Economics 602 Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Problem Set 3 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2012

Similar documents
Problem 1 / 20 Problem 2 / 30 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

) dollars. Throughout the following, suppose

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

Chapter 3 Dynamic Consumption-Savings Framework

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Chapter 4 Inflation and Interest Rates in the Consumption-Savings Model

Economics 325 Intermediate Macroeconomic Analysis Problem Set 1 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 2009

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

~ In 20X7, a loaf of bread costs $1.50 and a flask of wine costs $6.00. A consumer with $120 buys 40 loaves of bread and 10 flasks of wine.

Chapter 19 Optimal Fiscal Policy

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

2. Explain the notion of the marginal rate of substitution and how it relates to the utilitymaximizing

Marginal Utility, Utils Total Utility, Utils

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Section 4.3 Objectives

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 1 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2, Question 1

8 POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES. Chapter. Key Concepts. The Budget Line

POSSIBILITIES, PREFERENCES, AND CHOICES

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL POLICY IN JUNE 16, 2010 THE CONSUMPTION-SAVINGS MODEL (CONTINUED) ADYNAMIC MODEL OF THE GOVERNMENT

3Choice Sets in Labor and Financial

Economics 111 Exam 1 Fall 2005 Prof Montgomery

Microeconomics Pre-sessional September Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 1

GRAPHS IN ECONOMICS. Appendix. Key Concepts. Graphing Data

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 15 Problem 3 / 15 Problem 4 / 20 Problem 5 / 25 TOTAL / 100

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Economics 202 (Section 05) Macroeconomic Theory Problem Set 1 Professor Sanjay Chugh Fall 2013 Due: Thursday, October 3, 2013

Full file at Microeconomics: An Intuitive Approach (with and without Calculus) Chapter 2

Consumption, Saving, and Investment. Chapter 4. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

1. Consider the figure with the following two budget constraints, BC1 and BC2.

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

This appendix discusses two extensions of the cost concepts developed in Chapter 10.

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

ECO101 PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS Notes. Consumer Behaviour. U tility fro m c o n s u m in g B ig M a c s

Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 3

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Microeconomics. The Theory of Consumer Choice. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich update C H A P T E R

Topic 4b Competitive consumer

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

ECONS 301 Homework #1. Answer Key

E&G, Ch. 1: Theory of Choice; Utility Analysis - Certainty

Introduction to economics for PhD Students of The Institute of Physical Chemistry, PAS Lecture 3 Consumer s choice

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

Midterm 1 - Solutions

13 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS: THE KEYNESIAN MODEL* Chapter. Key Concepts

Problem Set 4 - Answers. Specific Factors Models

Principle of Microeconomics

If a model were to predict that prices and money are inversely related, that prediction would be evidence against that model.

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

Income and Substitution Effects in Consumer Goods Markest

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

11 EXPENDITURE MULTIPLIERS* Chapt er. Key Concepts. Fixed Prices and Expenditure Plans1

2c Tax Incidence : General Equilibrium

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

Module 4. The theory of consumer behaviour. Introduction

Intro to Economic analysis

Economics 111 Exam 1 Spring 2008 Prof Montgomery. Answer all questions. Explanations can be brief. 100 points possible.

2) Indifference curve (IC) 1. Represents consumer preferences. 2. MRS (marginal rate of substitution) = MUx/MUy = (-)slope of the IC = (-) Δy/Δx

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis November 13, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 2

Midterm 1 - Solutions

First Welfare Theorem in Production Economies

If Tom's utility function is given by U(F, S) = FS, graph the indifference curves that correspond to 1, 2, 3, and 4 utils, respectively.

EXAMINATION #2 VERSION A Consumers and Demand October 1, 2015

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

Consumers cannot afford all the goods and services they desire. Consumers are limited by their income and the prices of goods.

Labor Economics 7th Edition TEST BANK Borjas Full download at:

PRACTICE QUESTIONS CHAPTER 5

Practice Problem Solutions for Exam 1

Practice Problem Set 2 (ANSWERS)

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

Econ 1101 Summer 2013 Lecture 7. Section 005 6/26/2013

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Fall 2018) Consumer Choice Theory

Economics 101 Section 5

ANSWER: We can find consumption and saving by solving:

Intermediate Microeconomics UTILITY BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

Econ 001 Levinson -- Fall 2008

Homework 1 Due February 10, 2009 Chapters 1-4, and 18-24

Assignment 1 Solutions. October 6, 2017

File: ch03, Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and The Concept of Utility

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

ECNB , Spring 2003 Intermediate Microeconomics Saint Louis University. Midterm 2

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 25 Problem 3 / 25 Problem 4 / 25

KOÇ UNIVERSITY ECON 202 Macroeconomics Fall Problem Set VI C = (Y T) I = 380 G = 400 T = 0.20Y Y = C + I + G.

