Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets

Similar documents
Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

EC 202. Lecture notes 14 Oligopoly I. George Symeonidis

DUOPOLY. MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell. July 2017 Frank Cowell: Duopoly. Almost essential Monopoly

Lecture 9: Basic Oligopoly Models

Answer Key. q C. Firm i s profit-maximization problem (PMP) is given by. }{{} i + γ(a q i q j c)q Firm j s profit

Chapter 3. Dynamic discrete games and auctions: an introduction

ECO410H: Practice Questions 2 SOLUTIONS

What s New in Econometrics. Lecture 11

L industria del latte alimentare italiana: Comportamenti di consumo e analisi della struttura di mercato

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

Noncooperative Oligopoly

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Lecture 13 Price discrimination and Entry. Bronwyn H. Hall Economics 220C, UC Berkeley Spring 2005

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

The test has 13 questions. Answer any four. All questions carry equal (25) marks.

A monopoly is an industry consisting a single. A duopoly is an industry consisting of two. An oligopoly is an industry consisting of a few

UCLA Department of Economics Ph.D. Preliminary Exam Industrial Organization Field Exam (Spring 2010) Use SEPARATE booklets to answer each question

Pricing Behavior in Markets with State Dependence in Demand. Technical Appendix. (for review only, not for publication) This Draft: July 5, 2006

Choice Models. Session 1. K. Sudhir Yale School of Management. Spring

Multiproduct-Firm Oligopoly: An Aggregative Games Approach

Lecture Note 3. Oligopoly

Lecture 4: Graduate Industrial Organization. Characteristic Space, Product Level Data, and Price Indices.

Automobile Prices in Equilibrium Berry, Levinsohn and Pakes. Empirical analysis of demand and supply in a differentiated product market.

Noncooperative Market Games in Normal Form

MICROECONOMICS AND POLICY ANALYSIS - U8213 Professor Rajeev H. Dehejia Class Notes - Spring 2001

Introduction to Industrial Organization Professor: Caixia Shen Fall 2014 Lecture Note 5 Games and Strategy (Ch. 4)

Estimating the Effect of Tax Reform in Differentiated Product Oligopolistic Markets

The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry

Choice Probabilities. Logit Choice Probabilities Derivation. Choice Probabilities. Basic Econometrics in Transportation.

MKTG 555: Marketing Models

LECTURE NOTES ON GAME THEORY. Player 2 Cooperate Defect Cooperate (10,10) (-1,11) Defect (11,-1) (0,0)

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati

ECE 586BH: Problem Set 5: Problems and Solutions Multistage games, including repeated games, with observed moves

Part 2: Monopoly and Oligopoly Investment

When one firm considers changing its price or output level, it must make assumptions about the reactions of its rivals.

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

Static Games and Cournot. Competition

is the best response of firm 1 to the quantity chosen by firm 2. Firm 2 s problem: Max Π 2 = q 2 (a b(q 1 + q 2 )) cq 2

Estimating Mixed Logit Models with Large Choice Sets. Roger H. von Haefen, NC State & NBER Adam Domanski, NOAA July 2013

Research Note Endogeneity and Heterogeneity in a Probit Demand Model: Estimation Using Aggregate Data

This article appeared in a journal published by Elsevier. The attached copy is furnished to the author for internal non-commercial research and

Economics Multinomial Choice Models

How (not) to measure Competition

ECON/MGMT 115. Industrial Organization

Economics Honors Exam 2009 Solutions: Microeconomics, Questions 1-2

Game Theory Fall 2003

Business Strategy in Oligopoly Markets

R&D, International Sourcing and the Joint Impact on Firm Performance: Online Appendix

ESTIMATING THE EFFECTS OF TAX REFORM IN DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCT OLIGOPOLISTIC MARKETS. Chaim Fershtman, Neil Gandal and Sarit Markovich

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

PhD Qualifier Examination

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Monopolistic competition models

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 9

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Problem 3,a. ds 1 (s 2 ) ds 2 < 0. = (1+t)

Heterogeneity in Multinomial Choice Models, with an Application to a Study of Employment Dynamics

ISSN BWPEF Uninformative Equilibrium in Uniform Price Auctions. Arup Daripa Birkbeck, University of London.

Measuring market power in the Spanish mutual funds industry for retail investors

GT CREST-LMA. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative Prices

PhD Qualifier Examination

Two-Part Tariffs versus Linear Pricing Between Manufacturers and Retailers : Empirical Tests on Differentiated Products Markets

Inflation Dynamics During the Financial Crisis

Solution to Assignment 3

Lecture 3: Tax incidence

Strategic Production Game 1

Adverse Selection in the Loan Market

Financial Liberalization and Neighbor Coordination

Table 10.1: Elimination and equilibrium. 1. Is there a dominant strategy for either of the two agents?

