Martingale representation theorem

Similar documents
Economics has never been a science - and it is even less now than a few years ago. Paul Samuelson. Funeral by funeral, theory advances Paul Samuelson

RMSC 4005 Stochastic Calculus for Finance and Risk. 1 Exercises. (c) Let X = {X n } n=0 be a {F n }-supermartingale. Show that.

Risk Neutral Measures

Stochastic calculus Introduction I. Stochastic Finance. C. Azizieh VUB 1/91. C. Azizieh VUB Stochastic Finance

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

Stochastic Dynamical Systems and SDE s. An Informal Introduction

THE MARTINGALE METHOD DEMYSTIFIED

Drunken Birds, Brownian Motion, and Other Random Fun

STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL

Valuation of derivative assets Lecture 8

A No-Arbitrage Theorem for Uncertain Stock Model

PAPER 27 STOCHASTIC CALCULUS AND APPLICATIONS

Stochastic Processes and Stochastic Calculus - 9 Complete and Incomplete Market Models

Equivalence between Semimartingales and Itô Processes

Weierstrass Institute for Applied Analysis and Stochastics Maximum likelihood estimation for jump diffusions

Enlargement of filtration

Math 416/516: Stochastic Simulation

Stochastic modelling of electricity markets Pricing Forwards and Swaps

Stochastic Differential equations as applied to pricing of options

KØBENHAVNS UNIVERSITET (Blok 2, 2011/2012) Naturvidenskabelig kandidateksamen Continuous time finance (FinKont) TIME ALLOWED : 3 hours

The stochastic calculus

Risk, Return, and Ross Recovery

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

Continuous Time Finance. Tomas Björk

Chapter 3: Black-Scholes Equation and Its Numerical Evaluation

An Introduction to Point Processes. from a. Martingale Point of View

BROWNIAN MOTION II. D.Majumdar

Risk Neutral Valuation

4 Risk-neutral pricing

Exponential martingales and the UI martingale property

1 Mathematics in a Pill 1.1 PROBABILITY SPACE AND RANDOM VARIABLES. A probability triple P consists of the following components:

SPDE and portfolio choice (joint work with M. Musiela) Princeton University. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Option Pricing with Long Memory Stochastic Volatility Models

Stochastic Calculus, Application of Real Analysis in Finance

Partial differential approach for continuous models. Closed form pricing formulas for discretely monitored models

Hedging of swaptions in a Lévy driven Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework

Stochastic Modelling in Finance

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

STOCHASTIC INTEGRALS

Economathematics. Problem Sheet 1. Zbigniew Palmowski. Ws 2 dw s = 1 t

MSc Financial Engineering CHRISTMAS ASSIGNMENT: MERTON S JUMP-DIFFUSION MODEL. To be handed in by monday January 28, 2013

Homework Assignments

Optimal asset allocation under forward performance criteria Oberwolfach, February 2007

An overview of some financial models using BSDE with enlarged filtrations

Hedging under Arbitrage

Limit Theorems for the Empirical Distribution Function of Scaled Increments of Itô Semimartingales at high frequencies

Stochastic Processes and Financial Mathematics (part two) Dr Nic Freeman

Valuing volatility and variance swaps for a non-gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck stochastic volatility model

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

M5MF6. Advanced Methods in Derivatives Pricing

Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information

An application of an entropy principle to short term interest rate modelling

Last Time. Martingale inequalities Martingale convergence theorem Uniformly integrable martingales. Today s lecture: Sections 4.4.1, 5.

Sensitivity Analysis on Long-term Cash flows

Lecture 3: Review of mathematical finance and derivative pricing models

Parameters Estimation in Stochastic Process Model

Introduction Taylor s Theorem Einstein s Theory Bachelier s Probability Law Brownian Motion Itô s Calculus. Itô s Calculus.

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

BACHELIER FINANCE SOCIETY. 4 th World Congress Tokyo, Investments and forward utilities. Thaleia Zariphopoulou The University of Texas at Austin

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

Brownian Motion. Richard Lockhart. Simon Fraser University. STAT 870 Summer 2011

VOLATILITY TIME AND PROPERTIES OF OPTION PRICES

Interest rate models in continuous time

Martingales. by D. Cox December 2, 2009

Basic Arbitrage Theory KTH Tomas Björk

Exponential utility maximization under partial information

Conditional Full Support and No Arbitrage

Stochastic Calculus for Finance II - some Solutions to Chapter IV

Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Black-Scholes Model. Chapter Black-Scholes Model

Remarks: 1. Often we shall be sloppy about specifying the ltration. In all of our examples there will be a Brownian motion around and it will be impli

