Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Similar documents
Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle

Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle

How Much Insurance in Bewley Models?

From Wages to Welfare: Decomposing Gains and Losses From Rising Inequality

Relating Income to Consumption Part 1

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Consumption and Labor Supply with Partial Insurance: An Analytical Framework

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

Partial Insurance. ECON 34430: Topics in Labor Markets. T. Lamadon (U of Chicago) Fall 2017

HARD VS. SOFT FINANCIAL CONSTRAINTS IMPLICATIONS FOR THE EFFECTS OF A CREDIT CRUNCH

Business Cycles and Household Formation: The Micro versus the Macro Labor Elasticity

Consumption, Working Hours, and Wealth Determination in a Life Cycle Model

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

A simple wealth model

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments

House Prices and Risk Sharing

Excess Smoothness of Consumption in an Estimated Life Cycle Model

Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho

How Much Consumption Insurance in Bewley Models with Endogenous Family Labor Supply?

Wealth inequality, family background, and estate taxation

Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Groupe de Travail: International Risk-Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks

The Idea. Friedman (1957): Permanent Income Hypothesis. Use the Benchmark KS model with Modifications. Income Process. Progress since then

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Aggregate Implications of Wealth Redistribution: The Case of Inflation

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

Euler Equations, Subjective Expectations and Income Shocks

Excess Smoothness of Consumption in an Estimated Life Cycle Model

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Household Finance in China

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

Characterization of the Optimum

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

The Impact of Personal Bankruptcy Law on Entrepreneurship

Income Dynamics and Consumption Insurance

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

Commentary. Thomas MaCurdy. Description of the Proposed Earnings-Supplement Program

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Household income risk, nominal frictions, and incomplete markets 1

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Idiosyncratic risk and the dynamics of aggregate consumption: a likelihood-based perspective

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

Endogenous Money, Inflation and Welfare

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Final Exam. Consumption Dynamics: Theory and Evidence Spring, Answers

How Well Does the U.S. Social Insurance System Provide Social Insurance?

Financial Integration and Growth in a Risky World

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Notes for Econ202A: Consumption

Optimal monetary policy when asset markets are incomplete

INTERTEMPORAL ASSET ALLOCATION: THEORY

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

The Zero Lower Bound

Nonlinear Persistence and Partial Insurance: Income and Consumption Dynamics in the PSID

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

Risk Sharing in Human Capital Models with Limited Enforcement

Enrique Martínez-García. University of Texas at Austin and Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HOW MUCH CONSUMPTION INSURANCE BEYOND SELF-INSURANCE? Greg Kaplan Giovanni L. Violante

Optimal Spatial Taxation

How Do Consumers Respond To Transitory Income Shocks? Reconciling Longitudinal Studies and Natural Experiments

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Robustness Appendix for Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst

Discussion of Heaton and Lucas Can heterogeneity, undiversified risk, and trading frictions solve the equity premium puzzle?

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

1. Operating procedures and choice of monetary policy instrument. 2. Intermediate targets in policymaking. Literature: Walsh (Chapter 11, pp.

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

The Financial Labor Supply Accelerator

A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk. June 2012

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

How Much Competition is a Secondary Market? Online Appendixes (Not for Publication)

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

THE RESPONSE OF HOUSEHOLD SAVING TO THE LARGE SHOCK OF GERMAN REUNIFICATION. Nicola Fuchs-Schündeln

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Amaintained assumption of nearly all macroeconomic analysis is that

Imperfect Information and Market Segmentation Walsh Chapter 5

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership

Household finance in Europe 1

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Cahier de recherche/working Paper Inequality and Debt in a Model with Heterogeneous Agents. Federico Ravenna Nicolas Vincent.

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

How Well Does the U.S. Social Insurance System Provide Social Insurance?

Adjustment Costs, Firm Responses, and Labor Supply Elasticities: Evidence from Danish Tax Records

STOCHASTIC CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL: CANONICAL APPLICATIONS FEBRUARY 19, 2013

A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments

Transcription:

Online Appendix Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle Not intended for publication Alexander Bick Arizona State University Sekyu Choi Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Barcelona GSE and MOVE July 2013 Abstract This appendix contains four sections supplementing the analysis in the main paper. First, we provide a further theoretical result which discusses differences in the level of per-adult equivalent consumption in the Demographics and Single nt model. Second, we show and discuss insurance coefficients in the spirit of Blundell, Pistaferri, and Preston (2008) and Kaplan and Violante (2010) for our benchmark calibration. Third, we report the quantitative results for our benchmark model extended with a pensions system. Fourth, based on the empirical estimates in Attanasio, Banks, Meghir, and Weber (1999) we back out the implied utility weights δ in the Demographics model.

