Misspecification, Identification or Measurement? Another Look at the Price Puzzle

Similar documents
Effects of monetary policy shocks on the trade balance in small open European countries

The role of house prices in the monetary policy transmission mechanism in the U.S.

IMPACT OF SOME OVERSEAS MONETARY VARIABLES ON INDONESIA: SVAR APPROACH

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Asian Economic and Financial Review SOURCES OF EXCHANGE RATE FLUCTUATION IN VIETNAM: AN APPLICATION OF THE SVAR MODEL

Monetary Policy Shock Analysis Using Structural Vector Autoregression

THE PRICE PUZZLE AND VAR IDENTIFICATION

Empirical Effects of Monetary Policy and Shocks. Valerie A. Ramey

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Structural Cointegration Analysis of Private and Public Investment

COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY GRADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS. Professor Frederic S. Mishkin Fall 1999 Uris Hall 619 Extension:

Not-for-Publication Appendix to:

CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL*

Estimating a Monetary Policy Rule for India

Measuring the Channels of Monetary Policy Transmission: A Factor-Augmented Vector Autoregressive (Favar) Approach

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

Interest Rate Smoothing and Calvo-Type Interest Rate Rules: A Comment on Levine, McAdam, and Pearlman (2007)

Testing the Stickiness of Macroeconomic Indicators and Disaggregated Prices in Japan: A FAVAR Approach

Effects of US Monetary Policy Shocks During Financial Crises - A Threshold Vector Autoregression Approach

Do Fed Forecast Errors Matter?

Monetary policy transmission in Switzerland: Headline inflation and asset prices

Uncertainty and the Transmission of Fiscal Policy

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

MONETARY ECONOMICS Objective: Overview of Theoretical, Empirical and Policy Issues in Modern Monetary Economics

Macro shocks and real stock prices

No Matthias Neuenkirch. Monetary Policy Transmission in Vector Autoregressions: A New Approach Using Central Bank Communication

ON THE LONG-TERM MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF SOCIAL SPENDING IN THE UNITED STATES (*) Alfredo Marvão Pereira The College of William and Mary

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Commodity Prices and BRIC and G3 Liquidity: A SFAVEC Approach

The Price Puzzle and Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism in Pakistan: Structural Vector Autoregressive Approach

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

The Transmission of International Shocks: A Factor-Augmented VAR Approach

Inflation Targeting and the Anchoring of Inflation Expectations: Cross-country Evidence from Consensus Forecasts *

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Do Fed Forecast Errors Matter?

Volume 35, Issue 4. Real-Exchange-Rate-Adjusted Inflation Targeting in an Open Economy: Some Analytical Results

The Effects of Japanese Monetary Policy Shocks on Exchange Rates: A Structural Vector Error Correction Model Approach

New evidence on the effects of US monetary policy on exchange rates

Exchange Rates and Uncovered Interest Differentials: The Role of Permanent Monetary Shocks. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Martín Uribe

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Vector Autoregressions. September 7, 2016

The Limits of Monetary Policy Under Imperfect Knowledge

ECON : Topics in Monetary Economics

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH

Review over Empirical Evidence on Real Effects of Monetary Policy

Discussion of DSGE Models for Monetary Policy. Discussion of

For Online Publication. The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix

The Transmission of International Shocks: A Factor Augmented VAR Approach

A Note on the Oil Price Trend and GARCH Shocks

DEMB Working Paper Series N. 24. Sources of Unemployment Fluctuations in the USA and in the Euro Area in the Last Decade.

University of Pretoria Department of Economics Working Paper Series

The effect of monetary policy on housing tenure choice as an explanation for the price puzzle

Monetary Policy and Long-term U.S. Interest Rates

Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure, and Debt in Sri Lanka : A Vector Autoregressive Model Analysis

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

The International Transmission of Euro Area Monetary Policy Shocks. by Nils Jannsen and Melanie Klein

Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? *

Asian Economic and Financial Review EMPIRICAL TESTING OF EXCHANGE RATE AND INTEREST RATE TRANSMISSION CHANNELS IN CHINA

Practical Issues in Monetary Policy Targeting

Monetary Policy Analysis. Bennett T. McCallum* Carnegie Mellon University. and. National Bureau of Economic Research.