Analytical formulas for local volatility model with stochastic. Mohammed Miri

L 2 -theoretical study of the relation between the LIBOR market model and the HJM model Takashi Yasuoka

Hedging under arbitrage

Portfolio Optimization

MATH3075/3975 FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS TUTORIAL PROBLEMS

Option pricing in the stochastic volatility model of Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard

(Informal) Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Local Volatility Dynamic Models

Optimal robust bounds for variance options and asymptotically extreme models

S t d with probability (1 p), where

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 19 11/20/2013. Applications of Ito calculus to finance

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

Dr. Maddah ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 10/16/06

Convergence of Discretized Stochastic (Interest Rate) Processes with Stochastic Drift Term.

Girsanov s Theorem. Bernardo D Auria web: July 5, 2017 ICMAT / UC3M

Lévy models in finance

Asymptotic results discrete time martingales and stochastic algorithms

Continuous time; continuous variable stochastic process. We assume that stock prices follow Markov processes. That is, the future movements in a

Stochastic Modelling Unit 3: Brownian Motion and Diffusions

Non-semimartingales in finance

The Derivation and Discussion of Standard Black-Scholes Formula

Functional vs Banach space stochastic calculus & strong-viscosity solutions to semilinear parabolic path-dependent PDEs.

Continous time models and realized variance: Simulations

Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion

An Introduction to Stochastic Calculus

Lecture 4. Finite difference and finite element methods

is a standard Brownian motion.

Introduction to Probability Theory and Stochastic Processes for Finance Lecture Notes

Transcription:

Martingale representation theorem Ω = C[, T ], F T = smallest σ-field with respect to which B s are all measurable, s T, P the Wiener measure, B t = Brownian motion M t square integrable martingale with respect to F t Then there exists σ(t, ω) which is 1 progressively measurable 2 square integrable 3 B([, )) F mble such that M t = M + σ(s)db s () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 1 / 1

Lemma A = set of all linear combinations of random variables of the form er T hdb 1 2 A is dense in L 2 (Ω, F T, P) Proof R T h2 dt, h L 2 ([, T ]) Suppose g L 2 (Ω, F T, P) is orthogonal to all such functions We want to show that g = By an easy choice of simple functions h we find that for any λ 1,..., λ n R and t 1,..., t n [, T ], E P [ge λ 1B t1 + +λ nb t n ] = lhs real analytic in λ and hence has an analytic extension to λ C n () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 2 / 1

Since E P [ge λ 1B t1 + +λ nb t n ] is analytic and vanishes on the real axis, it is zero everywhere. In particular E P [ge i(y 1B t1 + +y nb t n ) ] = Suppose φ C (Rn ) ˆφ(y) = (2π) R n/2 φ(x)e ix y dx n Fourier inversion: φ(x) = (2π) R n/2 ˆφ(y)e ix y dy n E P [gφ(b t1,..., B tn )] = (2π) n/2 R n ˆφ(y)E P [e iy 1B t1 + +y nb t n ) ]dy = Hence g is orthogonal to fns of form φ(b t1,..., B tn ) where φ C (Rn ) Dense in L 2 (Ω, F T, P) g = () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 3 / 1

Lemma F L 2 (Ω, F T, P) There exists a unique f (t, ω) which is 1 progressively measurable 2 square integrable 3 B([, )) F measurable such that T F(ω) = E[F] + fdb. Proof of Uniqueness suppose T T F = E[F] + f 1 db = E[F] + f 2 db T (f 2 f 1 )db = T E[(f 2 f 1 ) 2 ]dt = f 2 = f 1 () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 4 / 1

Proof of existence First we prove it if F is of the form F = e R T Defining F t = e R t hdb 1 R t 2 h2ds gives hdb 1 R T 2 h2 ds so Plugging in t = T gives the result. df = hfdb, F = 1, F t = 1 + F s hdb. If F is a linear combination of such functions the result follows by linearity () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 5 / 1

Proof of existence for F L 2 (Ω, F T, P) F n L 2 (Ω, F T, P) with F n F and T F n = E[F n ] + f n db. E[F n ] E[F], so wlog E[F n ] = E[F] = E[(F n F m ) 2 ] = T f n Cauchy in L 2 ([, T ] Ω, dx dp). Let f be the limit. Taking limits we have E[(f n f m ) 2 ]dt as n, m T F = E[F] + fdb. () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 6 / 1

