For Online Publication. The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix

Similar documents
Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? *

Empirical Effects of Monetary Policy and Shocks. Valerie A. Ramey

If the Fed sneezes, who gets a cold?

Testing the Stickiness of Macroeconomic Indicators and Disaggregated Prices in Japan: A FAVAR Approach

Measuring the Channels of Monetary Policy Transmission: A Factor-Augmented Vector Autoregressive (Favar) Approach

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

LECTURE 3 The Effects of Monetary Changes: Vector Autoregressions. September 7, 2016

Monetary Policy Matters: New Evidence Based on a New Shock Measure

Online Appendix to: The Composition Effects of Tax-Based Consolidations on Income Inequality. June 19, 2017

Effects of US Monetary Policy Shocks During Financial Crises - A Threshold Vector Autoregression Approach

Monetary Policy and Income Inequality in Korea

Web Appendix. Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Olivier Coibion

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

Current Account Balances and Output Volatility

Comments on Foreign Effects of Higher U.S. Interest Rates. James D. Hamilton. University of California at San Diego.

Changes in Monetary Regimes and the Identification of Monetary Policy Shocks: Narrative Evidence from Canada

Inflation Regimes and Monetary Policy Surprises in the EU

On the size of fiscal multipliers: A counterfactual analysis

Government Spending Shocks in Quarterly and Annual Time Series

Not-for-Publication Appendix to:

Do Fed Forecast Errors Matter?

The Gertler-Gilchrist Evidence on Small and Large Firm Sales

Online Appendixes to Missing Disinflation and Missing Inflation: A VAR Perspective

The effect of monetary policy on housing tenure choice as an explanation for the price puzzle

Short-run effects of fiscal policy on GDP and employment in Sweden

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY AND SECTORAL SHOCKS: DID THE FED REACT PROPERLY TO THE HIGH-TECH CRISIS? Claudio Raddatz Roberto Rigobon

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Risk-Adjusted Futures and Intermeeting Moves

Measuring Oil-price Shocks Using Market-based Information

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Workshop on resilience

Stress-testing the Impact of an Italian Growth Shock using Structural Scenarios

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

The International Transmission of Euro Area Monetary Policy Shocks. by Nils Jannsen and Melanie Klein

Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in Structural VAR models

OUTPUT SPILLOVERS FROM FISCAL POLICY

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

MEASURING OIL-PRICE SHOCKS USING MARKET-BASED INFORMATION

Rethinking the Link Between Exchange Rates & Inflation: Misperceptions and New Approaches

This is a repository copy of Asymmetries in Bank of England Monetary Policy.

Investment, Financial Frictions and the Dynamic Effects of Monetary Policy

Monetary Policy and Sectoral Shocks: Did the Federal Reserve React Properly to the High-Tech Crisis?

Decomposing the Effects of Monetary Policy Using an External Instruments SVAR

Monetary Policy Surprises, Credit Costs and Economic Activity

A Model of Monetary Policy Shocks for Financial Crises and Normal Conditions

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

A New Measure of Monetary Policy Shocks

Same, but different: testing monetary policy shock measures

Demographics and Monetary Policy Shocks

The Economic Effects of Government Spending * (Preliminary Draft)

Demographics and Monetary Policy Shocks

BIS Working Papers. Do interest rates play a major role in monetary policy transmission in China? No 714. Monetary and Economic Department

Supplementary Appendix. July 22, 2016

Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series

Productivity, monetary policy and financial indicators

News Shocks and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: Reply Online Appendix

Discussion of Beetsma et al. s The Confidence Channel of Fiscal Consolidation. Lutz Kilian University of Michigan CEPR

MONETARY ECONOMICS Objective: Overview of Theoretical, Empirical and Policy Issues in Modern Monetary Economics

CONFIDENCE AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: THE CASE OF PORTUGAL*

Delayed Overshooting: Is It an 80s Puzzle?

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession

The Economic Effects of Government Spending * (First Draft)

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ARE GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS GREATER DURING PERIODS OF SLACK? EVIDENCE FROM 20TH CENTURY HISTORICAL DATA

Figure 1: The function g(.)