PUTTING M BACK IN MONETARY POLICY

COMMENTS ON MONETARY POLICY UNDER UNCERTAINTY IN MICRO-FOUNDED MACROECONOMETRIC MODELS, BY A. LEVIN, A. ONATSKI, J. WILLIAMS AND N.

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE PUBLIC DEBT RELEVANCE TO THE ECONOMIC GROWTH OF THE USA

Structural Vector Autoregressive Analysis of Monetary Policy in Thailand

Reassessing Exchange Rate Overshooting in a Monetary Framework

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

How do Macroeconomic Shocks affect Expectations? Lessons from Survey Data

The Effects of Oil Shocks on Turkish Macroeconomic Aggregates

Gauging Taylor rules: Do differences make a difference?

Information Technology, Productivity, Value Added, and Inflation: An Empirical Study on the U.S. Economy,

BANK LOAN COMPONENTS AND THE TIME-VARYING EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY SHOCKS

Monetary policy rule and its performance under inflation targeting: the evidence of Thailand

Central bank losses and monetary policy rules: a DSGE investigation

EE 631: MONETARY ECONOMICS 2 nd Semester 2013

Is the Exchange Rate a Shock Absorber or Source of Shocks? New Empirical Evidence

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

Oil prices and the economy: A global perspective

MONETARY POLICY TRANSMISSION MECHANISM IN ROMANIA OVER THE PERIOD 2001 TO 2012: A BVAR ANALYSIS

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

A Simple Recursive Forecasting Model

Vector Autoregression Model of Monetary Policy for India and the Case of Inflation Targeting 1. Introduction

A comparison of two housing markets

The Liquidity Effect in Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems. Johann Scharler *) Working Paper No October 2007

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

Determinacy, Stock Market Dynamics and Monetary Policy Inertia Pfajfar, Damjan; Santoro, Emiliano

Does money matter in the euro area?: Evidence from a new Divisia index 1. Introduction

Regional Business Cycles In the United States

The Systematic Component of Monetary Policy in SVARs: An Agnostic Identification Procedure

Stepping on a rake: The role of fiscal policy in the inflation of the 1970s. Chris Sims

Monetary policy analysis in an inflation targeting framework in emerging economies: The case of India

How do stock prices respond to fundamental shocks?

Monetary Policy Matters: New Evidence Based on a New Shock Measure

Analysis of monetary policy variables with stock returns using var frame work

There is considerable interest in determining whether monetary policy

Do core inflation measures help forecast inflation? Out-of-sample evidence from French data

Test of the bank lending channel: The case of Hungary

Macroeconometricians do four things: describe and summarize macroeconomic

Growth Rate of Domestic Credit and Output: Evidence of the Asymmetric Relationship between Japan and the United States

Transcription:

Department of Economics Working Paper Series Misspecification, Identification or Measurement? Another Look at the Price Puzzle Shuyun May Li, Roshan Perera and Kalvinder Shields JAN 2013 Research Paper Number 1169 ISSN: 0819 2642 ISBN: 978 0 7340 4520 1 Department of Economics The University of Melbourne Parkville VIC 3010 www.economics.unimelb.edu.au

Misspecification, Identification or Measurement? Another Look at the Price Puzzle by Shuyun May Li, Roshan Perera and Kalvinder Shields Abstract This paper re-examines the VAR analysis of the price puzzle with regard to the issues of measurement, identification and misspecification. In an empirical analysis conducted for the US economy, we consider alternative measures of economic activity and inflation, alternative assumptions to identify the monetary policy shock and various VAR specifications making use of contemporaneous and forward looking variables. All three issues are found to be important for the resolution of the price puzzle and a robust preferred specification is proposed. Keywords: Price puzzle, Monetary policy, Output gap, Expectations. JEL Classification: E52, E31, C32. Shuyun May Li (shuyunl@unimelb.edu.au) and Kalvinder Shields, corresponding author, (k.shields@unimelb.edu.au), University of Melbourne, Australia; Roshan Perera, Central Bank of Sri Lanka, Sri Lanka (roshan@cbsl.lk). 1

