Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour for the quantitative study of Social Security: two examples

Similar documents
Social Security Reforms in a Life Cycle Model with Human Capital Accumulation and Heterogeneous Agents

Retirement Savings Accounts and Human Capital Investment

Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States

Exercises on chapter 4

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Welfare Analysis of Progressive Expenditure Taxation in Japan

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Tax Benefit Linkages in Pension Systems (a note) Monika Bütler DEEP Université de Lausanne, CentER Tilburg University & CEPR Λ July 27, 2000 Abstract

The Effects of Financing Rules in Pay-As-You-Go Pension Systems on the Life and the Business Cycle

Designing the Optimal Social Security Pension System

Convergence of Life Expectancy and Living Standards in the World

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation.

Business Cycle Fluctuations and the Life Cycle: How Important is On-The-Job Skill Accumulation?

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

AK and reduced-form AK models. Consumption taxation. Distributive politics

The Macroeconomics e ects of a Negative Income Tax

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Privatizing Social Security

SOCIAL SECURITY: UNIVERSAL VS. EARNINGS DEPENDENT BENEFITS WORKING PAPER SERIES

Accounting for Patterns of Wealth Inequality

Unemployment, Income Growth and Social Security

Pension Reform in an OLG Model with Multiple Social Security Systems

Homework #4. Due back: Beginning of class, Friday 5pm, December 11, 2009.

Lecture 2, November 16: A Classical Model (Galí, Chapter 2)

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

Optimal Actuarial Fairness in Pension Systems

Financing National Health Insurance and Challenge of Fast Population Aging: The Case of Taiwan

Detailed Working Through Garegnani Reswitching Example Robert L. Vienneau 27 March 2005, Updated: 11 October 2005

CAN CAPITAL INCOME TAX IMPROVE WELFARE IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET ECONOMY WITH A LABOR-LEISURE DECISION?

Threshold cointegration and nonlinear adjustment between stock prices and dividends

1 The Solow Growth Model

1 Chapter 1: Economic growth

Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital

Appendix: Net Exports, Consumption Volatility and International Business Cycle Models.

working FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Social Security: Universal vs Earnings-Dependent Bene ts

1. Money in the utility function (start)

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Unfunded Pension and Labor Supply: Characterizing the Nature of the Distortion Cost

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Public Pension Reform in Japan

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 12 - Idiosyncratic Risk and Incomplete Markets Equilibrium April. Sciences Po

The Japanese saving rate between 1960 and 2000: productivity, policy changes, and demographics

Evaluating Fiscal Policy with a Dynamic Simulation Model

Aging, Social Security Reform and Factor Price in a Transition Economy

Intergenerational Policy and the Measurement of the Tax Incidence of Unfunded Liabilities

Human Capital Formation and General Equilibrium Treatment Effects: A Study of Tax and Tuition Policy

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Policy e ects of the elasticity of substitution across labor types in life cycle models

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Social Security in an Overlapping Generations Economy with Land*

Public versus Private Investment in Human Capital: Endogenous Growth and Income Inequality

Population ageing and economic growth in seven OECD countries

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Managing the maturity structure of government debt $

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

. Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective. May 10, 2013

Comment. Jonathan A. Parker Princeton University and NBER. 1. Introduction

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

Optimal Public Debt with Life Cycle Motives

Funded Pension Scheme, Endogenous Time Preference and Capital Accumulation

Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb

Does the Social Safety Net Improve Welfare? A Dynamic General Equilibrium Analysis

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

LECTURE 3 NEO-CLASSICAL AND NEW GROWTH THEORY

Limited Market Participation, Financial Intermediaries, And Endogenous Growth

The Japanese Saving Rate between : Productivity, Policy Changes, and Demographics

Essays on Exchange Rate Regime Choice. for Emerging Market Countries

APPENDIX A: Income inequality literature review

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

On the Distributional Effects of Social Security Reform*

The Influence of China s Pension System in the Context of Aging: with A Computable General Equilibrium Analysis. Abstract

Fiscal Consolidation Strategy: An Update for the Budget Reform Proposal of March 2013

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Problem set #2. Martin Ellison MPhil Macroeconomics, University of Oxford. The questions marked with an * should be handed in. max log (1) s.t.

