Appendix A Gravity Model Assessment of the Impact of WTO Accession on Russian Trade

Similar documents
Recommendation of the Council on Tax Avoidance and Evasion

Corrigendum. OECD Pensions Outlook 2012 DOI: ISBN (print) ISBN (PDF) OECD 2012

Gravity Model Analysis

Table 1: Foreign exchange turnover: Summary of surveys Billions of U.S. dollars. Number of business days

Burden of Taxation: International Comparisons

Approach to Employment Injury (EI) compensation benefits in the EU and OECD

Estimates from Gravity and CGE Models

PREDICTING VEHICLE SALES FROM GDP

International Statistical Release

University of Iceland May 12th Helga Kristjánsdóttir

The Socialist Federal Republic of Yugoslavia takes part in some of the work of the OECD (agreement of 28th October 1961).

Statistical annex. Sources and definitions

2017/SOM3/DIA/005. GATS Plus - Services. Submitted by: Australia

Bank of Canada Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Over-the-Counter (OTC) Derivatives Markets

THE DETERMINANTS OF SECTORAL INWARD FDI PERFORMANCE INDEX IN OECD COUNTRIES

Trade and Development Board Sixty-first session. Geneva, September 2014

Actuarial Supply & Demand. By i.e. muhanna. i.e. muhanna Page 1 of

Declaration on Environmental Policy

DEVELOPMENT AID AT A GLANCE

IMPLICATIONS OF LOW PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH FOR DEBT SUSTAINABILITY

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - APRIL 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

BULGARIAN TRADE WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - MAY 2017 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

India s Bilateral Trade in Services: Patterns, Determinants and Role of Trade in Goods

Summary of key findings

Statistics Brief. Investment in Inland Transport Infrastructure at Record Low. Infrastructure Investment. July

May 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.9 bn euro 3.8 bn euro deficit for EU27

Information and Capital Flows Revisited: the Internet as a

Recommendation of the Council on the Implementation of the Polluter-Pays Principle

CANADA EUROPEAN UNION

The Outlook for the U.S. Economy and the Policies of the New President

THE IMPACT OF REGIONALISM AND MULTILATERALISM FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: THE GRAVITY APPROACH. By Blasetti Eugenia, De Marinis Marta, Urzi Alessandra

FCCC/SBI/2010/10/Add.1

June 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 14.9 bn euro 0.4 bn euro surplus for EU27

American Chamber of Commerce to the European Union (AmCham EU)

August 2012 Euro area international trade in goods surplus of 6.6 bn euro 12.6 bn euro deficit for EU27

Seventeenth Meeting of the IMF Committee on Balance of Payments Statistics Pretoria, October 26 29, 2004

Bank of Canada Triennial Central Bank Surveys of Foreign Exchange and Over-the-Counter (OTC) Derivatives Markets Turnover for April, 2007 and Amounts

International Statistical Release

International Statistical Release

Basic information. Tax-to-GDP ratio Date: 29 November 2010

Reporting practices for domestic and total debt securities

March 2005 Euro-zone external trade surplus 4.2 bn euro 6.5 bn euro deficit for EU25

Empirical appendix of Public Expenditure Distribution, Voting, and Growth

WORLD TRADE ORGANIZATION

Third Revised Decision of the Council concerning National Treatment

8-Jun-06 Personal Income Top Marginal Tax Rate,

August 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.6 bn euro 14.2 bn euro deficit for EU25

This DataWatch provides current information on health spending

MDG 8: Develop a Global Partnership for Development

Global Monitoring Report: Findings on Progress since Monterrey

Linking Education for Eurostat- OECD Countries to Other ICP Regions

REVIEW PRACTICE GUIDANCE

The OECD s Society at a Glance Simon Chapple OECD ELS/SPD Villa Vigoni, Italy, 9-11 th March 2011

First estimate for 2011 Euro area external trade deficit 7.7 bn euro bn euro deficit for EU27

Executive Summary. The Transatlantic Economy Annual Survey of Jobs, Trade and Investment between the United States and Europe

January 2014 Euro area international trade in goods surplus 0.9 bn euro 13.0 bn euro deficit for EU28

International Statistical Release

June 2014 Euro area international trade in goods surplus 16.8 bn 2.9 bn surplus for EU28