1 Consumption Levels Figure 1a in the paper compares the Single nt model with the Demographics model with δ = φ. One can directly see that the (life-time) level of per-adult equivalent consumption differs between the two models. The following section provides the theoretical explanation for this. Proposition 1. Life-time per-adult equivalent consumption in the Demographics model and Single nt model coincide if and only if κ 2 = φ 2 ( ). 1 (φ 2 1) Y 1 1 CD 1 Y 2 Y1 This result is straightforward to show. Life-time per-adult equivalent consumption in the Demographics model c D is given by =C D 2 {}}{ c D = C D 1 + CD 2 = C D Y 1 + Y 2 C D 1 1 + = φ 2 1 C D 1 + Y 1 + Y 2 (1) φ 2 φ 2 φ 2 φ 2 while in the Single nt model life-time per-adult equivalent consumption c S per-adult equivalent income: equals life-time c S = c S 1 + c S 2 = Y 1 + Y 2 κ 2. (2) Equating Equations (1) and (2) yields the critical value of κ 2 stated in Proposition 1 which also has a very intuitive interpretation. One can directly see from Equations (1) and (2) that when the household in the Demographics model optimally chooses to neither save nor borrow (C D 1 = Y 1), the life-time per-adult equivalent consumption levels in both setups are the same if and only if κ 2 = φ 2. Now consider the case when the household in the Demographics model optimally chooses to be a borrower (C D 1 > Y 1). Assume for a moment that κ 2 is still equal to φ 2 instead of the critical value stated in Proposition 1. In the Demographics model only period two consumption which in this example is smaller than period two income is deflated by the equivalence scale in the calculation of life-time per-adult equivalent consumption. This directly implies a higher life-time per-adult equivalent consumption level in the Demographics model compared to the Single nt model which is determined only by life-time per-adult equivalent income. To undo this, κ 2 has to be decreased below φ 2 in order to increase life-time per-adult equivalent income and thus life-time per-adult equivalent consumption in the Single nt model. While in quantitative work life-time (per-adult equivalent) consumption is not a statistic of 1

primary interest, it is relevant for welfare comparisons between different economic environments. If e.g. a linear income tax rate is raised to finance wasteful government consumption, households in the economy with the lower, pre-reform life-time per-adult equivalent consumption suffer a larger welfare loss with concave utility. Moreover, this statistic highlights a key difference between the Single nt and Demographics model. In the latter the household has total household income at its disposal to allocate between the two periods which then determines life-time per-adult equivalent consumption. In the Single nt model, the income process is exogenously adjusted thus directly restricting life-time per-adult equivalent income (total resources available). This difference becomes particularly obvious when one would consider two types of households (A, B) experiencing differences in the timing of household income, i.e. income y A 1 + ya 2 = yb 1 + yb 2 y A 1 y A 2 yb 1. Even for the same life-time household y2 B, life-time per-adult equivalent incomes differ in the Single nt but not in the Demographics model. This generates inequality in life-time per-adult equivalent consumption in the Single nt model but not in the Demographics model. The derivation and implications of Proposition 1 only depend on the choice of δ 2 in so far that it determines C D 1 equivalent consumption levels. and thus, for a given Y 1 and Y 2, the relationship between the two per-adult 2 Insurance Coefficients In the following section, we consult an alternative statistic closely related to the variance of log per-adult equivalent consumption. We follow Blundell, Pistaferri, and Preston (2008) and Kaplan and Violante (2010) and compute insurance coefficients for each model, a measure of how much consumption comoves with income shocks. For each model we calculate the contemporaneous correlation of changes in consumption and permanent (P ) and transitory (T r) shocks to labor income: ψ x t = 1 cov( log(c t/φ t ), ɛ x t ) var(ɛ x t ) where c t /φ t is per-adult equivalent consumption at age t and x = {P, T r}. The higher the comovement between consumption and unexpected changes in income (represented by the shocks ɛ x ), the lower is the implied value of the insurance coefficient. 2

