Lecture 16: Delta Hedging

Similar documents
Outline One-step model Risk-neutral valuation Two-step model Delta u&d Girsanov s Theorem. Binomial Trees. Haipeng Xing

Outline One-step model Risk-neutral valuation Two-step model Delta u&d Girsanov s Theorem. Binomial Trees. Haipeng Xing

Pricing Options with Binomial Trees

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

Risk-neutral Binomial Option Valuation

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Binomial Trees. Liuren Wu. Options Markets. Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Liuren Wu (Baruch ) Binomial Trees Options Markets 1 / 22

Introduction to Binomial Trees. Chapter 12

One Period Binomial Model: The risk-neutral probability measure assumption and the state price deflator approach

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Homework Assignments

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Cash Flows on Options strike or exercise price

Bose Vandermark (Lehman) Method

Option Pricing Models for European Options

The Multistep Binomial Model

non linear Payoffs Markus K. Brunnermeier

Binomial Trees. Liuren Wu. Zicklin School of Business, Baruch College. Options Markets

Final Exam. Please answer all four questions. Each question carries 25% of the total grade.

FINANCE 2011 TITLE: 2013 RISK AND SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT GROUP WORKING PAPER SERIES

B. Combinations. 1. Synthetic Call (Put-Call Parity). 2. Writing a Covered Call. 3. Straddle, Strangle. 4. Spreads (Bull, Bear, Butterfly).

Energy and public Policies

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Fixed-Income Securities Lecture 5: Tools from Option Pricing

SYSM 6304: Risk and Decision Analysis Lecture 6: Pricing and Hedging Financial Derivatives

Financial Markets & Risk

Hedging and Pricing in the Binomial Model

From Discrete Time to Continuous Time Modeling

LECTURE 12. Volatility is the question on the B/S which assumes constant SD throughout the exercise period - The time series of implied volatility

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

Option Pricing With Dividends

Option Pricing. Chapter Discrete Time

FINANCE 2011 TITLE: RISK AND SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT GROUP WORKING PAPER SERIES

1.1 Basic Financial Derivatives: Forward Contracts and Options

MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTIONS

Binomial Option Pricing and the Conditions for Early Exercise: An Example using Foreign Exchange Options

P&L Attribution and Risk Management

Lecture 1 Definitions from finance

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Optimal Portfolios under a Value at Risk Constraint

2 The binomial pricing model

Options Markets: Introduction

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

MATH 425: BINOMIAL TREES

Option Pricing Models. c 2013 Prof. Yuh-Dauh Lyuu, National Taiwan University Page 205

Help Session 2. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Appendix A Financial Calculations

Notes for Lecture 5 (February 28)

MATH 425 EXERCISES G. BERKOLAIKO

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

An Introduction to the Mathematics of Finance. Basu, Goodman, Stampfli

Finance: Lecture 4 - No Arbitrage Pricing Chapters of DD Chapter 1 of Ross (2005)

Edgeworth Binomial Trees

In general, the value of any asset is the present value of the expected cash flows on

EC3070 FINANCIAL DERIVATIVES FUTURES: MARKING TO MARKET

Lecture 18. More on option pricing. Lecture 18 1 / 21

Econ 174 Financial Insurance Fall 2000 Allan Timmermann. Final Exam. Please answer all four questions. Each question carries 25% of the total grade.

Computational Finance. Computational Finance p. 1

Pricing of Stock Options using Black-Scholes, Black s and Binomial Option Pricing Models. Felcy R Coelho 1 and Y V Reddy 2

Binomial Option Pricing

B8.3 Week 2 summary 2018

Fixed Income and Risk Management

Help Session 4. David Sovich. Washington University in St. Louis

Financial Derivatives Section 5

******************************* The multi-period binomial model generalizes the single-period binomial model we considered in Section 2.

INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES OF INDIA

Appendix: Basics of Options and Option Pricing Option Payoffs

FNCE 302, Investments H Guy Williams, 2008

Degree project. Pricing American and European options under the binomial tree model and its Black-Scholes limit model

Notes: This is a closed book and closed notes exam. The maximal score on this exam is 100 points. Time: 75 minutes

Bond Future Option Valuation Guide

ECON4510 Finance Theory Lecture 10

Derivative Instruments

UNIVERSITY OF AGDER EXAM. Faculty of Economicsand Social Sciences. Exam code: Exam name: Date: Time: Number of pages: Number of problems: Enclosure:

Employee Reload Options: Pricing, Hedging, and Optimal Exercise

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Hull, Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 9 th Edition

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Learning Martingale Measures to Price Options

Fixed-Income Options

OPTIONS CALCULATOR QUICK GUIDE

Some Computational Aspects of Martingale Processes in ruling the Arbitrage from Binomial asset Pricing Model