Proof of the martingale representation theorem By previous lemma, for each t we have σ t (s, ω) such that M t = E[M t ] + σ t (s)db s Let t 2 > t 1 M t1 = E[M t2 F t1 ] 1 σ t2 (s)db s = 1 σ t1 (s)db s Uniqueness σ t1 = σ t2 () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 7 / 1

Quadratic variation of X t = σ(s)db s e λ R t R λ2 σ(s)dbs t 2 σ2 (s)ds =martingale E[e λ R t i+1 t σ(s)db i s λ2 R ti+1 2 t σ 2 (s)ds i Fti ] = i+1 i+1 E[Z (t i, t i+1 ) F ti ] =, Z (t i, t i+1 ) = ( σ(s)db s ) 2 σ 2 (s)ds t i t i i+1 E[{Z (t i, t i+1 )} 2 4( σ 2 (s)ds) 2 F ti ] = t i E[( i Z (t i, t i+1 )) 2 ] 4E[( i i+1 ( σ 2 (s)ds) 2 ] t i X t, X t = σ 2 (s, ω)ds () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 8 / 1

Levy s Theorem Let X t be a process adapted to a filtration F t which 1 has continuous sample paths 2 is a martingale 3 has quadratic variation t Then X t is a Brownian motion () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 9 / 1

Proof of Levy s theorem Enough to show that for each λ, E[e iλ(x t X s) F s ] = e 1 2 λ2 (t s) Call M t = e iλx t + 1 2 λ2t, t j = s + j 2 n (t s) M t M s = M tj M tj 1 2 n j=1 = iλm tj 1 (X tj X tj 1 ) 1 2 λ2 M ξj [(X tj X tj 1 ) 2 (t j t j 1 )] 2 n j=1 E[M tj 1 (X tj X tj 1 ) F s ] = E[E[M tj 1 (X tj X tj 1 ) F tj 1 ] F s ] = E[M tj 1 E[(X tj X tj 1 ) F tj 1 ] F s ] = () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 1 / 1

Proof of Levy s theorem Fix m. Let ξ m = max{ i 2 m : i 2 m ξ} lim n M ξ m j [(X tj X tj 1 ) 2 (t j t j 1 )] = 2 n j=1 So we only have to show Would follow from lim n lim n [M ξ m j M ξj ](X tj X tj 1 ) 2 = 2 n j=1 (X ξ m j X ξj )(X tj X tj 1 ) 2 = 2 n j=1 Left hand side = t lim n max 1 j 2 n X ξ m j X ξj = a.s. () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 11 / 1

Note the same proof gives Itô formula for semimartingales Let Mt 1,..., Md t be martingales with respect to a filtration F t, t, A 1 t,..., Ad t adapted processes of bounded variation, X t = x + A t + M t where x F, and f (t, x) C 1,2. Then f d f (t, X t ) = f (, X ) + t (s, X f s)ds + (s, X s )da i s + dms i x i + d i,j=1 i=1 2 f x i x j (s, X s )d M i, M j s Multidimensional Levy s theorem Let Mt 1,..., Md t F t, t, with Then M 1 t,..., Md t be continuous martingales with respect to a filtration M i, M j t = δ ij t is a Brownian motion in R d () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 12 / 1

Time change Let Y t be a stochastic integral Y t = gds + fdb where f and g are adapted square integrable processes Let c t > be another adapted process and define β t = c s ds. Then β t is adapted and strictly increasing. We call α t its inverse. We can check that f t Y αt = c ds + g d B c for some Brownian motion B. In particular, if we are given a stochastic integral fdb we can choose f 2 = c as the rate of our time change and the resulting Y αt is a Brownian motion () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 13 / 1

Time change Theorem Let B t be Brownian motion and F t its canonical σ-field Suppose that M t is a square integrable martingale with respect to F t Let M t = M + f (s)db s be its representation in terms of Brownian motion. Suppose that f 2 > (i.e. its quadratic variation is strictly increasing) Let c = f 2 and define α t as above Then M αt is a Brownian motion () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 14 / 1

Example. Stochastic growth model dx = rxdt + σ XdB Solution is X t = rτ t + B(τ t ) where τ t = X t Because if dy = rdt + σdb then by time change X t = Y τt satisfies dx = rτ dt + σ τ db () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 15 / 1

Here s a funny trick to solve dx = σ XdB Let φ = φ(t) be deterministic and look at X(t)φ(T t) Y (t) = e So if φ = σ2 2 φ2, φ() = λ then Called Duality Great if it works. dy = ( φ + σ2 2 φ2 )Ydt φy σ XdB E[e λx(t ) ] = e X()φ(T ) () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 16 / 1