Figure 1: Insurance Coefficients, Single nt vs. Demographics with δ = φ (a) Permanent Shock (b) Temporary Shock 0.2.4.6.8.6.7.8.9 Single(β Cal. ) Dem. δ=φ Single(β Dem. ) Single(β Cal. ) Dem. δ=φ Single(β Dem. ) 2.1 Demographics model with δ = φ vs. Single nt model Figure 1a shows the insurance coefficient for the permanent income shock for the Demographics model with δ = φ and the two calibrations of the Single nt model (one with the discount factor being calibrated and one with the same discount factor as in the Demographics model). The life-cycle profiles of the insurance coefficients for the permanent shock mirrors the one for the log variance of per-adult equivalent consumption (Figure 1b in the paper). They are hardly distinguishable across the three simulations until the mid 30s, and diverge subsequently. The Single nt model with the calibrated β displays a higher variance of log per-adult equivalent consumption, i.e. a higher consumption inequality, and the insurance coefficient is lower, i.e. peradult equivalent consumption fluctuates more with the permanent income shock. The overall shape of these profiles is in line with the findings by Kaplan and Violante (2010). As households age and accumulate more assets they can better insulate their consumption from income shocks. Moreover, as the retirement age gets closer, the permanent shocks loose in some sense their permanent nature, e.g. in the last period of working life the permanent shock is effectively a transitory shock. Figure 1b compares the insurance coefficients for the transitory income shocks. Per-adult equivalent consumption comoves to a much lesser degree with transitory income shocks than with permanent income shocks. At age 26 the coefficients are between 0.6 and 0.7 for the transitory shock compared to less than 0.1 for the permanent shock. From the mid 40s onwards the insurance coeffi- 3

cients are very similar across the three models. When holding fixed the discount factor, households in the Demographics model are less insulated against transitory income shocks than in the Single nt model because of the lower effective return to savings and thus higher costs of providing insurance. The Single nt model calibrated to match the empirical wealth to income ratio has a lower discount factor. This higher preference for current consumption makes per-adult equivalent consumption by construction react more to income shocks (higher comovement, lower coefficient). Finally, the overall pattern looks closer to the case with a zero borrowing constraint in Kaplan and Violante (2010). The lack of a redistributive pension system in our benchmark analysis induces households to accumulate savings right from the start of their life rather than to smooth transitory shocks by going into debt. To sum up, the permanent insurance coefficients are basically replicating the informational content of the variance of log per-adult equivalent consumption shown in the paper. The differences between the insurance coefficients for the transitory income shocks until the mid 40s are much larger than for any statistic we have reported. Since households can self-insure these types of shocks relatively well, these differences do not change our conclusion that the Single nt model does not miss much relative to the Demographics model. 2.2 Different Specifications of the Demographics Model Figure 2a shows the insurance coefficient for the permanent income shock for the three specifications of the Demographics model. Similar to the variance of log per-adult equivalent consumption consumption, the insurance coefficients are virtually the same. Figure 2b compares the insurance coefficients for the transitory income shocks. From age 40 onwards the insurance coefficients are very similar across the three models. During the 20s and 30s, the higher preference for current consumption for the δ = 1 specification makes consumption move more than for the δ = N speficiation. These differences, albeit being larger than in the previous case, remain of second order magnitude. 4

Figure 2: Insurance Coefficients, Different Specifications of the Demographics Model (a) Permanent Shock (b) Temporary Shock 0.2.4.6.8.6.7.8.9 δ=1 δ=φ δ=n δ=1 δ=φ δ=n 3 Introducing Pensions Our benchmark calibration abstracts from pensions. Here we show the results with the same redistributive pension system as in Storesletten, Telmer, and Yaron (2004). Pensions are fully funded by a proportional tax on labor income. Pensions themselves depend on average income over the life-cycle as follows: p(ȳ i ) = 0.90 min {ȳ i, 0.3ȳ} if ȳ i 4.1ȳ + 0.32 (min {ȳ i, 2.0ȳ} 0.3ȳ) if 0.3ȳ < ȳ i 4.1ȳ + 0.15 (min {ȳ i, 4.1ȳ} 2.0ȳ) if 2.0ȳ < ȳ i 4.1ȳ 1.10ȳ if ȳ i > 4.1ȳ, where ȳ i is the individual average of life-time earnings and ȳ is the average of cross-sectional earnings in the economy. Households with an average life-time income more than 4.1 times the average cross-sectional earnings receive a pension of 1.1 times the average cross-sectional earnings. Household with average life-time earnings below this threshold receive a replacement rate of 90% for any fraction of their life-time earnings that falls below 30% of average cross-sectional earnings. Any fraction of life-time earnings above this threshold and below twice average cross-sectional earnings is replaced at a rate of 32% and any fraction of life-time earnings between 2 and 4.1 times the average cross-sectional earnings is replaced at a rate of 15%. 5

