ARE PUBLIC SECTOR WORKERS MORE RISK AVERSE THAN PRIVATE SECTOR WORKERS? DON BELLANTE and ALBERT N. LINK*

Similar documents
In Debt and Approaching Retirement: Claim Social Security or Work Longer?

Correcting for Survival Effects in Cross Section Wage Equations Using NBA Data

Gender Differences in the Labor Market Effects of the Dollar

An Empirical Note on the Relationship between Unemployment and Risk- Aversion

Retirement Plans of Mid die-aged Married Women 1

PUBLIC SECTOR WORKERS AND JOB SECURITY

ESTIMATING THE RISK PREMIUM OF LAW ENFORCEMENT OFFICERS. Brandon Payne East Carolina University Department of Economics Thesis Paper November 27, 2002

CAN AGENCY COSTS OF DEBT BE REDUCED WITHOUT EXPLICIT PROTECTIVE COVENANTS? THE CASE OF RESTRICTION ON THE SALE AND LEASE-BACK ARRANGEMENT

Monetary Policy Implications of Electronic Currency: An Empirical Analysis. Christopher Fogelstrom. Ann L. Owen* Hamilton College.

Married Women s Labor Force Participation and The Role of Human Capital Evidence from the United States

Equity, Vacancy, and Time to Sale in Real Estate.

Value of a Statistical Life: Relative Position vs. Relative Age

Green Giving and Demand for Environmental Quality: Evidence from the Giving and Volunteering Surveys. Debra K. Israel* Indiana State University

COMMUNITY ADVANTAGE PANEL SURVEY: DATA COLLECTION UPDATE AND ANALYSIS OF PANEL ATTRITION

RISK AVERSION AND THE PREFERENCE FOR PUBLIC SECTOR EMPLOYMENT: EVIDENCE FROM EGYPTIAN LABOR SURVEY DATA Mona Said

Employment Status of the Civilian Noninstitutional Population by Educational Attainment, Age, Sex and Race

Effect of Financial Resources And Credit On Savings Behavior Of Low-Income Families

The Economic Policy Institute is Wrong: Public Employees. ARE Overpaid. A Report by the Center for Union Facts

PUBLISHER ABSTRACT AB

Saving for Retirement: Household Bargaining and Household Net Worth

The Lack of Persistence of Employee Contributions to Their 401(k) Plans May Lead to Insufficient Retirement Savings

Incentives and political contributions*

THE PERSISTENCE OF UNEMPLOYMENT AMONG AUSTRALIAN MALES

A STUDY OF INVESTMENT AWARENESS AND PREFERENCE OF WORKING WOMEN IN JAFFNA DISTRICT IN SRI LANKA

Race to Employment: Does Race affect the probability of Employment?

Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln

Obesity, Disability, and Movement onto the DI Rolls

CORNELL STAFF PAPER. THE NATIONAL SCHOOL LUNCH PROGRAM Effects of. Recent Legislation on Participation in New York State

Income and Poverty Among Older Americans in 2008

Reemployment after Job Loss

Gender differences in defined contribution pension decisions

What You Don t Know Can t Help You: Knowledge and Retirement Decision Making

Individual and Neighborhood Effects on FHA Mortgage Activity: Evidence from HMDA Data

Review questions for Multinomial Logit/Probit, Tobit, Heckit, Quantile Regressions

COMMUNITY ADVANTAGE PANEL SURVEY: DATA COLLECTION UPDATE AND ANALYSIS OF PANEL ATTRITION

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY DO PENSIONS REDUCE MOBILITY? Ann A. McDermed. Working Paper No. 2509

Access to Retirement Savings and its Effects on Labor Supply Decisions

Determinants of Family Bond And Stock Holdings

COMMUNITY ADVANTAGE PANEL SURVEY: DATA COLLECTION UPDATE AND ANALYSIS OF PANEL ATTRITION

The Risk Tolerance and Stock Ownership of Business Owning Households

Estimating Personal Consumption With and Without Savings in Wrongful Death Cases

Table 1 Annual Median Income of Households by Age, Selected Years 1995 to Median Income in 2008 Dollars 1

a. Explain why the coefficients change in the observed direction when switching from OLS to Tobit estimation.