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

Generalized Multi-Factor Commodity Spot Price Modeling through Dynamic Cournot Resource Extraction Models

Parallel Accommodating Conduct: Evaluating the Performance of the CPPI Index

Increasing Returns and Economic Geography

ECON106P: Pricing and Strategy

Two-Part Tariffs versus Linear Pricing Between Manufacturers and Retailers : Empirical Tests on Differentiated Products Markets

Internationalization of Production: FDI and. FDI-Outsourcing

Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs. SS223B-Empirical IO

Two-Part Tariffs versus Linear Pricing Between Manufacturers and Retailers : Empirical Tests on Differentiated Products Markets

Economics Honors Exam 2008 Solutions Question 1

Oligopoly Games and Voting Games. Cournot s Model of Quantity Competition:

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2005

GS/ECON 5010 Answers to Assignment 3 November 2008

Online Appendix to R&D and the Incentives from Merger and Acquisition Activity *

Maximin and minimax strategies in asymmetric duopoly: Cournot and Bertrand

Endogenous Cartel Formation with Differentiated Products and Price Competition

Dynamic Replication of Non-Maturing Assets and Liabilities

EconS 424 Strategy and Game Theory. Homework #5 Answer Key

Discrete Choice Theory and Travel Demand Modelling

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

A potentially useful approach to model nonlinearities in time series is to assume different behavior (structural break) in different subsamples

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Pricing Problems under the Markov Chain Choice Model

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

Competition in Electricity Markets with Renewable Sources

Vertical Relations: Double Marginalization, Price Negotiation and Integration

Transcription:

Estimating Market Power in Differentiated Product Markets Metin Cakir Purdue University December 6, 2010 Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 1 / 28

Outline Outline Estimating structural market equilibrium models Supply side: Review of Cournot and Bertrand competition Demand side: Homogeneous vs. differentiated product markets Review of classical demand system models Random utility models: Discrete choice modeling An empirical application to ready to eat cereal industry Nevo, 2001 Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 2 / 28

Quantity Setting Firms Cournot Model: Max q i π i = P(Q)q i c(q i ) Supply Side Cournot Competition where Q is aggregate quantity and q i is quantity produced by firm i. The FOC is: π i q i where = P + q i P(Q) q i c (q i ) = 0 P(Q) q i P(Q) q i P(Q) q i = P(Q) Q Q q i = P(Q) Q = P(Q) } Q {{ } P (Q) ( qi q i + q j ( q i ) 1 + q ) j q } {{ i } θ C Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 3 / 28

Quantity Setting Firms Supply Side Cournot Competition At the optimum P = MC P (Q)θ C q i where P (Q) is the slope of inverse demand, θ C = Q q i = 1 + q j q i is the conjectural variation (not elasticity). θ C = 1 Cournot-Nash. ( q j q i = 0) θ C = 0 Perfect Comp. ( q j q i = 1) θ C = N Cartel (Symmetry) ( q j q i = 1) Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 4 / 28

Price Setting Firms Supply Side Bertrand Competition Bertrand Model: Bertrand competition refers to a model of oligopoly in which two or more firms compete by simultaneously setting prices. A price setting game can be formalized as: Players: n 2 players (firms), i,..., n Actions: Each firm simultaneously sets price p i P i = [0, ] Payoffs: π i (p i, p i ) = p i D(p i, p i ) C i (D(p i, p i )) Under assumption of profit maximization A Bertrand Nash equilibrium is a vector of prices (pi, p i ) such that for each player i, Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 5 / 28

Supply Side Bertrand Competition Price Setting Firms Bertrand equilibrium with differentiated products is simply the solution to the system of first-order conditions implied by each firms profit-maximizing pricing decision. Let output of each firm denoted as: Firm i s profit maximization problem is given as: Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 6 / 28

Supply Side Bertrand Competition Price Setting Firms P i = MC q i / dq i dp i where dq i dp i dq i dp i = q i p i p i p i + q i p j p j p i = q i p i + q i p j θ B θ B = 0 Bertrand-Nash. (p i = MC q i / q i p i ) θ B = Perfect Comp. p i = MC θ B = 1 Cartel (Symmetry) (p i = MC q i /( q i p i + q i p j )) Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 7 / 28

Demand Side Homogeneous Product Markets NEIO models are typical examples of structural market equilibrium models for homogeneous product markets. Empirical applications use macro (aggregate) data Demand side: Typically a single product demand curve is estimated Supply side: A model of Cournot competition is employed Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 8 / 28