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

The level of consumption and saving in the United States is higher today than a decade ago because real GDP and income are higher.

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester. ECON 101 Mid term Exam

Introduction. The Theory of Consumer Choice. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

Transcription:

Department of Applied Economics Johns Hopkins University Economics 60 Macroeconomic Theory and Policy Problem Set 3 Suggested Solutions Professor Sanjay Chugh Spring 0. The Wealth Effect on Consumption. Consider the two-period consumption-savings model we have been developing in class. a. As in class, maintain the simplifying assumption that A 0 = 0. Show graphically how a rise in the period- nominal price of consumption can lead to a decrease in optimal consumption in period. Solution: Recall from the standard two-period consumption-savings model that the when plotting the lifetime budget constraint (LBC) with c on the vertical axis and c on the horizontal axis, the price P affects the slope but not the vertical intercept (refer to Figure 7 in Chapter 3). It follows that if P rises, then the vertical intercept is unaffected but the budget line becomes steeper. As shown in the figure below, this can lead to lower consumption in period. c ((+i)y /P ) + (Y /P ) Initial LBC New LBC New * Initial * PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh

Notice that as drawn, the optimal choice of c has also fallen. There is nothing in the structure of the model as we have discussed it that can lead us to definitively conclude that this must be the case however, it is the most likely case. b. Now suppose that A0 0. Show graphically how a decrease in A 0 can lead to a decrease in optimal consumption in period. Solution: We saw that the LBC in the two-period model is Y c + = Y+ + ( + i) A0. ( + i) ( + i) If we keep A0 0, then solving for c gives us the LBC P( + i) + i Y ( + i) = + + + 0 P P P P c c Y A. Clearly, A 0 (regardless of whether it is positive or negative) affects only the intercepts of the LBC but not the slope. Thus a decrease in A 0 leads to a parallel shift inwards of the LBC, thus leading to a fall in the optimal choice of as shown in the figure below. c Initial LBC New LBC New * Initial * PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh

c. The two effects you analyzed in parts a and b work through seemingly different channels. Actually, they are usefully thought of as operating through the same broadly-defined channel. Explain this broadly-defined channel. Solution: The perfectly-rational representative-agent considers all his lifetime resources (both labor income as well as initial wealth) when making his optimal consumption-savings decision. Thus, both the change in price in part a and the change in initial wealth in part b (as well as possible changes in the nominal interest rate, the price of consumption in period, or labor income in either period!) have their effect by impacting the real value (as opposed to nominal value) of lifetime resources. The real value of lifetime resources is sometimes called lifetime wealth thus, it is lifetime wealth that the individual considers when making his optimal consumption-savings choice.. A Three-Period Economy. Rather than the two-period consumption-savings model economy we have been developing in class, consider a three-period model that is analogous to the two-period model. a. Derive a relation similar to expression on page 46 in the Lecture Text for the three-period economy (that is, derive the lifetime budget constraint (LBC) for the three-period economy). Define any new notation you introduce, and briefly explain the logic you use in deriving your final expression. Solution: The period-3 budget constraint would be + A = Y + ( + i) A, 3 3 3 3 where, analogous to our existing notation, c 3 is consumption in period 3, P 3 is the nominal price of consumption in period 3, Y 3 is nominal labor income in period 3, and A 3 is the wealth the individual chooses to carry from period 3 to period 4. Because there is no period 4 to save for, however, we know the individual will choose A 3 = 0. This condition replaces the condition A = 0 we had in the two-period economy (that is, we can no longer simply say that A = 0 ). Then perform the following steps of algebra (watch your algebra!): solve the period-3 budget constraint for A, then insert this expression for A into the period- budget constraint. Solve the resulting expression for A (tedious algebra here), and insert this into the period- budget constraint the final expression you now have is the LBC for the three-period economy, 3 3 Y Y3 + + = Y + + + ( + i) A 0. ( + i) ( + i) ( + i) ( + i) Notice carefully the squared ( + i) terms which now appear in the LBC. PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 3