IJMIE Volume 2, Issue 3 ISSN:

International Review of Business Research Papers Vol. 4 No.3 June 2008 Pp

COMMONWEALTH JOURNAL OF COMMERCE & MANAGEMENT RESEARCH A STUDY ON GENDER DIFFERENCES IN INVESTOR SAVINGS BEHAVIOUR

Nonprofit organizations are becoming a large and important

The Strength of the Precautionary Saving Motive when Prudence is Heterogenous*

Social Security and Saving: A Comment

While total employment and wage growth fell substantially

Probabilistic Thinking and Early Social Security Claiming

PPI ALERT November 2011

Investment Platforms Market Study Interim Report: Annex 7 Fund Discounts and Promotions

Effect of Education on Wage Earning

Designing a Multipurpose Longitudinal Incentives Experiment for the Survey of Income and Program Participation

CHAPTER 6 DATA ANALYSIS AND INTERPRETATION

Analytical Framework and the Specification of the Model

Racial Differences in Labor Market Values of a Statistical Life

Online appendix for W. Kip Viscusi, Joel Huber, and Jason Bell, Assessing Whether There Is a Cancer Premium for the Value of a Statistical Life

The Use of Attrition Rates for Economic Loss Calculations in Employment Discrimination Cases: A Hypothetical Case Study

Is Debt Good or Bad for a Comfortable Retirement? Exploring the Relationship between Consumer Debt and Retirement Preparedness

THE BEHAVIOUR OF CONSUMER S EXPENDITURE IN INDIA:

Using Land Values to Predict Future Farm Income

This document provides additional information on the survey, its respondents, and the variables

Health Status and Portfolio Choice by Harvey S. Rosen, Princeton University Stephen Wu, Hamilton College. CEPS Working Paper No. 75.

BLS Spotlight on Statistics: Self-Employment in the United States

Analyzing the Determinants of Project Success: A Probit Regression Approach

How Do Predatory Lending Laws Influence Mortgage Lending in Urban Areas? A Tale of Two Cities

RISK AMD THE RATE OF RETUR1^I ON FINANCIAL ASSETS: SOME OLD VJINE IN NEW BOTTLES. Robert A. Haugen and A. James lleins*


Employer-Provided Health Insurance and Labor Supply of Married Women

ECONOMIC FACTORS ASSOCIATED WITH DELINQUENCY RATES ON CONSUMER INSTALMENT DEBT A. Charlene Sullivan *

Are Old Age Workers Out of Luck? An Empirical Study of the U.S. Labor Market. Keith Brian Kline II Sreenath Majumder, PhD March 16, 2015

PORTFOLIO CHOICE AND HEALTH STATUS. Harvey S. Rosen. Princeton University. Stephen Wu. Hamilton College. February 2003

A study on investor perception towards investment in capital market with special reference to Coimbatore City

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

Volume Author/Editor: John F. Kain and John M. Quigley. Volume URL:

Program on Retirement Policy Number 1, February 2011

Journal Of Financial And Strategic Decisions Volume 10 Number 3 Fall 1997 CORPORATE MANAGERS RISKY BEHAVIOR: RISK TAKING OR AVOIDING?

Issue Brief. Salary Reduction Plans and Individual Saving for Retirement EBRI EMPLOYEE BENEFIT RESEARCH INSTITUTE

Financial Risk Tolerance and the influence of Socio-demographic Characteristics of Retail Investors

Recent proposals to advance so-called right-to-work (RTW) laws are being suggested in states as a way to boost

Defined contribution retirement plan design and the role of the employer default

The demand for lottery expenditure in Taiwan: a quantile regression approach. Abstract

Answers To Chapter 12

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan

Ruhm, C. (1991). Are Workers Permanently Scarred by Job Displacements? The American Economic Review, Vol. 81(1):

Understanding the underlying dynamics of the reservation wage for South African youth. Essa Conference 2013

Income Convergence in the South: Myth or Reality?

Changes in Hours Worked Since 1950

401(k) PLANS AND RACE

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

A Profile of the Working Poor, 2001

SHARE OF WORKERS IN NONSTANDARD JOBS DECLINES Latest survey shows a narrowing yet still wide gap in pay and benefits.