Example. Cox-Ingersol-Ross model The interest rate r(t) is assumed to satisfy the equation dr(t) = (α βr(t))dt + σ r(t)db(t). Note that the Lipschitz condition is not satisfied, but existence/uniqueness holds by the stronger theorem we did not prove If d = 4α/σ 2 is a positive integer, then we can find a solution as follows: Let B 1 (t), B 2 (t),..., B d (t) be d independent Brownian motions and let X 1 (t), X 2 (t),..., X d (t) be the solutions of the Langevin equations dx i = αx i dt + σdb i, i = 1,..., d. In other words, X 1 (t), X 2 (t),..., X d (t) are d independent Ornstein-Uhlenbeck processes () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 17 / 1

Example. Cox-Ingersol-Ross model r(t) = X 2 1 (t) + + X 2 d (t), dr(t) = (α βr(t))dt + σ r(t) d B(t) = X 1(t), X 2 (t),..., X d (t) indep O-U. d i=1 { d i=1 X i (t) r(t) db i (t) B(t) is a martingale with quadratic variation d Bd B = d i,j=1 B(t) Brownian motion X i (t)x j (t) db i (t)db j (t) = r(t) } X i (t) db i (t). r(t) d i=1 X 2 i (t) r(t) dr(t) = (α βr(t))dt + σ r(t)d B(t) dt = dt () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 18 / 1

The type of solutions dealt with in the existence/uniqueness theorem are strong solutions This means that you are given the Brownian motion B(t) and asked to come up with a solution X(t) of the stochastic differential equation dx = bdt + σdb. A weak solution is when you just find some Brownian motion B(t) for which you can solve the equation dx = bdt + σd B. Example. Cox-Ingersol-Ross. If d = 1 then B(t) = B 1 (t) so we have a strong solution But if d = 2, 3,... then all we have is a weak solution, because given a Brownian motion B(t) it is not at all clear how to find B 1 (t),..., B d (t) for which db(t) = d X i (t) i=1 db i (t). r(t) () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 19 / 1

Diffusion process as probability measure on C([, )) Brownian motion=collection of rv s B t, t on (Ω, F, P) or Brownian motion=probability measure P on C([, )) If A is a (measurable) subset of continuous functions, then P(A) is just the probability that a Brownian path falls in that subset Same for any diffusion.if X(t) is the solution of the stochastic differential equation dx(t) = b(t, X(t))dt + σ(t, X(t))dB(t), X() = x then we can let Px a,b denote the probability measure on the space of continuous functions with P a,b x (A) = Prob(X( ) A) a = σσ T Question:What is the relation of P a,b x for different x, a, b? () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 2 / 1

1 If x 1 x 2 then Px a,b 1 Px a,b 2. 2 The quadratic variation 2 n T lim X( i + 1 n 2 n ) X( i T 2 n ) 2 = a(t, X(t))dt i= a.s. P a,b x Hence if a 1 a 2, P a 1,b x P a 2,b x 3 To see what happens if we change b, let dx i (t) = b i dt + σdb(t), i = 1, 2 P(X 1 (t 1 ) dx 1,..., X 1 (t n ) dx n ) P(X 2 (t 1 ) dx 1,..., X 2 (t n ) dx n ) = e P n 1 i= = e Z dx 1 dx n (x i+1 x i b 1 (t i+1 t i )) 2 (x i+1 x i b 2 (t i+1 t i )) 2 2σ 2 (t i+1 t i ) dx 1 dx n () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 21 / 1

P(X 1 (t 1 ) dx 1,..., X 1 (t n ) dx n ) P(X 2 (t 1 ) dx 1,..., X 2 (t n ) dx n ) = ez dx 1 dx n n 1 Z = i= (x i+1 x i b 1 (t i+1 t i )) 2 (x i+1 x i b 2 (t i+1 t i )) 2 2σ 2 (t i+1 t i ) n 1 = σ 1 (b 2 b 1 )σ 1 (x i+1 x i b 2 (t i+1 t i )) n i= 1 n 1 (σ 1 (b 2 b 1 )) 2 (t i+1 t i ) 2 i= σ 1 (b 2 b 1 )db(s) 1 2 (σ 1 (b 2 b 1 )) 2 ds () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 22 / 1