Mitigating America s demographic dilemma by pre-funding social security $

IS FINANCIAL REPRESSION REALLY BAD? Eun Young OH Durham Univeristy 17 Sidegate, Durham, United Kingdom

ECON Chapter 6: Economic growth: The Solow growth model (Part 1)

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Methods Examination (Macro Part) Spring Please answer all the four questions below. The exam has 100 points.

The Theory of Taxation and Public Economics

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE MARGINAL EXCESS BURDEN OF DIFFERENT CAPITAL TAX INSTRUMENTS. Don Fullerton. Yolanda K. Henderson. Working Paper No.

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Endogenous Growth, Inequality and the Composition of Government Expenditures

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Online Appendices: Implications of U.S. Tax Policy for House Prices, Rents, and Homeownership

Transcription:

Applied Economics Letters, 2004, 11, 693 697 Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour for the quantitative study of Social Security: two examples CARMEN D. ALVAREZ-ALBELO Departamento de Ana lisis Econo mico, Facultad de Ciencias Econo micas, Universidad de La Laguna, Campus de Guajara. Camino La Hornera s/n 38071 La Laguna S/C de Tenerife, Spain and Centre for Research in Welfare Economics (CRWE-CREB), E-mail: calbelo@ull.es This paper explores the role of endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour for the quantitative evaluation of the impact of pay-as-you-go Social Security on labour supply. Pension response to a population growth rate change is also studied. Two dynamic general equilibrium models are used: one with human capital accumulation through learning-by-doing, and a second with exogenous efficiency units of labour. The main differences in the results are the following: (a) the shift in the working time-age profile induced by the elimination of Social Security considerably differs in both models. The increase in average hours worked is 4% higher under human capital accumulation than in the alternative model; and (b) the pension falls by a similar percentage in both models when the population growth rate is set to zero. This occurs because the capital labour ratio changes less under learning-bydoing than with exogenous efficiency units of labour. I. INTRODUCTION A well-established result from the empirical literature is that human capital is endogenous to individual s decisions over the life cycle (e.g. Shaw, 1986; Heckman et al., 1998; Imai, 2001). However, most quantitative works on pay-asyou-go (PAYG) Social Security ignore this fact and assume exogenous efficiency units of labour (e.g. Cooley and Soares, 1999; Kotlikoff et al., 1999). Since human capital accumulation extremely affects wage evolution and time allocation, its omission might lead to inaccurate conclusions when quantitatively studying Social Security issues. This paper analyses the role of human capital accumulation for assessing the PAYG Social Security impact on labour supply and the pension response to a reduction in population growth. Two dynamic general equilibrium models are used for this purpose: one with human capital investment through learning-by-doing (LBD) and the other with exogenous efficiency units of labour. There are two steps in the process. Both models are calibrated following the same criteria. The calibrated model economies succeed in matching observed hours worked and hourly wage profiles. Two simple exercises are performed in the second step: the Social Security system is removed and the population growth rate is set to zero. The analysis is limited to the comparison of stationary equilibria. The results from the first exercise reveal that the elimination of Social Security induces a radically different change in the labour supply age profile in both models, leading to a higher increase in average hours worked under LBD than with fixed efficiency units of labour. This is because LBD reinforces the substitution effect. When the population growth rate is set to zero, the pension falls by a similar percentage in both models, though slightly larger in the model using endogenous efficiency units. The reason is that the capital labour ratio, and hence the wage per efficiency unit of labour, varies less if human capital is endogenous. Applied Economics Letters ISSN 1350 4851 print/issn 1466 4291 online # 2004 Taylor & Francis Ltd http://www.tandf.co.uk/journals DOI: 10.1080/1350485042000236548 693