1 Introduction The anomalous response of a rise in prices following a contractionary monetary policy shock, referred to as the price puzzle, has been documented in a large number of empirical studies conducted using the Vector Autoregressive (VAR) modelling framework (Sims, 1992 and Eichenbaum, 1992). Solutions proposed within this framework to resolve the price puzzle emphasize the issue of misspecified VAR models and their ability to correctly identify a monetary policy innovation (e.g., see Sims, 1992 and Giordani, 2004). However, such ability also hinges on the identification scheme adopted to identify the monetary policy shock and the measurement of variables included in the VAR, as suggested by the vast VAR literature on monetary policy. The identification issue concerns the plausible definition of the monetary policy innovation whilst the issues of measurement and misspecification concern the accuracy of the estimated monetary policy shock. These three categories, therefore, provide a useful framework to discuss the empirical consistency of various solutions to the price puzzle. The measurement issue concerns the statistical measures of variables used in the estimation of the respective VAR. Although not formally discussed in the prize puzzle literature, this is a common concern in macroeconomic modelling or for forecasting purposes where variant measures of variables, say, output gap and inflation, can have markedly differing implications. For instance, Orphanides and van Norden (2002), Watson (2007) and Garratt et al (2008) highlight the uncertainties and sensitivities in a forecasting context surrounding various popular output gap measures. Orphanides (2001) demonstrates that theperformanceofthetaylorruleincapturinginterest rate movements is considerably reduced when the real-time measures of output gap are used. Likewise, measurement issues surround the appropriate measure of inflation; even once-preferred measures of inflation by monetary authorities may change over time (Orphanides and Wieland, 2008). The identification issue concerns the definition of the monetary shock in the VAR. Whilst there is little consensus, typically a recursive ordering identification scheme is assumed on a VAR consisting of a measure of economic activity, inflation and the interest rate as the minimal information set (Sims, 1980). Although consistent with a standard [1]

Taylor rule (Christiano et al. 1999), the scheme is inconsistent with the New Keynesian class of theoretical models (Carlstrom et al, 2009). Various non-recursive identification schemes have been adopted in the price puzzle literature, ranging from assuming a general form indicated by theory (Sims and Zha, 2006, Kim, 1999) to the imposition of long-run restrictions (Clarida and Gali, 1994) and the inclusion of additional short-run restrictions (Bjornland and Leitemo, 2009). Further alternative operational schemes pay attention to the timing of actual information flows in the economy (Orphanides, 2001 and Garratt et al, 2006). The misspecification issue relates to the inclusion of all the variables in the information set of the monetary authority. Popular omitted variables in the literature include commodity prices (Sims, 1992 and Christiano et al, 1996) and principal components extracted from relevant macroeconomic series (Bernanke et al, 2005). Survey measures of expected output and inflation are also thought to be important forward looking variables that should be considered (Castelnouvo and Surico, 2010). Misspecification also concerns the use of appropriate variables; Giordani (2004) and Hanson (2004) propose the use of the output gap instead of output to resolve the price puzzle, for instance. Consideration of all possible combinations reflecting the three issues is clearly an exhaustive task. This paper therefore selects meaningful combinations of variables, identification schemes and measures of variables to provide insights into the contribution of relevant variables and the economically meaningful structures in resolving the price puzzle. In particular, the robustness of the output gap solution proposed in Giordani (2004) to alternative measures of variables and identification schemes is examined and a robust preferred VAR specification is proposed. 2 An Empirical Analysis of the Price Puzzle for the US The empirical analysis estimates alternative VAR models that consider various measures of variables, identification schemes and specifications to examine whether or not a price puzzle is present under various model specifications. The empirical analysis is conducted using quarterly data for the US over the sample period 1967q1 to 2010q2. A description of the data series is given in the Data Appendix. [2]