Payroll Taxes in Canada from 1997 to 2007

COMPARISON OF RIA SYSTEMS IN OECD COUNTRIES

Revenue Arrangements for Implementing EU and OECD Exchange of Information Requirements In Respect of Tax Rulings

Income smoothing and foreign asset holdings

Sources of Government Revenue in the OECD, 2016

January 2005 Euro-zone external trade deficit 2.2 bn euro 14.0 bn euro deficit for EU25

The Velocity of Money and Nominal Interest Rates: Evidence from Developed and Latin-American Countries

STOXX EMERGING MARKETS INDICES. UNDERSTANDA RULES-BA EMERGING MARK TRANSPARENT SIMPLE

DG TAXUD. STAT/11/100 1 July 2011

Second Quarter Trading Update 9 July 2010

Growth in OECD Unit Labour Costs slows to 0.4% in the third quarter of 2016

International Statistical Release

EUROPEAN UNION SOUTH KOREA TRADE AND INVESTMENT 5 TH ANNIVERSARY OF THE FTA. Delegation of the European Union to the Republic of Korea

Internet Appendix: Government Debt and Corporate Leverage: International Evidence

Pension Fund Investment and Regulation - An International Perspective and Implications for China s Pension System

TRADE IN GOODS OF BULGARIA WITH EU IN THE PERIOD JANUARY - JUNE 2018 (PRELIMINARY DATA)

Goal 8: Develop a Global Partnership for Development

Capital Access Index 2006 Gauging Entrepreneurial Access to Capital

Key Issues in the Design of Capital Gains Tax Regimes: Taxing Non- Residents. 18 July 2014

Statistics Brief. Inland transport infrastructure investment on the rise. Infrastructure Investment. August

Income, pensions, spending and wealth

Registration of Foreign Limited Partnerships in the Cayman Islands

OECD Report Shows Tax Burdens Falling in Many OECD Countries

Official Journal of the European Union L 57/5

Constraints on Exchange Rate Flexibility in Transition Economies: a Meta-Regression Analysis of Exchange Rate Pass-Through

The Economics of Public Health Care Reform in Advanced and Emerging Economies

Doing Business in the Pacific

STATISTICS. Taxing Wages DIS P O NIB LE E N SPECIAL FEATURE: PART-TIME WORK AND TAXING WAGES

LONG-TERM PROJECTIONS OF PUBLIC PENSION EXPENDITURE

INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH

The macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in the Netherlands Íde Kearney, 13 th September 2018.

Rev. Proc Implementation of Nonresident Alien Deposit Interest Regulations

Basic information. Tax-to-GDP ratio Date: 24 October 2012

PENSIONS IN OECD COUNTRIES: INDICATORS AND DEVELOPMENTS

EUR billions (b.kr.) 2000 Q3/2008 Q3/

Theory of Economic Integration

Indicator B3 How much public and private investment in education is there?

THIRD MEETING OF THE OECD FORUM ON TAX ADMINISTRATION

A. Definitions and sources of data

10% 10% 15% 15% Caseload: WE. 15% Caseload: SS 10% 10% 15%

Measuring National Output and National Income. Gross Domestic Product. National Income and Product Accounts

Lecture 13 International Trade: Economics 181 Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and Multinational Corporations (MNCs)

Transcription:

Appendix A Gravity Model Assessment of the Impact of WTO Accession on Russian Trade To assess the quantitative impact of WTO accession on Russian trade, we draw on estimates for merchandise trade between industrial countries derived from the Peterson Institute gravity model, many of whose explanatory variables have their origin in an augmented version of Andrew Rose s (2004) gravity model. The basic Peterson Institute model (following Rose) evaluates two-way bilateral trade flows, measured in a common currency (and adjusted for inflation), against the gravitational mass of explanatory variables describing the characteristics of bilateral trading partners. 1 Two fundamental variables are distance and joint real GDP. In general, gravity models find that two-way trade between countries is significantly greater the larger the combined GDP and the shorter the distance between them. Additional explanatory variables show how much two-way bilateral trade expands or contracts from the quantity predicted by the basic core variables on account of institutional or policy features of the partners. For instance, trading partners that share a common language, a common currency, or belong to the same regional trading arrangement typically enjoy greater mutual trade. Following Rose (2004), the model additionally includes GATT/WTO membership by one or both trading partners as an institutional factor, with the expectation that membership will enhance bilateral trade. The rationale is straightforward: Accession to the GATT/WTO provides reciprocal most favored nation (MFN) status to both members and hence better trade oppor- This appendix was principally authored by Dean DeRosa. 1. Among other recent applications of the Peterson Institute gravity model, see DeRosa (2009). 67