The Binomial Lattice Model for Stocks: Introduction to Option Pricing

Computational Finance Least Squares Monte Carlo

Course MFE/3F Practice Exam 1 Solutions

Youngrok Lee and Jaesung Lee

Lecture: Continuous Time Finance Lecturer: o. Univ. Prof. Dr. phil. Helmut Strasser

Risk Measures for Derivative Securities: From a Yin-Yang Approach to Aerospace Space

Chapter 24 Interest Rate Models

Evaluating the Black-Scholes option pricing model using hedging simulations

Introduction to Financial Derivatives

Stochastic Models. Introduction to Derivatives. Walt Pohl. April 10, Department of Business Administration

10. Discrete-time models

University of Texas at Austin. Problem Set #4

Theory and practice of option pricing

Transcription:

Lecture 16: Delta Hedging We are now going to look at the construction of binomial trees as a first technique for pricing options in an approximative way. These techniques were first proposed in: J.C. Cox, S.A. Ross, M. Rubinstein, Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach, Journal of Financial Economics 7 (1979), 229 264. 1 / 12

Example Suppose we want to value a European call option giving the right to buy a stock for the strike price K = AC 21 (the price in the contract) in 3 months (expiry date T ). The current stock price S 0 is AC 20. 2 / 12

Example Suppose we want to value a European call option giving the right to buy a stock for the strike price K = AC 21 (the price in the contract) in 3 months (expiry date T ). The current stock price S 0 is AC 20. We make a very simplifying assumption which in reality is not satisfied: in 3 months the stock price will be either AC 22 or AC 18. We do not know the probability for the occurrence of the stock prices AC 22 or AC 18. 2 / 12

Example Suppose we want to value a European call option giving the right to buy a stock for the strike price K = AC 21 (the price in the contract) in 3 months (expiry date T ). The current stock price S 0 is AC 20. We make a very simplifying assumption which in reality is not satisfied: in 3 months the stock price will be either AC 22 or AC 18. We do not know the probability for the occurrence of the stock prices AC 22 or AC 18. However, at expiry date, we know the value of the option: if the stock price goes up (to AC 22), the payoff S T K is AC 1; if the stock price goes down (to AC 18), then the option is worthless, so the value is 0. 2 / 12

A portfolio with one stock and shares Look at a portfolio which is generated at time 0 by buying many shares of a stock (long position) and selling one call option of the stock (short position). If f is the price of the option the portfolio at time 0 has value 20 f. After three months the value of this portfolio can be computed: if the stock prices moves from AC 20 to AC 22 then the value of the shares is AC 22 and the value of the option is AC 1, so the total value of the portfolio is 22 1 (in this case our contract partner has the right to buy from us one stock at the strike price AC 21, so we have to give him AC 1); If the stock prices moves from AC 20 to AC 18 then the value of the shares is AC 18 and the value of the option is zero, so the total value of the portfolio 18. 3 / 12

Strategy: delta hedging The idea is now to choose such that the value of the portfolio in both cases (stock price up or down) is the same: so we require 22 1 = 18, so = 0.25. Control: in 3 months if S T = AC 22, then the portfolio is worth 22 0.25 1 = AC 4.50. if S T = AC 18, then the portfolio is worth 18 0.25 = AC 4.50. 4 / 12

Strategy: delta hedging The idea is now to choose such that the value of the portfolio in both cases (stock price up or down) is the same: so we require 22 1 = 18, so = 0.25. Control: in 3 months if S T = AC 22, then the portfolio is worth 22 0.25 1 = AC 4.50. if S T = AC 18, then the portfolio is worth 18 0.25 = AC 4.50. Definition The delta of an option is the number of shares we should hold for one option (short position) in order to create a riskless hedge: so after maturity time T the value of the portfolio containing share and selling one call option is for both cases S T > K and S T K the same. The construction of a riskless hedge is called delta hedging. 4 / 12

So choosing = 0.25 leads to a portfolio where there is no uncertainty about the value of the portfolio in 3 months, namely AC 4.50. Since the portfolio has no risk we can compute its value at time 0 by discounting the price with the risk-free rate (no arbitrage opportunities). This means that we can find the value of the portfolio at time 0 by discounting the value in 3 months: 5 / 12

So choosing = 0.25 leads to a portfolio where there is no uncertainty about the value of the portfolio in 3 months, namely AC 4.50. Since the portfolio has no risk we can compute its value at time 0 by discounting the price with the risk-free rate (no arbitrage opportunities). This means that we can find the value of the portfolio at time 0 by discounting the value in 3 months: If we suppose that r = 12%, then the portfolio at time 0 is worth 4.50e 0.12 0.25 = AC 4.367. 5 / 12