Cameron-Martin-Girsanov formula For each x the measure Px a,b is absolutely continuous on F t with respect to the measure Px a, and dpx a,b dpx a, Ft { = exp a 1 (X s )b(x s )dx s 1 } b(x s )a 1 (X s )b(x s )ds 2 Proof We want to show is if we define a measure { Q(A) = exp a 1 bdx s 1 2 A } a 1 b 2 ds dpx a, then Q is a diffusion with parameters a and b in other words, for each λ, exp{λ(x t X bds) λ2 ads} 2 is a martingale with respect to Q () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 23 / 1

Proof. Y t = (λ + a 1 b)dx s = (λ + a 1 b)σdb s. e Y t Y 1 2 R t a(λ+a 1 b) 2 ds = martingale w.r.t. P a, x e λ(x t X R t R λ2 bds) t 2 ads+r t a 1 bdx s 1 R t 2 a 1 b 2 ds = martingale w.r.t. P a, x e λ(x t X R t R λ2 bds) t 2 ads = martingale w.r.t. Q t dq = er a 1 bdx s 1 R t 2 a 1 b 2ds dpx a, () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 24 / 1

Solution of one dimensional stochastic differential equations Suppose you want to solve the one dimensional stochastic differential equation dx(t) = σ(t, X(t))dB(t) + b(t, X(t))dt By Cameron-Martin-Girsanov, you could instead solve dz (t) = σ(t, Z (t))db(t) and then change to an equivalent measure which will correspond to the solution of X(t) Define t(τ) by τ(t) = σ 2 (u, Y (u))du B(τ) = Z (t(τ)) is a Brownian motion and Z (t) = B(τ(t)). Only works in d = 1 () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 25 / 1

Brownian motion as the limit of random walks X 1, X 2,... iid Bernoulli P(X i = 1) = P(X i = 1) = 1/2 S n = X 1 + + X n B n (t) = 1 n S tn Takes steps ± 1 n at times 1 n, 2 n,... Or B n (t) = polygonalized version. Almost the same but continuous B n (t) n Brownian motion B(t) What does it mean for stochastic processes to converge? dist(b n (t 1 ),..., B n (t k )) dist(b(t 1 ),..., B(t k )) k = 1, 2, 3,... Convergenence of finite dimesional distributions Immediate from (multidimensional) central limit theorem Same for B n (t) () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 26 / 1

P n = measure on C[, T ] corresponding to B n (t), t T Invariance principle (Donsker s Theorem) P n P Much stronger than convergence of finite dimensional distributions Examples 1 1 dist( max S m ) dist( sup B(t)) m n n t 1 2 n dist(n 1 k 2 Sm) k dist( m=1 1 B k (t)dt) () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 27 / 1

Brownian motion with variance σ 2 and drift b as the limit of random walks X n (t) jumps 1 n σ + 1 n b or 1 n σ + 1 nb with probabilities 1/2 at times 1 n, 2 n,... X n (t) b nt n = σb n(t) X n (t) σb(t) + bt General local diffusivity σ 2 (t, x) and drift b(t, x) X n (t) jumps 1 n σ( i n, X n( i n )) + 1 n b( i n, X n( i 1 n )) or n σ( i n, X n( i n )) + 1 n b( i n, X n( i n )) with probabilities 1/2 at times i n, i = 1, 2,... X n(t) X(t) But how to prove it? dx(t) = σ(t, X(t))dB(t) + b(t, X(t))dt () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 28 / 1

Here s another proof that random walks converge to Brownian motions, which does generalize Recall B n (t) = 1 n S tn where S n = X 1 + + X n Let f C 2 f (B n (t)) = 1 n tn 1 i= L n f (B n ( i n ) = Martingale L n f (x) = 1 2 n(f (x + n 1/2 ) 2f (x) + f (x n 1/2 )) f (B(t)) 1 2 L n f (x) 1 2 f (x) tn 1 1 L n f (B n ( i n n ) 1 2 i= f (B(s))ds f (B(s))ds = martingale B(t) Brownian motion () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 29 / 1

Really one needs to show that P n are precompact as a set of probability measures. It is similar to the proof that Brownian motion is continuous, but you just use the martingale formulation directly. The details are long, but the final result is Theorem Suppose that 1 n y x 1 (y i x i )(y j x j )p 1/n (x, dy) a ij (x) uniformly on compact sets 2 n y x 1 (y i x i )p 1/n (x, dy) b i (x) uniformly on compact sets 3 np 1/n (x, B(x, ɛ) C ) uniformly on compact sets, for each ɛ > where a(x) and b(x) are continuous. Suppose that we have weak uniqueness for the stochastic differential equation dx = σ(x)db + b(x)dt and let P denote the measure on C[, T ] corresponding to X(t), t T. Then P n P () Stochastic Calculus March 3, 27 3 / 1