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

THE EFFECTS OF FISCAL POLICY ON EMERGING ECONOMIES. A TVP-VAR APPROACH

Misspecification, Identification or Measurement? Another Look at the Price Puzzle

Volume 35, Issue 1. Thai-Ha Le RMIT University (Vietnam Campus)

Government Spending Multipliers in Good Times and in Bad: Evidence from U.S. Historical Data

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

Internet Appendix for: Cyclical Dispersion in Expected Defaults

Introduction to the UK Economy

Global Slack as a Determinant of US Inflation *

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

The Dynamic Effects of Forward Guidance Shocks

Part VII. How Successful Has Inflation Targeting Been?

5. STRUCTURAL VAR: APPLICATIONS

Core Inflation and the Business Cycle

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy

Corresponding author: Gregory C Chow,

Do Fed Forecast Errors Matter?

The Impact of Monetary Policy on Inequality in the UK. An Empirical Analysis

Ten Years after the Financial Crisis: What Have We Learned from. the Renaissance in Fiscal Research?

THE ROLE OF EXCHANGE RATES IN MONETARY POLICY RULE: THE CASE OF INFLATION TARGETING COUNTRIES

EC910 Econometrics B. Exchange Rate Pass-Through and Inflation Dynamics in. the United Kingdom: VAR analysis of Exchange Rate.

Administered Prices and Inflation Targeting in Thailand Kanin Peerawattanachart

Juan Carlos Castro-Fernández * Working Paper This version: 19 November 2017

How do Macroeconomic Shocks affect Expectations? Lessons from Survey Data

What determines government spending multipliers?

WO R K I N G PA PE R S E R I E S

Transmission in India:

Measuring How Fiscal Shocks Affect Durable Spending in Recessions and Expansions

Innocent Bystanders? Monetary Policy and Inequality in the U.S.

Money and Banking. Lecture V: Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanisms. Guoxiong ZHANG, Ph.D. November 7th, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Antai

Pavel Ryska. PCPE, April 18, 2015

Does money matter in the euro area?: Evidence from a new Divisia index 1. Introduction

There is considerable interest in determining whether monetary policy

Economics Letters 108 (2010) Contents lists available at ScienceDirect. Economics Letters. journal homepage:

Discussion of The Term Structure of Growth-at-Risk

Transcription:

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY For Online Publication The macroeconomic effects of monetary policy: A new measure for the United Kingdom: Online Appendix James Cloyne and Patrick Hürtgen

2 AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR TABLE A DATA SOURCES Variable Source Description Series GDP ONS GDP (CVM, seasonally adjusted ) ABMI Household consumption ONS Household consumption expenditures (CVM, SA) ABJR Investment ONS Gross Fixed Capital Formation NPQT (CVM, SA) Hours worked ONS Weekly hours worked per capita YBUS/MGRZ Industrial production ONS Covers manufacturing, mining and CKYW quarrying and energy supply (S.A.) Inflation (RPIX) ONS Annual change in Retail Price Index excluding mortgage interest payments, extended back using Retail Prices Index CDKQ (CZBH for 975, RPI) RPIX ONS Retail Prices Index excluding mortgage interest payments, extended back using Retail Prices Index Retail Prices Index Inflation (RPI) ONS Annual change in Retail Price Index CZBH Consumer Prices Index ONS CPI long run series Interest rates Bank of England Bank Rate / Minimum Lending Rate / Repo Rate / Official Bank Rate Unemployment rate ONS Unemployment rate (Age 6 and over). Claimant count and ILO measure (S.A.) Money supply M Bank of England Monthly average amount outstanding of total sterling notes and coin in circulation, excluding backing assets for commercial banknote issue in Scotland and Northern Ireland (S.A.) Money supply M4 Bank of England Monetary financial institutions sterling M4 liabilities to private sector), seasonally adjusted Exchange rates Sterling/USD Bank of England Spot exchange rate, USD into Sterling (monthly average) Exchange rates Sterling/DM Bundesbank Spot exchange rate DM into Sterling (monthly average) Sterling effective exchange rate Eurostat Nominal Effective Exchange Rate - 24 trading partners Commodity price index IMF IMF Commodity price index converted to Sterling (S.A.) FTSE Bloomberg FTSE All Share Index United States data: Industrial production, CPI, effective exchange rate, commodity price index Data from Coibion (22), Coibion et al. (22) and FRED Romer and Romer (24) shocks Data from Coibion (22), Extended using original approach. Coibion et al. (22), Romer and Romer (24) and authors own reading of FOMC Greenbook data CHMK, CDKQ and CDKO Official Bank Rate history MGSX LPMAVAB Break-adjusted LPMAUZJ and LPMAUYN XUDLUSS, XUMAUSS BBK.WT55 Barakchian and Crowe (23) data set Authors websites and https://fred.stlouisfed.org/ Authors websites and https://www.philadelphiafed.org.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY 3 TABLE A2 VARIABLES OF REAL-TIME FORECASTS DATA SET Variable Source Description Period Real GDP growth Bank of England Annualised quarterly real GDP growth rates (S.A.) 997-7 RPIX Bank of England Annual RPIX inflation rate 993-3 CPI Bank of England Annual CPI inflation rate 23-7 Real GDP growth NIESR & NIER Annualised quarterly real GDP growth rates (S.A.) 975-7 RPI/RPIX NIESR & NIER Annual RPI/RPIX inflation rate 987-92 / 993-23 CPI NIESR & NIER Annual CPI inflation rate 23-7 Consumer price defl. NIESR & NIER Annual change in consumer price deflator 975-87 Notes: Bank of England data are based on Inflation Report forecasts which are available from the Bank of England website. We use data from the Bank of England directly, which includes back-cast data, to compute growth rates. NIESR electronic forecast data are available post99 from NiGEM (the National Institute s Global Econometric Model). For older data we only use the NIER (National Institute Economic Review). Where back-data are not included with the forecast, we make use of the Bank of England s real-time dataset (also available online) to construct the previous quarters associated with the forecast.