2 Measurement We first investigate the robustness of the output gap solution proposed in Giordani (2004) to alternative measures of output gap and inflation. We consider a simple VAR model consisting of output gap, inflation and interest rate X t =[y g t,π t,r t ]. The VAR model is estimated using two alternative measures of the output gap: the Congressional Budget Office measure (y g CBO t ) and the Greenbook real time measure (yt g GB ), two popular measures of inflation: the rate of change in the CPI (πt CPI ) and the rate of change in the GDP deflator (πt GDP ), and the monetary policy shock is identified using a typical recursive ordering. Figure 1 displays the impulse response functions of inflation to a one standard deviation interest rate innovation from the estimated VAR model over four combinations of the respective measures (the dashed lines represent +/ two standard error bands). Table 1 summarizes the results with regard to whether or not a price puzzle is observed. Figure 1 shows that the two measures of the output gap do not produce a significant difference in the dynamic response of inflation to the interest rate innovation, whilst a significant difference is observed for the two measures of inflation. With the πt CPI measure and either measure of the output gap, the impulse responses of inflation suggest a price puzzle which is close to being statistically significant when yt g GB is used. In contrast, with πt GDP,a price puzzle is not produced, although there is a prolonged response of inflation to the interest rate innovation. These results suggest that the GDP deflator measure of inflation enables a more accurate estimate of the monetary policy shock. Insert Fig 1 and Table 1 here 2 Identification We then investigate the sensitivity of the output gap solution to an alternative identification scheme. The recursive ordering scheme used above assumes that the monetary authority has contemporaneous information about output and inflation when setting the policy instrument. This scheme has been criticized for being inconsistent with the ac- [3]

tual timing of information flows (McCallum, 1999 and Orphanides, 2001). An alternative scheme that is also widely adopted (Leeper et al, 1996, Sims and Zha, 2006 and Garret et al, 2006) is to assume that the interest rate is set based on information on output and inflation from the previous period. This identification scheme is relatively more general in that it assumes that the monetary policy instrument is not contemporaneously affected by movements in output and prices. This structure is reflected in the VAR model X t =[r t,y g t,π t ] with zero restrictions imposed only on the first row of the contemporaneous matrix (i.e., the first row reads as [1 0 0]). Figure 2 plots the impulse responses of inflation to an interest rate innovation from the estimated VAR model over the four combinations of the alternative measures of the output gap and inflation and Table 2 summarizes the results. A striking finding is that the change in the identification scheme leads to significant differences in the dynamic response of inflation to the interest rate innovation, at least over the short horizon. A price puzzle is now observed in all cases. significant when the π CPI t In particular, the price puzzle is large and measure of inflation is used. When the π GDP t measure of inflation is used, the dynamic responses of inflation exhibit a smaller price puzzle which is also marginally significant. Further, in contrast to Figure 1, the impulse responses seem to be more plausible given the shorter duration associated with the dissipation of the interest rate innovation. These results imply that the ability of the output gap to resolve the price puzzle crucially depends on the assumptions used to identify the monetary policy shock. Insert Fig 2 and Table 2 here 2.3 Misspecification Finally,weexaminethemisspecification issue by comparing impulse responses of inflation to an interest rate innovation generated from several specifications. The first comparison concerns the choice of whether to include output growth or the output gap in the VAR model, which is motivated by the finding in Giordani (2004) in that it is the use of output instead of output gap that generates a price puzzle. Another comparison concerns the [4]

importance of augmenting the VAR with timely forward-looking information available to decision-makers, such as direct measures of expected future inflation and output growth. The use of expected inflation and output growth instead of other indicator variables that may contain information on future inflation and output can be justified on several grounds. First, whilst the inclusion of the typical indicator variables, such as commodity prices, have weak theoretical basis, the addition of direct measures of expectations is very much in keeping with standard New Keynesian models and have strong theoretical foundations in the analysis of monetary policy (Lubik and Schorfheide, 2004, Gali and Gertler, 2007). Second, the direct measures of expectations far outperform other forecasts of inflation (see Hanson, 2004 and Ang, Bekaert and Wei, 2007). Third, the inclusion of expectation variables provides a means to improve the measurement of the monetary policy shock in the presence of a change in monetary policy regime. Rather than conducting an analysis on sub-samples (see Castelnuovo and Surico, 2010) or working within a nonlinear framework, inflation expectations can be used in the VAR to capture the additional information on future inflation that is not reflected in current inflation and thereby improve the specification of the VAR model. This is especially relevant for monetary policy regimes that are considered to be passive. In terms of the identification scheme we assume that contemporaneous values of macroeconomic variables are not available when forecasts are made, while the forecasts of inflation and output are available to policy-makers when interest rates are set. 1 Figure 3 plots the impulse responses of inflationtoaninterestrateinnovationfromthe following estimated VAR models: ³ ³ ³ ey t,πt GDP,r t, rt, ey t,πt, GDP Et π t+1,e t y t+1, ey t,πt GDP,r t, ³ Et π t+1,e t y t+1,r t, ey t,πt, GDP whereeyt takes the form of either y t or yt g CBO ;Table3 summarizes the results. Several clear findings emerge from these results. First, the addition of the expectation variables either eliminates or substantially mitigates the positive response of inflation to the interest rate innovation for both identification schemes. This highlights the importance of including direct measures of expectations in the VAR specification for a more accurate measure of the monetary policy shock. Second, including output gap instead of output growth yields a smaller positive response of inflation, although 1 This is the assumption adopted in Leduc, Sill and Stark (2007) and Mehra and Herrington (2008). [5]