Demand Side Differentiated Product Markets Could refer to vertical or horizontal differentiation Empirical applications use brand and/or individual level data Demand side: Requires a demand system estimation of competing brands Supply side: A model of Bertrand competition is employed Wide range of applicability of these models in IO and Marketing: Analysis of competition Market power Price discrimination Advertisement Merger analysis Analysis of consumer behavior Sensitivity to price Valuation of product attributes Brand loyalty Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 9 / 28

Demand Side Demand system models: The dimensionality problem Suppose we have observations of the same 50 brands of ice cream from 50 cities, 2500 data points. We also have data on 4 product and 6 consumer characteristics. We seek to estimate bulk ice cream demand elasticity. We can take a classical demand system approach, i.e. AIDS model. This would require: Estimating a total of 2500 own and cross price elasticities, using 2500 data points Even with symmetry, homogeneity and adding up restrictions estimation would be impractical Instead we can work in product characteristics space rather than product space (discrete choice models): Redefine consumer s utility as a function of product characteristics Redefine consumer s problem as a probability of buying a particular product rather than how much to buy Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 10 / 28

Demand Side Random Utility Models, RUM Random Utility Models RUMs describe the relation of explanatory variables to the outcome of a choice, without reference to exactly how the choice is made. Agent i, i = 1,..., n is assumed to make a choice among j = 1, 2,..., J possible alternatives. Agent i chooses the alternative that provides the greatest utility, U ij > U ik j k Researcher observes the choice and its attributes, x ij, but not the utility Therefore, the utility is assumed to be represented additively as the sum of a partially observable part, V ij, and an unobservable part, ɛ ij, such that Usually we ll assume V ij = x ij β Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 11 / 28

Demand Side Random Utility Models, RUM Random Utility Models Let f(ɛ i ) denote the joint density of random vector ɛ i = (ɛ i1,..., ɛ ij ). The probability that agent i chooses alternative j is: This cumulative distribution is the probability of each random term ɛ ik ɛ ij is below observed quantity V ij V ik. Since the joint density of random errors is f(ɛ i ), we can rewrite as: where I is indicator function equal to 1 if the term in parentheses is true. The model collapses to logit if f(ɛ i ) is i.i.d. extreme value The model collapses to probit if f(ɛ i ) is multivariate normal Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 12 / 28

Demand Side Multinomial Logit Multinomial Logit Logit model is derived by assuming error terms follow a Type I extreme value distribution. Specifically, assume that the errors are independent across i and j with a density function: f(ɛ ij ) = exp( ɛ ij )exp( e ɛ ij)), and the cumulative function F(ɛ ij ) = exp( e ɛ ij)) By this assumption the logit probability of individual i choosing alternative j is Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 13 / 28

Demand Side Multinomial Logit Estimation Likelihood function: L(β) = n J i=1 j=1 (P ij) Y ij where Y ij =1 if person i selects j and zero otherwise. The loglikelihood is: L(β) = n J i=1 j=1 Y ij(x ij β log[ J j=1 exp(x ijβ)]) where V ij = x ij β. The score is L β (β) = i j (Y ij P ij )x ij ) Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 14 / 28

Demand Side Multinomial Logit Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives, IIA MNL model is subject to IIA problem. Take 2 alternatives k and l P ik P il = [exp(v ik )/ j l=1 exp(v il][exp(v il )/ j l=1 exp(v il] 1 That is, the ratio of probabilities are unaffected from any other outside alternatives. Because they cancel at the ratio. This imposes restrictions on substitution patterns Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 15 / 28

Demand Side Multinomial Logit Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives, IIA The reason for IIA problem is i.i.d errors not the logit itself The problem is that consumer characteristics are independent of the observed product The solution to this problem can be interacting consumer characteristics with product characteristics Nested Logit Mixed Logit Multinomial Probit Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 16 / 28

Empirical Application Nevo, 2001, Econometrica RTE industry is a classic example of a concentrated differentiated-products industry: high concentration high price-cost margins large advertising to sales ratio aggressive introduction of new products The paper analyzes price competition by estimating the true economic price-cost margins (PCM) and distinguishing between three sources: firm s ability to differentiate its brands from those of its competitors portfolio effect (ability to charge more by producing imperfect substitutes) price collusion Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 17 / 28

Empirical Application Nevo, 2001, Econometrica The steps of estimation are: estimate the demand function (random coefficient logit model) as a function of observed product characteristics, unobserved product characteristics, and unknown parameters Compute PCM implied by three industry structures by using demand elasticities single product firms multi-brand oligopolistic firms multi-brand monopolistic firm Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 18 / 28

Empirical Application Supply side Empirical Framework: Supply Side Suppose there are F firms, each of which produces some subset, Γ j, of the j = 1,..., J different brands. define Ω = 1 if f : (r, j) Γ f, Ω = 0 otherwise. then Ω jr = Ω S jr where S jr = s r (p) p j s(p) Ω(p mc) = 0 Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 19 / 28