4 AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR A. Comparison with Bank Rate FIGURE A. CUMULATED SHOCK SERIES AND ACTUAL BANK RATE 2 5 Actual Bank Rate narrative: exogenous Bank Rate path recursive VAR: exogenous Bank Rate path 5-5 975 98 985 99 995 2 25 Notes: Exogenous Bank Rate path is the cumulated shock series adjusted for the average Bank Rate.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY 5 TABLE A3 THE EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY INNOVATIONS IN PREVIOUS STUDIES Authors Country Method Peak Effects (in %) Output Prices/Inflation Romer and Romer (24) US narrative.9 to -4.3 (IP) -3.6 to -5.9 (CPI/PPI) Coibion (22) US narrative.6 to -4.3 (IP).8 to -4.2 (CPI inflation) Dedola and Lippi (25) UK VAR -.5 (IP).2 (CPI) Mountford (25) UK sign-restriction -.6 (GDP) -.5 (GDP defl.) Ellis et al. (24) UK FAVAR./-2. (IP, 75-9/92-5) -.3/-2 on CPI (75-9/92-5) -.5/-.5 (GDP,75-9/92-5) Bernanke and Mihov (998) US VAR -.6 to (GDP) -.7 to.6 (GDP defl.) Christiano et al. (999) US VAR -.7 (GDP) -.6 (GDP defl.) Bernanke et al. (25) US FAVAR -.6 (IP) -.7 (CPI) Uhlig (25) US sign-restriction -.3 (GDP). (GDP defl.) Barakchian and Crowe (23) US Fed Futures data -.9 (IP) -. (CPI) Gertler and Karadi (25) US VAR-HFI 45. to -2. (IP) -.75 to.3 (CPI) Notes: The results from previous studies listed in the table are from impulse responses displayed in these papers. We computed implied peak effects to a one percentage point increase in the interest rate. In brackets we report the specific output and price measure, where IP denotes industrial production. Coibion (22) presents a range of exercises and magnitudes. These are taken from Coibion (22) Figure 2, reporting the baseline specification results using a VAR and ADL model. The US narrative results are for the Romer and Romer (24) sample 969996. ADDITIONAL ROBUSTNESS EXERCISES B. Expanding the first stage: money supply and exchange rates Although inflation targeting has been the stable policy regime since 993, there have been a number of other policy environments since 975. Monetary targeting was emphasised in the early 98s and stricter control of the money supply had begun in the late 97s. In addition, during the latter half of the 98s the UK began shadowing the Deutsche Mark as a forerunner to the UK joining the European Exchange Rate Mechanism, which it then was forced to leave in 992. Batini and Nelson (29) argue that short-term interest rates have consistently been used as the policy instrument even throughout these earlier periods of UK monetary policy. Nonetheless, to examine whether these extra objectives affected the setting of the policy target rate, we expand the variables in the first stage regression to include lagged money supply (M) as well as the US Dollar- Sterling exchange rate and the Deutsche Mark/Euro-Sterling exchange rate. 46 Panel A of Figure B shows that our baseline results are largely unaffected by the inclusions of these extra variables. 45 The authors combine high frequency identification (HFI) with a VAR approach. We report the range of results for the full sample 979-22 and the sample up to 28 excluding the crisis. 46 Clarida, Galí and Gertler (998) estimate policy rules for several countries, among these for the UK economy, and include the Sterling-Deutsche Mark exchange rate as a relevant regressor.