tunities. 2 Contrary to his expectation, Rose (2004) found little appreciable impact on trade from the inclusion of two simple GATT/WTO indicator variables. One indicator variable takes a unitary value if both trading partners are members of the GATT/WTO, and zero otherwise. The other indicator variable takes a unitary value if only one trading partner is a member of the GATT/ WTO, and zero otherwise. Rose s findings stimulated considerable controversy in trade policy circles, as summarized by Rose himself (2006). Recent investigators have, for instance, emphasized the importance of so-called country fixed effects and the differential experiences of industrial countries versus less developed countries. The latest studies also stress the creation of bilateral trade by new GATT/WTO members where no trade previously existed. The variant of the Rose model employed here focuses on aggregate merchandise trade between countries at the 1-digit Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) level over the period 1976 2005 and takes into account the influence of inward foreign direct investment (FDI) stocks on the magnitude of bilateral trade flows. Table A.1 presents estimation results both for all nonfuel merchandise trade (SITC 0 through 8, less SITC 3) and for manufactures trade (SITC 5 through 8) of industrial countries with all their trading partners. 3 Manufactures are widely held to be the most appropriate trade category for estimation by gravity models because intraindustry commerce flourishes when trade barriers are low. Moreover, tariffs on manufactures have historically been the prime object of multilateral trade liberalization under GATT/WTO auspices. The estimation results in table A.1 indicate that the gravity model explains a substantial proportion of trade for both trade aggregates. Indeed the R-squared value for both sets of estimation results is 0.96. 4 Moreover, the coefficient estimates in table A.1 for traditional gravity model explanatory variables, such as joint GDP and distance between trading partners, bear the anticipated signs and are highly significant particular hallmarks of gravity models. Our main interest, however, is to estimate the increase in Russian trade with the world that would result from membership in the WTO and an expansion of inward FDI. To make these calculations, we focus on the coefficient estimates for the GATT/WTO and FDI variables, the explanatory vari- 2. Beyond direct enhancement of trading opportunities, reciprocal MFN policies imply a degree of own-country trade liberalization and therefore indirect enhancement of export competitiveness and performance through more efficient allocation of domestic resources. 3. Following Rose (2004), we use the International Monetary Fund s list of industrial countries: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United States, and United Kingdom. 4. Some caution should be exercised in interpreting the very high R-squared value for both estimation results. The statistic may be inflated by the Plumper and Troeger (2007) multistage estimation, which measures the statistic only in the last stage of the procedure. 68 PERMANENT NORMAL TRADE RELATIONS WITH RUSSIA

Table A.1 Estimates for nonfuel and manufactures trade by industrial countries with all partners, with WTO membership and foreign direct investment (FDI) explanatory variables, 1976 2005 Nonfuel commodities and manufactures Explanatory variable (SITC 0 to 8, less SITC 3) Manufactures (SITC 5 to 8) Both in GATT/WTO 0.16*** 0.16*** One in GATT/WTO 0.15*** 0.14*** Joint FDI (inward stock) 0.08*** 0.08*** Distance 0.83*** 1.03*** Joint GDP 1.04*** 1.14*** Currency union 0.04*** 0.03*** GSP 0.29*** 0.49*** Regional FTAs 0.17*** 0.18*** Common language 0.36*** 0.43*** Common border 0.21*** 0.01*** Landlocked 0.14*** 0.00*** Island 0.30*** 0.29*** Joint land area 0.14*** 0.18*** Colony now 0.31*** 0.37*** Ever a colony 0.75*** 0.62*** Constant 34.85*** 38.07*** R-squared 0.96*** 0.96*** Observations (thousands) 34 ***** 34***** Groups (thousands) 3 ***** 3***** GSP = Generalized System of Preferences; FTAs = free trade agreements; SITC = Standard International Trade Classification Sources and notes: Fixed-effects estimates obtained by a multistep method developed by Plumper and Troeger (2007). Dependent variables are bilateral trade and bilateral inward FDI stocks, both measured in log real terms. Distance, joint real GDP, joint land area, and joint real inward FDI stocks are measured in log terms. Estimates for year effects are not reported. *,**,*** denote statistical signficance at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels, respectively. Clusters are the number of ordered country pairs in the panel dataset. APPENDIX A 69