Figure 3: Single nt vs. Demographics with δ = φ and US style pension system Per-Adult Equivalent Consumption (a) Mean (b) Variance (of Log) 20000 30000 40000 50000.1.2.3.4.5.6.7.8 70 Single(β Cal. ) Dem. δ=φ Single(β Dem. ) 70 Single(β Cal. ) Dem. δ=φ Single(β Dem. ) Insurance Coefficients (c) Permanent Shock (d) Temporary Shock.2.4.6.8 1 Single(β Cal. ) Dem. δ=φ Single(β Dem. ).92.93.94.95.96 Single(β Cal. ) Dem. δ=φ Single(β Dem. ) 6

During working life households in the Demographics model receive household income whereas in the Single nt model households receive household income divided by the adjustment factor κ, i.e. per-adult equivalent income. We maintain this analogy during retirement. A household in the Single nt model who experiences the same sequence of permanent and transitory income shocks as a corresponding household in the Demographics model is assigned the same pension as the household in Demographics model, but divided by the adjustment factor κ. We leave all preference parameters and prices as in our benchmark simulation without a pension system. But as before, we calibrate for each simulation the discount factor β in order to generate a wealth to income ratio of 3.1. Since the introduction of a redistributive pension system reduces the savings motive for retirement, all discount factors increase relative to the respective setting without a pension system. 3.1 Demographics model with δ = φ vs. Single nt model The calibrated βs for the Demographics model with δ = φ and the Single nt model are 1.0 and 0.999, respectively, which generate upward sloping consumption profiles even during retirement, see Figure 3a. Consumption inequality is reduced substantially compared to the no pension economies, specifically during retirement, see Figure 3b. Since the calibrated discount factors are virtually identical in the Demographics and Single nt model, the specification of the Single nt model with the same discount factor as in the Demographics model produces virtually the same results as the Single nt model with the calibrated discount factor. Put differently, in contrast to the scenario without pensions, only the difference in the effective interest rate matters. Thus, because of the lower effective interest rate and higher cost of providing insurance the variance of log peradult equivalent consumption is now larger in the Demographics model over the entire life-cycle with a difference of 4% during retirement. This is also reflected in lower insurance coefficients for both shocks, although the differences are fairly small, see Figures 3c and 3d. It is worthwhile to mention that with the pension system in place, the insurance coefficients look more similar to those in Kaplan and Violante (2010) with the natural borrowing constraint. Households now do in fact borrow during the early part of life and thus are better insured against income shocks, specifically transitory ones. 7

Figure 4: Different Specifications of the Demographics Model with US style pension system Per-Adult Equivalent Consumption (a) Mean (b) Variance (of Log) 20000 30000 40000 50000.1.2.3.4.5.6.7.8 70 δ=1 δ=φ δ=n 70 δ=1 δ=φ δ=n Insurance Coefficients (c) Permanent Shock (d) Temporary Shock.2.4.6.8 1 δ=1 δ=φ δ=n.92.93.94.95.96 δ=1 δ=φ δ=n 8