694 C. D. Alvarez-Albelo The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II presents the model economies. Section III describes the calibration procedure. Section IV presents and comments the results from the simulations. Lastly, Section V concludes the paper. II. DESCRIPTION OF THE MODEL ECONOMIES To simplify the notation, time index and the period at which agents were born are omitted in variables that remain unaltered in steady state. There is a continuum of identical firms, which operate with a constant returns to scale Cobb Douglas technology Y t ¼ BKt Nt 1 0 <<1 ð1þ where K t is the stock of physical capital, N t is the labour input in period t, and B is a scale parameter. There is no per capita output growth at long run. 1 Output can be used for consumption or for increasing the physical capital stock. The capital stock depreciates each period at the rate K. The conditions of equality between marginal productivities and factor prices from the maximization of profits by firms are R ¼ BKt 1 Nt 1 K W ¼ Bð1 ÞKt Nt ð2þ where R and W are interest rate and the wage per efficiency unit of labour, respectively. The economies have overlapping generations of households who live I periods, with ages denoted by i ¼ {1,..., I}. Agents work during the first I r 1 periods of their life and then retire. Retirement is compulsory. The population grows each period at a constant rate n. Each individual derives utility from an aggregate consumption good, C i, and disutility from the time devoted to work, L i, and maximizes his intertemporal utility discounted at a positive rate. There is no bequest motive. Preferences are represented by the following discounted utility function X I i 1 C C i LL i ð3þ i¼1 C L The budget constraint facing an individual can be written as ( ð1 þ RÞA i þ ð1 ÞWH i L i C i if 1 4 i 4 I r 1 A iþ1 ¼ ð1 þ RÞA i þ P C i if I r 4 i 4 I ð4þ where A i denotes wealth, H i represents efficiency units of labour, is the Social Security payroll tax and P is the pension. The only difference between these two models is in the assumption regarding efficiency units of labour. Model 1 incorporates human capital investment through LBD. Human capital technology is taken from Imai (2001), 2 H iþ1 ¼ a 0 þ a 1 H i þ ðb 0 b 1 ði 1ÞÞðc 0 þ H i Þ L i hn þ d e L c i hn 1 hn þ d hn Efficiency units of labour are exogenously given in the alternative model (Model 2). Each household maximizes its total discounted utility over the life cycle (Equation 3), subject to the initial conditions as well as constraints Equations 4 and 5 in Model 1, and Equation 4 in Model 2. It is assumed that agents have perfect foresight. The only role of the government is to administer the PAYG Social Security programme. The system is financed by workers proportional contributions on earnings and is balanced at each period. The pension is calculated as the sum of all workers Social Security contributions divided by the total number of retirees. In equilibrium, capital stock and the labour input in the economy are equal to K t ¼ XI i¼1 ð1 þ nþ t iþ1 A i N t ¼ XI r 1 ð1 þ nþ t iþ1 H i L i i¼1 III. CALIBRATION PROCEDURE Both models are calibrated to replicate some long-run observations of the American economy (calibration targets). Table 1 contains the parameter values and Fig. 1 shows simulated and actual age profiles of hours worked and pre-tax hourly wage. The calibration process classifies the parameters into two groups. Those in the first group are taken from other works, and the rest of parameters are calibrated to match the targets. In Model 1 six targets are used to calibrate seven parameters (, L,, L,B, K and b 1 ), while in Model 2 six parameters (except b 1 ) are calibrated with five targets. 3 ð5þ ð6þ 1 Human capital technology does not permit the introduction of either exogenous or endogenous growth. 2 hn is a parameter introduced here to rescale hours worked just to avoid dealing with large numbers in computation. See Imai (2001) for the justification of the functional form. 3 The non-linear least squares method (Levenberg Marquardt) used here permits systems with more unknowns than equations to be solved. The value for b 1 in Imai (2001) results too high to replicate the targets, this is why the parameter is calibrated.

Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour 695 Fig. 1. Age profiles of hours worked and pre-tax hourly wage delivered by the models confronted to actual data. The solid line represents profiles from the models, while the stars represent actual data from the PSID Table 1. Parameter values (baseline case) Population I ¼ 65 (age 84); I r ¼ 46 (age 65); n ¼ 0:012 (Cooley and Prescott, 1995) Social Security payroll tax ¼ 0:112 a (U.S. Social Security Administration) Output technology ¼ 0:36 (Rı os-rull, 1996); B ¼ 0:9025; K ¼ 0:0737 Preferences Model 1: ¼ 0:9624; C ¼ 0:0988; ¼ 16:7396; L ¼ 2:2011 Model 2: ¼ 0:9729; C ¼ 1:1356; ¼ 2:8837; L ¼ 2:1856 Human capital technology a 0 ¼ 0:03322; a 1 ¼ 0:3862; b 0 ¼ 0:1345; c 0 ¼ 0:04244; c 1 ¼ 0:0004057; d ¼ 404:2=hn; e ¼ 0:228 (Imai, 2001) hn ¼ 6000; b 1 ¼ 0:000393523 Exogenous efficiency units of labour In Fig. 1 Notes: a Old Age and Survivors Insurance (OASI) tax rate corresponding to 1990 1993. Sources: Between parentheses. The targets and sources are as follows. The capital output ratio (2.94) and the consumption output ratio (0.748) are taken from Rı os-rull (1996). 4 The third target is just a normalization of wage per efficiency unit of labour to the unit, which establishes the initial level of human capital to be equal to the hourly wage at age 20. The last three targets refer to mean and standard deviation of annual hours worked divided by 6000 (0.3116 and 0.053, respectively), and the average hourly wage (14.7292) taken from the 1993 Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID). 5 Average hourly wage is excluded in the calibration of Model 2. Lastly, human capital-age profile delivered by Model 1 is taken as the exogenous efficiency units of labour age profile in Model 2. Auerbach and Kotlikoff s (1987) numerical algorithm was modified to perform the computations of the models. Figure 1 shows that hours worked and hourly wage delivered by the calibrated model economies match quite well with those profiles from the data. 4 These are the observations constructed by Cooley and Prescott (1995), but do not reflect government data. 5 The sample is composed of 20 64 year olds, both sex family heads. Only individuals who belong to the employment status categories currently working and retired are included in the sample. The hourly wage is computed as annual labour income divided by annual hours worked. Data are collapsed in means by age.