the degree of uncertainty indicated by the confidence bands is of a similar magnitude. However, including output growth seems to produce more sensible dynamic responses of inflation to the interest rate innovation with a more reasonable rate of dissipation of the impact. With regard to the misspecification issue, these results suggest that the preferred specification would be one that includes direct measures of expectations and with output growth as a measure for economic activity. Insert Fig 3 and Table 3 here 3 Conclusion With regard to the identification issue, the previously proposed output gap solution was found to be markedly sensitive to a more general identification scheme. With regard to the accuracy of the estimated monetary policy shock, concerning both the measurement and misspecification issues, the paper found that the preferred VAR specification is one that includes direct measures of expectations, output growth as a measure of economic activity and the GDP deflator as a measure of inflation. Further, this specification was found to be robust to the two identification schemes considered. [6]

References Ang, A., Bekaert, G., Wei, M., 2007. Do macro variables, asset markets, or surveys forecast inflation better? Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(4), 1163-1212. Bernanke, B.S., Boivin, J., Eliasz, P. S., 2005. Measuring the effects of monetary policy: A factor-augmented vector autoregressive (FAVAR) approach. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(1), 387-422. Bjørnland, H.C., Leitemo, K., 2009. Identifying the interdependence between US monetary policy and the stock market. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(2), 275-282. Carlstrom, C. T., Fuerst, T. S., Paustian, M., 2009. Monetary policy shocks, choleski identification and DNK models. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(7), 1014-1021. Castelnuovo, E., Surico, P., 2010. Monetary policy, inflation expectations and the price puzzle. Economic Journal, 120(549), 1262-1283. Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C.L., 1996. The effects of monetary policy shocks: evidence from the flow of funds. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1), 16-34. Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C. L., 1999. Monetary policyshocks: what have we learned and to what end? In Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. Taylor, J. B. Woodford, M., Volume 1A, 65-148. New York and Oxford: Elsevier Science. Clarida, R., Gali, J., 1994. Sources of real exchange rate fluctuations: how important are nominal shocks? Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 41(1), 1-56. Eichenbaum, M., 1992. Comments on Interpreting the macroeconomic time series facts: The effects of monetary policy. European Economic Review, 36(5), 1001-1011. [7]

Garratt, A., Lee, K., Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y., 2006. Global and national macroeconometric modelling: A long run structural approach. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. Garratt, A., Lee, K., Mise, E., Shields, K., 2008. Real-time representations of the output gap. Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), 792-804. Giordani, P., 2004. An alternative explanation of the price puzzle. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(6), 1271-1296. Hanson, M.S., 2004. The price puzzle reconsidered. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(7), 1385-1413. Kim, S., 1999. Do monetary policy shocks matter in the G-7 countries? Using common identifying assumptions about monetary policy across countries. Journal of International Economics 48(2), 387-412. Leeper,E.M.,Sims,C.A.,Zha,T.,Hall,R.E.,Bernanke,B.S.,1996.Whatdoes monetary policy do? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1996(2), 1-78. Lubik, T. A., Schorfheide, F., 2004. Testing for Indeterminacy: An Application to U.S. Monetary Policy. American Economic Review, 94(1), 190-217. McCallum, B.T., 1999. Issues in the design of monetary policy rules. In Handbook of Macroeconomics, ed. Taylor, J.B., Woodford, M., Volume 1C, 1483-1530. Amsterdam; New York and Oxford: Elsevier Science. Orphanides, A., 2001. Monetary policy rules based on real-time data. American Economic Review, 91(4), 964-985. Orphanides, A., van Norden, S., 2002. The unreliability of output gap estimates in real time. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84, 4, 569-583. Orphanides, A., Wieland, V., 2008. Economic projections and rules of thumb for monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 90(4), 307-324. [8]