6 AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR FIGURE B. ROBUSTNESS TO INCLUDING EXTRA FIRST STAGE REGRESSORS AND TO TIMING ASSUMPTIONS IN STAGE.5 Panel A Inflation.5 Panel B Inflation Panel C Inflation Case 2.5 -.5 -.5 Case Case 2 -.5.5 6 2 8 24 3 36.5 6 2 8 24 3 36.5 4 8 2 Quarters Industrial production Industrial production.6 GDP.5.5.4.2 -.5 -.5 -.2 -.4 -.6 -.8.5 6 2 8 24 3 36.5 6 2 8 24 3 36 4 8 2 Quarters Notes: Impulse responses to a one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock (dashed line) of alternative specification compared to baseline specification (circled line) with corresponding 68 and 95 per cent confidence intervals. The baseline specification uses industrial production, RPIX2m inflation, commodity prices, and our shock measure. Panel A: first stage regression includes lagged money supply M, US Dollar-Sterling exchange rate, DM (Euro)-Sterling exchange rate (dashed line). Panel B: Alternative first stage regressions: Case (blue dashed): includes using additional observations when Bank Rate was unchanged but new forecasts have been released. Case 2 (red dashed): Using only observations when new forecasts have been released. Panel C: quarterly VAR with Case 2 (dashed line). B2. Alternative timing assumptions in stage In the main text we explained that, in deciding how to assign forecasts to policy changes, we keep all Bank Rate changes and assign the latest available forecast. In this section we consider two alternatives. First we consider all forecast release dates as points where policy could have been changed. This is important pre992 where there was no set meeting date and we do not observe whether an unchanged policy rate was a deliberate decision or not. This adds 29 new observations to our first stage regression. Case in Figure B Panel B shows that the effects hardly differ from our baseline results. We prefer our baseline shock series, however, since we cannot be sure that the additional observations are genuine monetary policy decisions. The second alternative we consider is to exclude policy changes where we do not have a new forecast. One concern is that there are quarters with multiple Bank Rate changes but which will be associated with the same forecast observation. To investigate this, we now only consider Bank Rate observations where new forecasts have been released. Since the forecast data is released at a quarterly frequency this also reduces the number of monetary policy shocks to a quarterly frequency. Case 2

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY 7 in Figure B Panel B illustrates that the results are also very similar to our baseline findings. The advantage of our baseline approach is that we obtain a high-frequency monetary surprise series that identifies a monetary policy shock for all available Bank Rate decisions. Case 2 naturally produce a quarterly shock series. It is therefore also natural to ask how robust our results are for quarterly GDP in the quarterly VAR specification considered in the robustness section of the paper. Reassuringly, the effects on GDP are very close to our baseline results, both in terms of peak effects and persistence, as shown in the last column of Figure B. We therefore conclude that our baseline results (based on a monthly shock series) are robust to these alternative timing assumptions.

8 AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR B3. Results from a larger VAR FIGURE B2. LARGE-SCALE VAR Inflation.5 -.5.5 6 2 8 24 3 36 Industrial production.5 -.5.5.4 6 2 8 24 3 36 Unemployment rate.2 -.2 -.4 2 6 2 8 24 3 36 Bank Rate -2 6 2 8 24 3 36 Notes: Impulse responses to a one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock with corresponding 68 and 95 per cent confidence intervals. The specification uses industrial production, RPIX2m inflation, unemployment rate, commodity prices, our new cumulated shock measure and Bank Rate.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY 9 B4. VAR specification sensitivity FIGURE B3. ROBUSTNESS TO VAR WITH AND WITHOUT TREND.6.4 Inflation Baseline VAR with trend Baseline VAR no trend.2 -.2 -.4 -.6 -.8 6 2 8 24 3 36 Industrial production.5.2.4 -.5.5 6 2 8 24 3 36 Notes: Impulse responses to a one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock (dashed line) of alternative specification compared to baseline specification (circled line) with corresponding 68 and 95 per cent confidence intervals. The baseline specification uses industrial production, RPIX2m inflation, commodity prices, and our shock measure. The blue dotted line depicts the VAR without trend. P=24. Sample: 975-27. Confidence bands indicate 68 and 95 per cent intervals.

AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR B5. Alternative price measures and lag length sensitivity FIGURE B4. ROBUSTNESS TO ALTERNATIVE PRICE MEASURES AND LAG LENGTH.5 Inflation.5 Inflation -.5 -.5.5 6 2 8 24 3 36.5 6 2 8 24 3 36 Industrial production Industrial production.5.5 -.5 -.5.5 6 2 8 24 3 36.5 6 2 8 24 3 36 RPIX2m RPI2m CPI2m P=24 P=2 P=36 Notes: Impulse responses to a one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock (dashed line) of alternative specifications compared to baseline specification (circled line) with corresponding 68 and 95 per cent confidence intervals. The baseline specification uses industrial production, RPIX2m inflation, commodity prices, and our shock measure. The first column compares the dynamics for various inflation measures (RPI and CPI) to the baseline VAR with RPIX. The second column provides the baseline VAR results compared to using 2 and 36 lags.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY FIGURE B5. VAR COMPARISON: PRICE LEVEL AND INFLATION.6.4 Inflation Inflation Implied inflation I Implied inflation II.2 -.2 -.4 -.6 -.8.2.4 6 2 8 24 3 36 Notes: Impulse responses to a one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock. VAR with industrial production, inflation rate (RPIX2m) and RPIX price level (dashed line), and -month RPIX inflation (blue), commodity prices, and narrative monetary policy measure. The impulse responses are transformed to the implied 2 month inflation rate. in P=24. Sample: 975-27. Confidence bands indicate 68 and 95 per cent intervals.

2 AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR B6. The price puzzle FIGURE B6. BASELINE VAR USING BANK RATE TO MEASURE MONETARY POLICY SHOCKS Inflation.8.6.4.2 -.2 -.4 -.6 -.8 6 2 8 24 3 36 Notes: Impulse responses to a one percentage point increase in Bank Rate with corresponding 68 and 95 per cent confidence intervals. The specification uses industrial production, RPIX2m inflation, commodity prices, and Bank Rate. P=24, sample=975-27.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY 3 A COMPARISON BETWEEN THE VAR AND SINGLE EQUATION APPROACHES In this section we present two additional sets of results. First, we use our new shock series in a simple auto-regressive distributed lag framework exactly following Romer and Romer (24). This can be seen as the counterpart of the single equation results in the main text estimated using local projections. Second, we show that the results from the single equation set-up can be reconciled with our VAR results. More precisely, we exactly follow Romer and Romer (24) and regress each macroeconomic variable (x t ) on its lags and lags of the policy innovations m t directly estimated from the first stage: (C) P Q x t = c + β i x t i + γ j m t j + ɛ t. i= j= As mentioned above, the data are monthly. To ensure comparability with Romer and Romer (24) we set P = 24 and Q = 36 for industrial production and P = 24 and Q = 48 for prices. Our VAR results have the same qualitative signs as the results from the single equation regressions, but have a quantitatively smaller magnitude and a different persistence. As mentioned in the paper, these differences can largely be explained by the different policy paths generated by the two methods. Being specified in differences, simulations of equation (C) assumes that the shock to the level of the policy rate is permanent. However, as noted in Coibion (22), the effect this produces on the implied policy path can significantly affect the magnitudes reported from impulse response functions. To harmonise the exercises, we simulate a shock sequence in the ADL model that produces the same path for the positive part of the policy rate in the VAR. Figure C reproduces the VAR results from the previous section for the response of industrial production and inflation and, for reference, also shows the actual response of the policy rate. 47 The results of the new single equation simulation are shown in the blue dotted lines. When we use this alternative shock profile in the single equation method, it is quite striking how close these two sets of results become, suggesting the two methods (VAR and ADL) differ largely due to the size and dynamics of the policy response, as has been emphasized by Coibion (22) for the US. In summary, while the single equation estimates may initially seem large, this section shows they can be reconciled with the VAR estimates. Since VARs are dominant in the empirical literature, we prefer to cite our VAR-based results as the baseline estimates. 47 In the VAR case, the policy rate is added to the VAR as the final variable, implying that our shocks affect the policy rate immediately.

