following the same rationale as stated in Proposition 2. According to proposition 2, only fiscal policy has an impact on crime, while according to proposition 3, that suggests non-separability from the utility function, both fiscal and monetary policies affect crime directly, corroborating proposition 1, discussed above. 3.2 Distortionary Taxation In order to introduce distortionary taxation in our model, we shall consider taxation as being a function of total consumption: T = T (c) (13) 6

Substituting (13) in (10) and solving the problem, only equation (3) will be altered in the steady state: u m u c = π (1 T c ) (14) Therefore, it becomes clear that none of the previous propositions shall be altered if distortionary taxation of this sort is considered. Thus, even in the case of distortionary taxation, the effects of monetary policy on crime will continue to depend on the non-separability of the utility function. The only alteration that will occur will be the magnitude of the effects of fiscal and monetary policies on crime. 4 Conclusion The investigation into why an optimizing agent would engage in an illicit activity has been the subject of several recent studies, having reached prominence in economic research. In this context, the present article has constructed an intertemporal general equilibrium model with micro-fundaments in order to discuss the relation between macroeconomic policies and crime. The monetization of the public deficit, lump-sum taxation, and distortionary taxation were analyzed. We have demonstrated that fiscal policies affect crime through government spending. Conversely, the effect of monetary policy, especially inflation, on crime depends on the separability of the utility function. References [1] Becker, G. (1968) Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach The Journal of Political Economy, 76:2, 169-217. [2] Burdett, K., Lagos, R. and Wright, R. (2003) Crime, Inequality, and Unemployment, American Economic Review, in press. [3] Ehrlich, I. (1996) Crime, Punishment and the Market of Offenses The Journal of Economic Perspectives, v.10, n.1, 43-67. [4] Ehrlich, I., Lui, F. (1999) Bureaucratic Corruption and Endogenous Economic Growth The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107, No. 6, Part 2: Symposium on the Economic Analysis of Social Behavior in Honor of Gary S. Becker. (Dec., 1999), pp. S270-S293. [5] Faria, J. R. (1998) Environment, growth and fiscal and monetary policies. Economic Modelling, 15, pp. 113-123. 7

[6] Fender, J. (1999) A general equilibrium model of crime and punishment Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 39 (1999) 437453. [7] Fleisher, B. (1966) The Economics of Delinquency, Chicago:Quadrangle. [8] Glaeser, E., Sacerdote, B. (1999) Why Is There More Crime in Cities? The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 107, No. 6, Part 2: Symposium on the Economic Analysis of Social Behavior in Honor of Gary S. Becker. (Dec., 1999), pp. S225-S258. [9] Huang, Chien-Chieh; Laing, Derek, and Wang, Ping. (2002).Crime and Poverty: A Search-Theoretic Approach, mimeo. [10] Rotemberg, S. (1968) The Clandestine Distribution of Heroin, Its Discovery and Suppression The Journal of Political Economy, 76:1, 78-90. [11] Sidrauski, M., 1967. Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy. American Economic Review 57, 534-544. [12] Stockman, A.C., 1981. Anticipated inflation and the capital stock in a cashin-advance economy. Journal of Monetary Economics 8, 387-393. [13] Tobin, J., 1965. Money and economic growth. Econometrica 32, 671-684. [14] Tullok, G. (1967) The Welfare Costs of Tarrifs, Monopolies, and Theft Economic Inquiry, 5, 224-232. [15] Turnovsky, S.J., 1995. Methods of Macroeconomic Dynamics. MIT Press, Cambridge. 8