Sims, C. A., 1980. Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica, 48(1), 1-48. Sims, C.A., 1992. Interpreting the macroeconomic time series facts: The effects of monetary policy. European Economic Review, 36(5), 975-1000. Sims, C.A., Zha, T.A., 2006. Does monetary policy generate recessions? Macroeconomic Dynamics 10(2), 231-71. Watson, M. W., 2007. How accurate are real-time estimates of output trends and gaps? Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, 93,143-161. [9]

Data Appendix Description of Data Variable Units Period Frequency Real GDP (y t) bns of chained 2000 $ 1967:1-2010:2 Quarterly Consumer Price Index (π CPI t ) Index 1982-84=100 1967:1-2010:2 3 mth average Fed Funds Rate (r) per cent 1967:1-2010:2 3 mth average GDP deflator (π GDP t ) Index 2000=100 1967:1-2010:2 Quarterly CBO measure of potential GDP (y g CBO t ) bns of chained 2000 $ 1967:1-2010:2 Quarterly Greenbook real time measure of output gap (y g GB t ) per cent 1987:3-2004:4 Quarterly Greenbook forecasts of inflation (E t π t+1 ) annualised percentage points 1968:3-2004:4 Quarterly Greenbook forecasts of output growth (E t y t+1 ) annualised percentage points 1968:3-2004:4 Quarterly Notes: The Greenbook projections of inflation and output growth are one quarter ahead forecasts of the quarter by quarter rates of change in the chain weighted GNP/GDP price index and real GNP/GDP, respectively. All the Greenbook projections are available from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. The CBO measure of potential GDP is obtained from the Congressional Budget Office. All other data are from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Database. The output growth rate, the federal funds rate, and both measures of inflation are generally treated as stationary series in the literature. 2 Standard tests for unit root suggest that both measures of the output gap considered are stationary. For all the VAR models estimated, the optimal lag length is chosen to be two lags by the Schwarz and Hannan-Quinn criteria. 2 Unit root tests on the stationarity of the two measures of inflation for the sample period 1967q1 2010q2 produce mixed results, however, see Henry and Shields (2004) for a detailed examination on this issue. [10]

Tables and Figures.3 ( ) (.3 ).3 ( ) (.3 ) Figure 1: Impulse response functions of inflation to an interest rate innovation for the VAR model: ( ) [15]

Table 1 Response of inflation to an interest rate innovation for the VAR model: ( ) Measure of Measure of Price Output gap Inflation Puzzle CBO CPI Yes (not significant) CBO GDP No (not significant) GB CPI Yes (not significant) GB GDP No (not significant) [16]

.6.5.4.3 ( ) (.6.5.4.3 ).6.5.4.3 ( ) (.6.5.4.3 ) Figure 2: Impulse response functions of inflation to an interest rate innovation for the VAR model: ( ) [17]

Table 2 Response of inflation to an interest rate innovation for the VAR model: ( ) Measure of Measure of Price Output gap Inflation Puzzle CBO CPI Yes (significant) CBO GDP Yes (not significant) GB CPI Yes (significant) GB GDP Yes (significant) [18]

.3 -.4.3 ( ) - ( ( ) ( ) ) -.4 -.4 ( +1 +1 ) ( +1 +1 ) ( +1 +1 ) ( +1 +1 ) Figure 3: Impulse response functions of inflation to an interest rate innovation for alternative specifications of VAR models [19]

Table 3 Response of inflation to an interest rate innovation for alternative VAR specifications VAR Price Puzzle Yes (not significant) No Yes (not significant) Yes (not significant) +1 +1 No +1 +1 No +1 +1 +1 +1 Yes (not significant) No [20]