3.2 Different Specifications of the Demographics Model The calibrated discount factors are β = 0.992 for δ = 1, β = 1.0 for δ = φ and β = 1.01 for δ = N. The qualitative and quantitative differences across the three different choices for δ are similar to those obtained without a pension system, see Figures 4a and 4b. As in the previous subsection, the pattern for the insurance coefficients are similar to those in Kaplan and Violante (2010) with the natural borrowing constraint, see Figures 4c and 4d. 4 Some Empirical Evidence As already mentioned, Attanasio, Banks, Meghir, and Weber (1999) (henceforth ABMW) introduce a general taste shifter to capture the impact of household size on the marginal utility of per-adult equivalent consumption u(c t, N t ) = exp(ξn t )u (C t ). (3) while preferences in our model are ( ) C u(c D D t, N t ) = δ(n t )u t. (4) φ(n t ) Despite the fact that the choice of δ does not generate important differences for key model predictions - as long as being calibrated to match aggregate moments - ABMW s results provide some empirical guidance for the choice of the utility weight δ. With CRRA preferences and a given coefficient of relative risk aversion, their specification of the utility function coincides with the one used in our exercise if the following relationship holds: exp (ζ 1 [N ad 1] + ζ 2 N ch ) = δ(n ad, N ch ), (5) φ(n ad, N ch ) 1 α where we normalize the taste shifter from ABMW to one for households of size one. ABMW loglinearize the Euler equation implied by Equation (3), assuming that households can borrow up to the natural borrowing constraint, and estimate ζ 1, ζ 2, and α from CEX data. With those estimates (ˆζ 1 = 0.71, ˆζ 2 = 0.34 and α = 1.57) at hand, one can back out the δ that solves Equation (5) for a given household size and composition, and a given equivalence scale φ (henceforth labeled as 9

Figure 5: Utility Weights for various Equivalence scales (a) Two Adults, Two Children (b) Life-Cycle Averages δ 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 δ OECD NAS SQR HHS DOC LM NELS. Equivalence Scale δ ABMW δ = 1 δ = φ δ = N ad δ = N ad +N ch OECD NAS SQR HHS DOC LM NELS. Equivalence Scale δ ABMW δ = 1 δ = φ δ = N ad δ = N ad +N ch δ ABMW ). We calculate the implied δ for each of the seven equivalence scales discussed in Fernández- Villaverde and Krueger (2007) and compare them to the set of δs used in applied work. We use the Square Root Scale instead of the Mean scale in Fernández-Villaverde and Krueger (2007) as the two are almost identical. Figure 5a refers to a household with two adults and two children. The horizontal axis displays the seven equivalences scales ordered from the lowest economies of scale (OECD) to the highest economies of scale (Nelson), whereas the vertical axes refers to the values the various δs take. The four lines refer to the set of δs used in applied work. All δs {1, N ad, N = N ad + N ch } are independent of the respective equivalence scale and therefore parallel to the horizontal axis. δ = φ, the solid line, obviously varies with the equivalence scale. Finally, the crosses refer to the δ ABMW implied by the estimates in ABMW for a given equivalence scale. The figure has to be read as follows: for the OECD scale δ ABMW is closest to δ = N ad, whereas for the NAS scale it is virtually identical to δ = φ. Overall, δ = φ and δ = N ad (number of adults in the household) most closely resemble the δ implied by the estimates in ABMW for the equivalence scales featuring low to medium economies of scale (OECD to DOC), whereas for the equivalence scales featuring high economies of scale (LM and Nelson) δ = N ad + N ch (household size) stands out. Figure 5b shows the life-cycle averages for each possible δ using the household size and composition profiles from our quantitative analysis, i.e. 95 1 71 t=25 δ(n ad,t, N ch,t ). Again, δ = N ad is relatively close to all equivalence scales, whereas δ = φ only for those scales featuring low to 10

medium economies of scale. All this together suggest to not use the extreme choices for δ, namely one and household size. However, this conclusion relies on taking the estimates by Attanasio, Banks, Meghir, and Weber (1999) for ξ 1, ξ 2 and the coefficient of risk aversion at face value. References Attanasio, O. P., J. Banks, C. Meghir, and G. Weber (1999): Humps and Bumps in Lifetime Consumption, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 17, 22 35. Blundell, R., L. Pistaferri, and I. Preston (2008): Consumption Inequality and Partial Insurance, American Economic Review, 98, 1887 1921. Fernández-Villaverde, J., and D. Krueger (2007): Consumption over the Life Cycle: Facts from Consumer Expenditure Survey Data, Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(3), 552 565. Kaplan, G., and G. L. Violante (2010): How Much Consumption Insurance Beyond Self- Insurance?, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(4), 53 87. Storesletten, K., C. I. Telmer, and A. Yaron (2004): Consumption and risk sharing over the life cycle, Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(3), pp. 609 633. 11