EXECUTIVE COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE: BIG CARROT, SMALL STICK

Women in the Labor Force: A Databook

ECONOMIC POLICY UNCERTAINTY AND SMALL BUSINESS DECISIONS

The Determinants of Planned Retirement Age

Economic Recovery and Self-employment: The Role of Older Americans

Transcription:

ARE PUBLIC SECTOR WORKERS MORE RISK AVERSE THAN PRIVATE SECTOR WORKERS? DON BELLANTE and ALBERT N. LINK* Available evidence suggests that stability of employment is greater in the public sector than in the private sector. The value that individuals place on tbis stability depends on tbe individual's degree of risk aversion. Economic reasoning suggests tbat, otber tbings equal, tbose individuals witb a high degree of aversion to risk will be more likely tban otbers to seek employment in the public sector. This paper tests tbat hypothesis tbrougb tbe use of probit analysis and a measure of risk aversion developed in ibe University of Micbigan's Panel Study of Income Dynamics. The results tend to confirm tbe bypotbesis, implying tbat a policy of intersectoral equality of pay for comparable jobs would result inanexcesssupplyof workers to tbe public sector. ANUMBER of recent studies by Sharon Smith, among others, have compared public sector and private sector pay levels.' These studies conclude that government workers on average receive higher pay than workers in the private sector with equivalent human capital.^ If one assumes that workers Don Bellante is an associate professor of economics and Albert Link is an assistant professor of economics, both at Auburn University. They gratefully acknowledge helpful comments made by James E. Long. 'Sharon Smith, "Government Wage Differentials," Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 4, No. 3 (July 1977), pp. 248-71; Sharon Smith, "Government Wage Differentials by Sex," Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 11, No. 2 (Spring 1976), pp. 185-99; and Sharon P. Smith, "Pay Differentials Between Federal Government and Private Sector Workers," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 29, No. 2 (January 1976), pp. 179-97. 'This conclusion, when limited to wage rate compensation, does not hold up for each sex in each level of government. However, as we explain below, the in the public and private sectors should be paid the same wages, holding human capital characteristics constant, then the amount of difference in sectoral pay levels also measures the amount of overpayment to public sector workers. The assumption, however, is problematic. Economic theory suggests that since characteristics of jobs differ, "equalizing differences" in pay will be generated so as to achieve comparability in the net advantage to being employed in various occupations. Although documentation is sparse, it appears that working conditions are generally regarded as more favorable in public than in private employment. The fact that some characteristics of public sector jobs are more favorable can be documented. For example, fringe benefits are demonstrably more favorable, on average, in all levels of conclusion holds for both sexes at all three levels of government when fringe benefits are added to wages. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 34, No. 3 (April 1981). 1981 by Cornell University. 0019-7939/81/3403-0408101.00 408

RISK AVERSION AND SECTOR OF EMPLOYMENT 409 government employment than they are in private employment.' Indeed, when data on fringe benefits are added to Smith's figures, it is found that public compensation exceeds private pay at all levels of government.^ More recently, Quinn found evidence that, in terms of Dictionary of Occupational Titles definitions, state and federal government jobs are on average more attractive than jobs in the private sector with regard to five characteristics: variety, repetitiveness, strength requirements, physical involvement, and the presence of a group of poor working conditions.^ Local government jobs also fared better than private sector jobs in comparisons of the first two characteristics. Whether the marginal local government worker considers his working conditions more or less favorable than private employment can thus not be definitively determined from Quinn's results. Furthermore, earnings from government employment are usually thought to be more secure than earnings from private employment. Bloch and Smith demonstrated that the probability of becoming unemployed is considerably less for workers in the public sector than for those in the private sector, ceteris paribus.^ Hall, in fact, has estimated that for males the probability of becoming unemployed in the public sector is less than half the probability in the private sector.' 'Edward Friend, First National Survey of Employee Benefits of Full-Time Personnel of U.S. Municipalities {V/ashinglon, D.C: Labor Management Relations Service, 1972); U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, State Government Employee Compensation 1972, Bulletin 1899 (Washington, D.C: G.P.O., 1976); and U.S. General Accounting Office, Report to Congress, Need for a Comparability Policy for both Pay and Benefits of Federal Civilian Employees, F.P.C.D.-75-62 (Washington, D.C: G.P.O., July 1, 1975). 'Don Bellante and Mark Jackson, Labor Economics: Choice in Labor Markets (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979), pp. 249-51. ^Joseph Quinn, "Wage Differentials Among Older Workers in the Public and Private Sectors," Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 14, No. 1 (Winter 1979), pp. 55-57. 'Farrell Bloch and Sharon Smith, "Human Capital and Labor Market Employment," Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 14, No. 2 (Spring 1979), pp. 550-60. 'Robert Hall, "Turnover in the Labor Force," in Brookings Papers on Economics Activity (Washington, D.C: The Brookings Institution, 1972), pp. 709-56. In light of this empirical evidence, we should expect that innately more risk averse individuals have a preference for public sector employment, ceteris paribus- While such a conclusion flows directly from utility-maximization principles, the relation has never been demonstrated empirically. Accordingly, the purpose of this note is to investigate the relation between risk aversion and choice of sector of employment. Model and Analysis It is assumed that when an individual chooses a sector of employment, broadly defined here as the public or private sector, he is in effect choosing a specific set of jobrelated characteristics. Among these many characteristics is the degree of financial risk associated with the sector of employment, one index of such financial risk being the probability of becoming unemployed. Our hypothesis is that innately risk-averse individuals will have a greater propensity to choose the less risky sector, that is, the public sector. The economic literature is replete with studies of occupational choice; however, to our knowledge these studies have not addressed the choice of public or private sector employment.* Common to these studies is the hypothesis that the relevant human capital-demographic variables to consider in explaining occupational choice are education, job experience or age, marital status, family size, race, and sex. We have included an additional variable: the individual's innate tendency toward risk aversion. Our empirical analysis is based on a sample of 3643 working heads of household from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, ^Michael Boskin, "A Conditional Logit Model of Occupational Choice," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 82, No. 2 (March/April 1974), pp. 389-98; Abraham Haspel, "A Study in Occupational Choice: Managerial Positions," Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 44, No. 4 (April 1978), pp. 958-67; Peter Schmidt and Robert Strauss, "Estimation of Models with Jointly Dependent Variables: A Simultaneous Logit Approach," Econometrica, Vol. 43, No. 4 (July 1975), pp. 745-55; and Schmidt and Strauss, "The Prediction of Occupation Using Multiple Logit Models," International Economic Review, Vol. 16, No. 2 (June 1975), pp. 471-86.