b. Provide a brief interpretation of the LBC you derive in part a. Solution: The interpretation of this LBC is exactly as before: it states that the present discounted value of all lifetime resources (which takes account both initial wealth as well as all lifetime labor income) equals the present discounted value of all lifetime consumption. Over the course of his lifetime, the individual spends all his lifetime resources on lifetime consumption. c. In reality, there are an infinite number of periods. Write down the LBC for an infinite-period economy. (No need to be very mathematical just use what you've learned in class and what you derived above). Solution: The LBC for the infinite-period economy is 3 3 4 4 5 5 + + + + +... = 3 4 ( + i) ( + i) ( + i) ( + i) Y Y 3 Y Y 4 5 ( + ia ) 0 + Y+ + + + +... 3 4 ( + i) ( + i) ( + i) ( + i) where the ellipsis on both sides of the equality indicate the summations continue indefinitely. Alternatively, using sigma-notation from mathematics, the LBC can be written more compactly as i i j = ( + ia ) 0 + i j i= ( + i) j= ( + i). Y d. The Permanent Income Hypothesis states that individuals consider their future lifetime earnings when making their current consumption decision. Discuss briefly how the multi-period models we are considering here (regardless of twoperiod, three-period, n-period, or infinite-period) are consistent with the Permanent Income Hypothesis. Solution: The Permanent Income Hypothesis is embodied in the very set-up of the consumption-savings model. The LBC shows that consumption in all periods depends on income over the course of the individual s entire lifetime thus, in particular, consumption in any single period (period, say) depends on income in that period and all future periods. 3. Mechanics of the Consumption-Savings Model. Recall that in our two-period consumption-savings model, real labor income in any period is given by nominal PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 4

labor income divided by the price level (that is, recall y = Y / P and y = Y / P). Suppose that nominal labor income in both periods is held constant. Clearly indicating the position of real labor income before and after each change on your diagrams, illustrate how the LBC is affected by the following events. As in class, make the simplifying assumption that the individual has zero initial wealth (i.e., A 0 = 0 ). a. The price level in period, P, rises, while P is held constant. Solution: A rise in the price level in period lowers real labor income in period because y = Y / P and Y remains constant by assumption. Real labor income in period is unaffected. The LBC becomes steeper because, recall, the slope of the LBC is ( P( + i)/ P). The vertical intercept is unaffected because P does not enter the expression for the vertical intercept of the LBC in nominal terms (see page 44 of the Lecture Notes). These effects are shown in the figure below: c Initial LBC y New LBC new y initial y b. The price level in period, P, rises, while P is held constant. Solution: A rise in the price level in period lowers real labor income in period because y = Y / P and Y remains constant by assumption. Real labor income in period is unaffected. The LBC becomes flatter because, recall again, the slope of the LBC is ( P( + i)/ P). Here, the vertical PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 5

intercept is now lower because P does enter the expression for the vertical intercept of the LBC in nominal terms (again see page 44 of the Lecture Notes), and it is the horizontal intercept which remains fixed. These effects are shown in the figure below: c Initial LBC initial y new y New LBC y Note: In both questions a and b, you might have been thrown off if you were trying to use Figure 8 on page 5 of the Lecture Notes, in which you see that both y and y affect the vertical intercept. If you tried to base your analysis on this diagram and your answers were incorrect, it is probably because you failed to take account of the fact that the real interest rate rises in an exactly offsetting way in part a and falls in an exactly offsetting way in part b. This points out that the LBC in nominal terms and the LBC in real terms highlight different issues. In any given problem, it is usually more straightforward to use one rather than the other. As you might expect, when you are considering changes in nominal variables (prices, nominal interest rate, inflation), it is usually more straightforward to use the LBC in nominal terms. c. The nominal interest rate i rises, while both P and P are held constant. Solution: Real labor income in both periods is unaffected by the change in the nominal interest rate. The rise in i makes the LBC steeper by pivoting around the unchanged point ( y, y ), as shown in the diagram below: PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 6

c Initial LBC y New LBC y 4. Taxes on Interest Earnings. In our two-period consumption-savings model (with no leisure), suppose positive interest income in period is taxed at the rate t s, where 0< t s <. That is, if interest income in period is positive, then the government takes a fraction t s of the interest income, while if interest income in period is nonpositive, then there is no tax. As in class, make the simplifying assumption that the individual has zero initial wealth (i.e., A 0 = 0 ). Also suppose that the interest tax has no effect on the nominal price level in either period. a. In this modified version of the model, algebraically express the period- budget constraint and the period- budget constraint of the individual. Solution: In the standard model we have studied, interest income in period is given by the term ia. Here, when interest income is positive, the government taxes part of it away, leaving the individual with only part of his original interest income. In mathematical terms, we have here that interest income = { i( ts ) A if c < y ia if c y The tax is only levied if the individual has positive wealth at the end of period, which only occurs if his consumption is less than his real labor income in period. Thus, notice that interest income, net of the tax, is a piecewise function. With this, the period- budget constraint is also piecewise: PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 7