So choosing = 0.25 leads to a portfolio where there is no uncertainty about the value of the portfolio in 3 months, namely AC 4.50. Since the portfolio has no risk we can compute its value at time 0 by discounting the price with the risk-free rate (no arbitrage opportunities). This means that we can find the value of the portfolio at time 0 by discounting the value in 3 months: If we suppose that r = 12%, then the portfolio at time 0 is worth 4.50e 0.12 0.25 = AC 4.367. Let f be the price of the call option today. Then the portfolio at time 0 has worth 20 0.25 f = 4.367, and so f = 20 0.25 4.367 = 0.633. 5 / 12

The general case We want to value the price f of an European option (put or call). The current stock price is S 0. 6 / 12

The general case We want to value the price f of an European option (put or call). The current stock price is S 0. We assume that after maturity time T the stock price S T will be either S 0 u (u > 1) or S 0 d (d < 1), where u stands for up, and d for down. After maturity time T we compute the value (payoff) of the option depending on the stock price S T and the strike price K: there are only two possibilities and we denote the value of the option by f u if the stock has gone up and by f d if it has gone down. 6 / 12

The general case We want to value the price f of an European option (put or call). The current stock price is S 0. We assume that after maturity time T the stock price S T will be either S 0 u (u > 1) or S 0 d (d < 1), where u stands for up, and d for down. After maturity time T we compute the value (payoff) of the option depending on the stock price S T and the strike price K: there are only two possibilities and we denote the value of the option by f u if the stock has gone up and by f d if it has gone down. In our example: if the stock price goes up (to AC 22), the value f u is AC 1; if the stock price goes down (to AC 18), then the value f d = 0. 6 / 12

The delta of a stock Look at a portfolio at time 0 generated by buying shares of a stock (long position) at stock price S 0 selling one option of the stock (short position). If f is the price of the option at time 0 then the portfolio at time 0 has value S 0 f. After expiry date T we can compute the value of the portfolio: if stock goes up the portfolio is worth S 0 u f u, if stock goes down the portfolio is worth S 0 d f d, We choose such that the value of the portfolio at time T in both cases (stock price up or down) is the same: S 0 u f u = S 0 d f d, 7 / 12

The delta of a stock From S 0 u f u = S 0 d f d, we find = f u f d S 0 (u d). Theorem Assume that the stock price S 0 after time T goes either up to S 0 u with u > 1 or down to S 0 d with d < 1. Let f u and f d be the payoffs at maturity time T in the case of up or down movement. Then the delta of one option is = f u f d S 0 (u d) = difference of payoffs at time T difference of prices of stock at time T. The delta of a call option is positive, whereas the delta of a put option is negative. 8 / 12

Using the choice = f u f d S 0 (u d) the value of portfolio at time T is in both cases (stock up or down) the same, namely: which is equal to S 0 u f u = S 0 u f u f d S 0 (u d) f u u fu f d u d f u = u (f u f d ) (u d) f u u d Thus the value of the portfolio at time T is P T := d f u u f d. u d = d f u u f d. u d 9 / 12

The portfolio is riskless. Since no arbitrage opportunities exist the portfolio at time 0 is worth P 0 = e rt P T = e rt df u uf d u d. The portfolio at time 0 is also worth P 0 = S 0 f = f u f d u d f. 10 / 12

The portfolio is riskless. Since no arbitrage opportunities exist the portfolio at time 0 is worth P 0 = e rt P T = e rt df u uf d u d. The portfolio at time 0 is also worth P 0 = S 0 f = f u f d u d f. Comparing these two values, we find f = f u f d u d df e rt u uf d u d = e rt u d = e rt u d ( e rt (f u f d ) (df u uf d ) ( ) f u (e rt d) + f d (u e rt ). ) 10 / 12

Put now Then Since p = ert d u d. ( f = e rt pf u + u ) ert u d f d. 1 p = u d u d ert d u d = u ert u d we obtain the final formula for the price f of an option: f = e rt [ pf u + (1 p)f d ]. 11 / 12

Summary Theorem Assume that the stock price S 0 after time T goes either up to S 0 u with u > 1 or down to S 0 d with d < 1. Let f be the price of an option (either call or put) at time 0 with payoff f u and f d respectively at time T. If r is the riskless interest rate then f = e rt [ pf u + (1 p)f d ] where p = ert d u d. 12 / 12

Summary Theorem Assume that the stock price S 0 after time T goes either up to S 0 u with u > 1 or down to S 0 d with d < 1. Let f be the price of an option (either call or put) at time 0 with payoff f u and f d respectively at time T. If r is the riskless interest rate then f = e rt [ pf u + (1 p)f d ] where p = ert d u d. In our previous example we had u = 1.1, d = 0.9, f u = 1, f d = 0, r = 0.12 and T = 0.25, so e0.12 0.25 0.9 p = = 0.6523, 1.1 0.9 f = e 0.12 0.25 (0.6523 1 + 0.3477 0) = 0.633. 12 / 12