410 INDUSTRIAL AND LABOR RELATIONS REVIEW prepared by the Survey Research Center of the University of Michigan, for the year 1972. Each individual was classified as working in either the public (nonmilitary) or the private sector (SOE). Public sector employees were coded by the number 1, and private sector employees were coded by the number 0. Eacb individual's age (AGE) and education (ED) were measured in years.' Work experience (EXP) was calculated as age less education less five. Marital status (MS) was measured as a binary variable with individuals currently married coded 1 and those not currently married coded 0. Family size (FS) was measured by the number of dependents living with the head of household. Race {RACE) and sex (SEX) were measured by binary variables. The number 0 was given to whites and to males, and the number 1 was given to nonwbites and to females. Tbe Panel Study reports an index of innate risk aversion (RA) for each head. This index is formulated on the basis of answers to questions involving the condition and insurance of automobiles owned, the use of seat belts, the head's extent of medical coverage, and the bead's smoking and drinking habits. This index ranges from 0 to 9, where 9 represents the highest level of risk aversion. The use of this index to proxy risk aversion can easily be criticized. The index has been derived on the basis of revealed consumer bebavior for insuring against unexpected cbanges in one's material possessions and physical health and, for that fact, it may partially reflect an ability rather than a propensity to avert risk. Nevertheless, the index has been used in at least one otber study and did perform as tbeoretically predicted.'" 'The head of household was asked, "How many grades of school did you finish?" Possible responses were as follows (with number of actual responses in parentheses): 1. 0-5 grades (3) 2. 6-8 grades (7) 3. 9-11 grades (10) 4. 12 grades (12) 5. 12 grades plus nonacademic training (14) 6. College, no degree (15) 7. College, degree (16) 8. College, advanced or professional degree (18) '"Robert Feinberg, "Risk Aversion, Risk, and the The probability of cboosing public sector employment was estimated in terms of these independent variables: (1) SOE = f(ed, AGE, AGE\ MS, FS, RACE, SEX, RA). The squared AGE variable is included to account for any possible nonlinear effect. An alternative form of Equation 1, Equation 1', was also estimated using EXP and EXP2 ratber than AGE and AGE\ Equations 1 and 1' were estimated by probit analysis and the results are shown in the first two columns of the table. Botb equations are statistically significant at the one percent level or better as measured by tbe likelihood ratio test.'' The reported probit coefficients and their significance level reveal the direction of the influence of the associated independent variable witb the dependent variable; however, they can not be interpreted directly as partial derivatives. There is a systematic relationship between a probit coefficient and its corresponding partial derivative.'^ Tbe partial derivatives are evaluated, at the mean, and are reported in the last two columns of the table. Since these estimates are almost identical for Equations 1 and 1', only the results from Equation 1 are discussed in detail. The estimated coefficient on ED is statistically significant at the one percent level or better and its partial derivative implies that a one-year increase in education increases the probability of selecting public sector employment by 0.5 percentage points. The influence of AGE is also statistically significant at the one percent level or better. Increases in A GE increase tbe probability of employment in tbe public sector until about age 50 and then the influence decreases. Clearly, the lower age group represents the majority of the work force. The impact of MS, FS, and SEX on the choice of sectoral Duration of Unemployment," Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 59, No. 3 (August 1977), pp. 269-71. "Jonathan Silberman and Garey Durden, "Determining Legislative Preferences on Minimum Wage: An Economic Approach," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 84, No. 2 (April 1976), pp. 317-29.