Y + ( + i( t )) A if c < y + A = Y + ( + i) A if c y s The period- budget constraint is unaffected by the tax, so it is simply + A = Y as usual. b. Using your period- and period- budget constraints from part a, derive the individual s lifetime budget constraint (LBC). (Hint: Is the slope of this LBC continuous?) Solution: As usual, we have that A = 0 because period is the last period of the economy. Solving the period- budget constraint for A (our usual next step at this point), we get Y if c < y + i( ts) + i( ts) = Y if c y A + i + i again piecewise. Substitute this expression for A into the period- budget constraint to get the LBC Y + = Y + if c < y + i( ts) + i( ts) Y + = Y + if c y + i + i Notice that if y, the LBC is the same as in our standard model (because t s = 0 ). If we solve the LBC for c as a function of c, we find c P( + i( t )) s + i( t ) s Y c+ Y+ if c < y P P P = P( + i) + i Y c+ Y+ if c y P P P Thus, the LBC is a piecewise linear function. It changes slope discontinuously at the point ( y, y ) : to the right of this point, the LBC is steeper than it is to the left of this point. Graphically, we have that the LBC has a kink in it: PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 8

c Slope = -P (+i(-t s ))/P y Slope = -P (+i)/p y c. Recall our assumption (based on empirical evidence) that the aggregate private savings function is an increasing function of the real interest rate. Suppose that at the representative agent s current optimal choice, he is choosing to consume exactly his real labor income in period. i. At his current optimal choice, is his marginal rate of substitution between present consumption and future consumption equal to (one plus) the real interest rate? Explain why or why not. Solution: If the individual s optimal choice is the following situation: c = y, then we must have * PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 9

c y y The indifference curve shown touches the LBC at the point ( y, y ) -- however, notice that it not tangent to the LBC at this point because the slope of the LBC at this point is undefined. That is, the slope has a (missing point) jump discontinuity at this point (try graphing the slope of the LBC for yourself to see it). Recall that the slope of an indifference curve is the marginal rate of substitution. From our basic microeconomics of consumer theory, we would be looking for the condition marginal rate of substitution equals the price ratio however, here the price ratio (the real interest rate) is undefined at the optimal choice. Thus, the MRS does not equal the price ratio here a perverse result that occurs here because the LBC has a kink in it and that kink point happens to be the point which gives the consumer the highest lifetime utility. ii. President Bush, as part of his first-term economic agenda, lowered the tax rate on interest income from savings (one part of this package was eliminating the tax on dividends but there are other elements of this idea in his tax package as well). Part of the rationale is that it will encourage individuals to save more. In this example, would a decrease in the tax rate t s encourage the representative agent to save more in period? Explain why or why not? Solution: As with many questions in economics, the answer here is that it depends. Specifically, it depends on the precise nature of the representative agent s indifference map. If the tax rate on interest earnings is lowered, this affects the slope of the upper portion of the LBC but not the slope of the lower portion specifically, it makes the upper portion of PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 0

the LBC steeper (just plug in a lower value of t s in the algebraic expressions in parts a and b above). Graphically: c Under low tax rate Under high tax rate y y Now suppose the individual s indifference map is as follows: PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh

c y y With very flat indifference curves, it is possible that the indifference curve on which the point ( y, y ) lies intersects the new upper portion of the LBC, in which case there must be another indifference curve which is tangent to the upper portion of the LBC. Such a tangency would therefore show the new optimal choice and because it is on the upper portion of the LBC, consumption in period is less than real labor income in period, so indeed the reduction in the interest tax has led to an increase in savings in period. However, this need not be the case. Consider instead the following situation: PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh

c y y If the indifference curves are very steep, as shown here, then it could be that despite the decrease in the interest tax, there still is no indifference curve that intersects the (new) upper portion of the LBC. If this is the case, then the original consumption choice ( y, y ) is still the optimal choice here, savings are completely unaffected despite the decrease in the interest tax. The economics to take away from this: despite the Bush economic team s pronouncements that lowering taxes on savings will necessarily lead to higher savings, it may or may not, depending on the average American s preferences over consumption in the present and consumption in the future. The second scenario shows a representative agent who simply does not want to save, regardless of the decrease in the interest tax. A simple analogy: if you absolutely hate pizza and it makes you sick, hearing that the pizza parlor down the street is now offering slices for one cent is not going to make you run out and buy pizza. PS 3 Solutions Sanjay K. Chugh 3