ables specially included to discern the potential impact of WTO accession on Russia s trade. For this purpose, we assume that once Russia joins the WTO, Russian trade will follow the pattern of other industrial countries. The coefficients of both the GATT/WTO variables and the FDI inward stock variable are positive and significant. Whereas Rose s estimates for the coefficient when both partners are members of the GATT/WTO were frequently negative, the present coefficient estimates for this variable in table A.1 are positive and identical in value, 0.16, for both trade aggregates. 5 This coefficient value implies that WTO accession would raise Russian bilateral trade in nonfuel commodities and manufactures by nearly 20 percent. In dollar terms, total Russian two-way trade in manufactures was $186 billion in 2009, and total bilateral manufactures trade with the United States was $10 billion. Based on the estimated coefficient, these figures could expand to $223 billion and $12 billion, respectively, following Russian accession to the WTO. 6 It is worth noting that the joint FDI stock variable has an estimated coefficient of 0.08 both for all nonfuel trade and for manufactures trade. This coefficient estimate implies that a 50 percent increase in Russia s inward FDI stock from the current level of about $200 billion to $300 billion a plausible consequence of WTO membership and greater normalization of the Russian economy would trigger an increase in total Russian two-way trade in manufactures trade of about 5 percent, or some $9.3 billion. The associated increase in bilateral manufactures trade with the United States would be $0.5 billion, assuming that the United States enjoys only a proportional increase in two-way trade. The foregoing calculations reflect an orthodox application of gravity model analysis, confined, as mentioned, to Russia s merchandise trade with the world. We believe the results, while orthodox, do not reflect the potential growth in US trade with Russia, especially since US export levels are low compared with the size of Russian GDP and the export experience of other countries that sell into the Russian market. 5. However, when the same trade data are disaggregated (and pooled) by 1-digit SITC categories, the gravity model frequently finds coefficient estimates for the two GATT/WTO variables that are negative but not statistically significant. 6. The percentage trade expansion is derived from the estimated coefficient for the both-in-gatt/ WTO variable. Given the log-linear specification of the gravity model regression equation, the impact of WTO accession on bilateral trade is computed in percentage terms as 100*[exp(b) 1.00]. In this expression, b is the estimated coefficient for the both-in-gatt/wto indicator variable, and exp(b) is the value of the natural number e raised to the exponent b. For example, if the coefficient b is 0.33, then the value of exp(b) is 1.39, and the percentage expansion in trade is estimated as 100*[1.39 1.00], which equals 39 percent. Notably, this calculation assumes that the trading partner of the new WTO member is also a WTO member. According to the estimation results in table A.1, however, the trade impacts of Russian accession to the WTO cited in the main text would be only slightly lower in value if one of its trading partners was not a WTO member, because the coefficient estimates for the one-in-gatt/wto variable are only somewhat lower in value. 70 PERMANENT NORMAL TRADE RELATIONS WITH RUSSIA

The calculations we offer in the main text and summarize in the next paragraph are more speculative but, in our opinion, better reflect the potential of US-Russian trade within the framework of normal WTO rules. These alternative calculations are based on the supposition that the so-called fixed-effects coefficient that uniquely characterizes US-Russian export relations is zero, rather than the negative value found in gravity model analysis. 7 Following this approach, it appears the potential total US exports to Russia are 2.8 times the size of actual US exports to Russia. 8 Since actual US exports to Russia in the last normal trade year before the Great Recession, namely 2008, were $9.3 billion, it appears that potential US exports could be as much as $26 billion. We think this figure, a near-tripling of total US exports to Russia, better represents the potential growth of trade within the WTO framework than the orthodox gravity model analysis. Conservatively, in the main text, we refer to the prospect of doubling US-Russian trade in the wake of WTO accession and PNTR. 7. See the technical explanation in DeRosa (forthcoming). 8. For US exports of manufactures to Russia, US potential trade is 2.2 times greater than the recorded size of US shipments to Russia. APPENDIX A 71