Empirical Application Supply side Empirical Framework: Supply Side Notice the resemblance to the simple Bertrand Model θ B = 0 Bertrand-Nash. (P i = MC q i / q i P i ) θ B = Perfect Comp. P i = MC θ B = 1 Cartel (Symmetry) (P i = MC q i /( q i P i + q i P j )) Ownership matrix allows to estimate different market structures. If none of the products are within the same subset it is single-product Bertrand-Nash If some of the products are within the same subset it is multi-product Bertrand-Nash If all of the products are within the same subset it is collusion Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 20 / 28

Empirical Application Demand side Empirical Framework: Demand Side Multinomial Logit: The estimation of the demand curves using random coefficient logit model is not an easy task. To better understand the procedure we first focus on estimation via multinomial logit. Let the utility of consumer i from choosing alternative j in town t is given by the equation: where i = 1,..., N, j = 1,..., 50, t = 1,..., 50 p jt observed price of product j in town t, x jt is 4 dimensional observed product characteristics, ξ jt is the unobserved product characteristics, ɛ ijt is mean zero error term Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 21 / 28

Empirical Application Demand side Empirical Framework: Demand Side Multinomial Logit: Since the coefficients are the same for all consumers we can obtain an aggregate utility function Assuming ɛ jt is i.i.d extreme value, the market share of product j is given by Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 22 / 28

Empirical Application Demand side Empirical Framework: Demand Side Multinomial Logit: Elasticities of Demand s jt = e x jt β αp jt +ξ jt 1+ 50 1 ex kt β αp kt +ξ kt We seek to obtain s jt p kt. Let G j = e x jt β αp jt +ξ jt s jt = s jt p kt = If k j then G j 1+ 50 1 G k G j p kt 1+ 50 1 G k s jt 0 p kt = 1+ 50 1 G k ( s jt p kt = α ( ) ( ) G + j (1+ Gk 50 1 G k ) 2 p kt ( + G j (1+ 50 1 G k ) ) G j (1+ 50 1 G k ) 2 ) ( G k (1+ 50 1 G k ) ( αg k ) ) so that Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 23 / 28

Empirical Application Demand side Empirical Framework: Demand Side Multinomial Logit: Elasticities of Demand s jt p kt ( = α G j (1+ 50 1 G k ) ) ( G k (1+ 50 1 G k ) ) Products with higher shares are close substitutes regardless of content similarly it can be shown that if If k = j then Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 24 / 28

Empirical Application Demand side Empirical Framework: Demand Side Random Coefficient Logit u ijt = x j β i α i p jt + ξ j + ξ jt + ɛ ijt individual heterogeneity is captured as deviations from mean value: α i = α + ΠD i + Σv i β i = β + ΠD i + Σv i v i N(0, I K+1 ) Note that coefficients are functions of demographic variables and unobserved component v i Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 25 / 28

Empirical Application Demand side Empirical Framework: Demand Side Random Coefficient Logit Let θ = (θ 1, θ 2 ) where θ 1 = (α, β) and θ 2 = (vec(π), vec(σ)) then the utility can be rewritten as deviations from mean u ijt = δ jt (x j, p jt, ξ j, ξ jt ; θ 1 ) + µ ijt (x j, p jt, v i, D i ; θ 2 ) + ɛ ijt δ jt = x j β i α i p jt + ξ j + ξ jt Component of utility from alternative j that is same across all consumers µ ijt = [p jt, x j ] (ΠD i + Σv i ) component of utility from alternative j that is individual specific Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 26 / 28

Empirical Application Demand side Empirical Framework: Demand Side Random Coefficient Logit: Market Shares Under the assumption of Type I extreme value for ɛ ijt the market share s ijt is given by: s ijt = ν D e δ jt +µ ijt 1+ 50 1 eδ jt +µ ijt s jt (x, p t, δ t ; θ 2 ) = [ ν] D dp (D, v, ɛ) = dp (v)dp (D) e δ jt +µ ijt 1+ 50 1 eδ jt +µ ijt Integral can be evaluated by simulation to obtain shares. It adds up the market shares of different types of consumers based on distribution of types. Nevo (2000a): A Practitioner s Guide to estimation of Random Coefficients Logit Models of Demand, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 9, 513-549. Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 27 / 28

Empirical Application Demand side Empirical Framework: Demand Side Random Coefficient Logit: Elasticities of Demand Own price elasticity, j = k, η jkt = p jt s jt ν D α is ijt (1 s ijt )dp (v)dp (D) Cross price elasticity, j k, η jkt = p kt s jt ν D α is ijt s ikt dp (v)dp (D) Metin Cakir (Purdue) Market Equilibrium Models December 6, 2010 28 / 28