RISK AVERSION AND SECTOR OF EMPLOYMENT 411 Table. Estimated Probit Results from Equations 1 and 1'. (Asymptotic (-values are in parentheses) Probit Coefficients Partial Derivatives (1) (I') Constant - 4.626** (-9.049) - 3.586** (- 12.475) ED AGE AGE 2 EXP EXP 2 MS FS RACE SEX RA - 2 X Log Likelihood Ratio 0.061** (4.545) 0.070** (2.906) - 0.0008** (-2.750) 0.017 (0.104) 0.012 (0.567) 0.381** (4.119) 0.122 (0.722) 0.104** (3.691) 72.01** 0.061** (4.110) 0.035** (2.830) - 0.0006** (-2.578) 0.019 (0.114) 0.016 (0.767) 0.373** (4.048) 0.132 (0.784) 0.106** (3.787) 70.90** - 0.00005 0.0009 0.029 0.0009 0.008 0.002-0.00004 0.001 0.001 0.029 0.010 0.008 **Statistically significant at the one percent level or better. employment is zero. The estimated coefficient on RACE, however, is statistically significant at the one percent level or better, implying that the probability of public sector employment is 2.9 percentage points greater for blacks than for whites. This finding is consistent with the findings of other studies" and suggests an awareness of, and rational response to, the lesser degree of racial discrimination in the public sector. The estimated coefficient on RA is positive and statistically significant at the one percent level or better. Since tbe risk aversion index is measured ordinally rather tban cardinally, there is no meaningful "per unit change" interpretation tbat can "James Long, "Public-Private Sectoral Differences in Employment Discrimination," Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 42, No. 1 (July 1975), pp. 89-96. be given to tbe numerical value of its estimated partial derivative. Nevertbeless, our results do indicate that, as hypothesized, innately risk-averse individuals bave a greater probability of cboosing public sector tban private sector employment.'* Concluding Remarks Our results seem to suggest tbat laborforce participants correctly perceive tbat less risk is attacbed to public sector employment, and that they act on this information. Specifically, the more value tbe individual places on tbe job security associated witb '*It should be pointed out that although the coefficient of RA is very significant, its value is small; hence, the probability of choosing the public sector is only 7.2% higher for those at the upper end of the range of observation on risk aversion than for those at the lower end.

412 INDUSTRIAL AND LABOR RELATIONS REVIEW public sector employment, the greater his tendency to seek employment in the public sector. One important implication follows from this conclusion. If, as is usually assumed,'^ markets are dominated by risk averters, then theory suggests that, ceteris paribus, equal pay between the public and private sectors would generate an excess supply of labor to the public sector. Stated otherwise, equal net advantage would require lower pay rates in public employment than in private employment for workers with comparable human capital. Hence, studies such as those by Smith may understate the extent of "overpayment" of public sector workers unless there is reason to believe that other nonpecuniary factors are more favorable in the '*See, for example, Allan King, "Occupational Choice, Risk Aversion, and Wealth," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 27, No. 4 (July 1974), pp. 586-96. public sector, which would contradict the findings of Quinn.'^ Recognition of this fact clarifies an apparent anomaly. Smith's finding that males in local and state government are underpaid relative to their counterparts in the private sector is inconsistent with the common perception that there are queues of applicants for most state and local government jobs.^' Yet if this apparent "underpayment" is in reality a negative equalizing difference associated with the higher degree of job stability (and other desirable job characteristics) in these sectors, no inconsistency exists. Indeed, where queues are formidable, it is logical to conclude that the negative equalizing difference is perhaps not sufficiently large. "Quinn, "Wage Differentials Among Older Workers," pp. 41-62. "Smith, "Government Wage Differentials by Sex," Table 1, pp. 793-94.