696 C. D. Alvarez-Albelo IV. RESULTS The calibrated models are used to perform two simple exercises: to remove the Social Security from the economy and to set the population growth rate to zero. Table 2 and Fig. 2 contain the findings. 6 The Social Security payroll tax distorts time allocation. Removing the distortionary taxation has an income and substitution effect on the labour supply. Table 2 shows that the substitution effect dominates and average hours worked increases in both models, though that increase is 4% higher in Model 1 than in Model 2. The termination of the PAYG system also induces a shift in the age profile of labour supply. Figure 2 shows that in both models, young agents work less and old agents work more than in the initial steady state, reflecting that individuals have to save for their retirement. However, the reduction in hours worked by young agents is considerably lower in Model 1 than in Model 2. The results suggest that human capital accumulation plays an important role in explaining the different response of the labour supply in Model 1. Human capital investment takes place mainly at the beginning of the working life because the cost in terms of forgone leisure is lower, and the period to enjoy investment returns is longer. This is precisely why the working time barely falls at early ages and, consequently, average hours worked increases by a higher percentage in Model 1 than in the alternative model. When the population growth rate is set to zero, the pension decrease is similar in both frameworks, though about 1% greater in the first one. The result is due to the lower increase in the capital labour ratio, and hence in the wage per efficiency unit of labour, under LBD than with exogenous efficiency units (Table 2). This is because in the first model both working time and the human capital vary, while in the second model the efficiency units are fixed. The reduction in the population growth rate makes labour relatively scarcer than physical capital, raising its market value and generating incentives to work more. As in the previous exercise, substitution and income effects drive the labour supply response. However, in Model 1 the average working time increase is higher and average hourly wage raise is lower than in Model 2. This explains why the pension falls by a similar percentage in both models. Even though additional hours worked lead to more human capital, the increase in this variable is not large enough to compensate for the lower variation of wage per efficiency unit of labour. V. CONCLUSION General equilibrium models of Social Security typically ignore human capital investment and assume exogenous efficiency units of labour, which is in contradiction with the empirical evidence. If human capital is endogenous to individual s decisions, its omission might lead to inaccurate results when quantitatively analysing Social Security issues. This paper has presented two examples, which consider whether human capital accumulation through LBD or Table 2. Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour a Model 1 Model 2 Variable Baseline ¼ 0% n ¼ 0% Baseline ¼ 0% n ¼ 0% K=N 4.5937 5.0314 4.8930 4.5937 5.3793 5.1159 (9.5282) (6.5154) (17.1016) (11.3677) P 1.7257 0 1.2363 1.7316 0 1.2553 ( 100) ( 28.3595) ( 100) ( 27.5063) R 4.87% 4.18% 4.39% 4.87% 3.70% 4.06% ( 14.1683) ( 9.8562) ( 24.0246) ( 16.6324) W 1.0000 1.0333 1.0230 1.0000 1.0585 1.0395 (3.3300) (2.3000) (5.8500) (3.9500) L b 0.3116 0.3274 0.3210 0.3116 0.3150 0.3189 (5.0706) (3.0166) (1.0911) (2.3427) H b 14.7292 14.9849 14.8618 14.7292 14.7292 14.7292 (1.7360) (0.9002) (0) (0) WH b 14.7292 15.4839 15.2033 14.7292 15.5908 15.3110 (5.1238) (3.2187) (5.8500) (3.9500) WHL b 4.6101 5.0971 4.9058 4.6406 5.0294 4.9815 (10.5637) (6.4141) (8.3782) (7.3460) Notes: a Variations in percentage respect to the baseline case between parentheses; b The dash over the variables denotes means. 6 Data, codes and results are available upon request via e-mail.

Endogenous versus exogenous efficiency units of labour 697 a similar percentage in both cases. However the reduced variation in the capital labour ratio is the main reason why this occurs. Though more research is needed on the role of human capital investment in quantitative models of Social Security, the findings obtained here suggest that the typical assumption of exogenous efficiency units of labour should be reconsidered. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I am deeply indebted to Vı ctor Rı os for his help and suggestions. I am also grateful to Fernando Perera for his comments. REFERENCES Fig. 2. Effects on hours worked due to Social Security elimination. The solid line represents the no Social Security case, while the stars represent the baseline case exogenous efficiency units of labour considerably modifies the quantitative results. More specifically, it has shown that the elimination of PAYG Social Security induces a higher increase in average hours worked under LBD than with fixed efficiency units of labour. Additionally, when the population growth rate is set to zero, the pension falls by Auerbach, A. J. and Kotlikoff, L. J. (1987) Dynamic Fiscal Policy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Cooley, T. F. and Prescott, E. (1995) Economic growth and business cycle, in Frontiers of Business Cycle Research (Ed.) T. F. Cooley, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, pp. 1 38. Cooley, T. F. and Soares, J. (1999) Privatizing social security, Review of Economic Dynamics, 2, 731 55. Heckman, J., Lochner, L. and Taber, C. (1998) Explaining rising wage inequality: explanations with a dynamic general equilibrium model of labor earnings with heterogeneous agents, Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 1 58. Imai, S. and Keane, M. P. (2004) Intertemporal labor supply and human capital accumulation, International Economic Review, 45(2), 601 41. Kotlikoff, L. J., Smetters, K. and Walliser, J. (1999) Privatizing social security in the United States: comparing the options, Review of Economic Dynamics, 2, 532 74. Ríos-Rull, J. V. (1996) Life-cycle economies and aggregate fluctuations, Review of Economic Studies, 63, 465 89. Shaw, K. (1986) Life-cycle labor supply with human capital accumulation, International Economic Review, 30, 431 56.