4 AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR FIGURE C. RECONCILIATION OF VAR AND SINGLE EQUATION APPROACH.5 Bank Rate.5 -.5.5 6 2 8 24 3 36.5 Inflation -.5.5 6 2 8 24 3 36.5 Industrial production.5 -.5.5 6 2 8 24 3 36 Notes: Impulse responses to one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock. Confidence bands indicate 68 and 95 per cent intervals.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY 5 ADDITIONAL SINGLE EQUATION RESULTS D. UK vs. US results using the single equation approach For completeness we now compare the UK and US results using the baseline single equation approach employed in Romer and Romer (24). As argued before, in comparing the UK and US results we use the same sample period, i.e. from 975 to 27, for both countries. 48 Comparing the single equation results, Figure D shows that our findings are very similar to those for the US following the RR method. The 68 and 95 per cent confidence bands are bootstrapped using 2, repetitions. FIGURE D. SINGLE EQUATION REGRESSIONS FOR THE UK AND THE US Price level: CPI Industrial production -2-2 -3-3 -4-4 -5 U.K. Romer-Romer: U.S. 6 2 8 24 3 36 42 48-5 U.K. Romer-Romer: U.S. 6 2 8 24 3 36 42 48 Notes: Impulse responses to a permanent one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock. Confidence bands indicate 68 and 95 per cent intervals. It is noteworthy that the industrial production response for the US is largely within the 95 per cent confidence bands of the UK industrial production response. In both countries the peak decline is reached after around two years, although in the US industrial production returns faster towards zero. Note that, to be directly comparable with the RR results for the US, in this section we compare the response of the price level. 49 The dynamics and the magnitude of the response of consumer prices in the US almost exactly match the estimated price dynamics for the UK. It is also remarkable that the price response is relatively small for both countries in the first two years, but falls significantly thereafter. D2. Results for other variables One of the advantages of the single equation approach is that it is straightforward to consider the effects on a range of further variables. 5 In this section we show the response of other macroeconomic 48 Extending the US sample to 969-27 does not alter the results. 49 In the comparison to the US we use the consumer price index for both countries as the UK producers price index is not available for our full sample. 5 We thank one of the anonymous referees for pointing this out.

6 AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR variables of interest using the single equation approach estimated using local projections, as discussed in the robustness section of the main paper. The effects on unemployment rate, investment, hours, consumption, the nominal effective exchange rate, and money supply to a contractionary monetary policy shock are reported in Figure D2. For brevity (and since our main focus is on output and inflation) we do not discuss each of the responses in detail, but all results accord well with the expected signs based on other empirical studies and theoretical macroeconomic models.

VOL. VOL NO. ISSUE THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF MONETARY POLICY 7 FIGURE D2. QUARTERLY SINGLE EQUATION RESULTS.5 Unemployment 4 Investment 2 Per cent.5 Per cent -2 -.5-4 4 8 2 6 Quarters -6 4 8 2 6 Quarters.6 Hours Consumption.4.5.2 Per cent -.2 Per cent -.5 -.4.5 -.6-2 -.8 4 8 2 6 Quarters -2.5 4 8 2 6 Quarters 4 NEER M 3 2 Per cent Per cent -2-2 -3-3 -4 4 8 2 6 Quarters -4 4 8 2 6 Quarters Notes: Impulse responses to a one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock with corresponding 68 and 95 per cent confidence intervals. We use P=4, Q=8 and estimate impulse responses using local projections. Full sample 975-27.

8 AMERICAN ECONOMIC JOURNAL MONTH YEAR FURTHER RESULTS FOR THE POST992 SAMPLE E. Predictability tests for the post992 subsample TABLE E PREDICTABILITY OF MONETARY POLICY INNOVATIONS: 993 TO 27 I = 3 lags I = 6 lags Variable F-statistics P-values F-statistics P-values Change in industrial production.67.57.64.7 Monthly inflation.85.4.32.25 Unemployment rate...87.52 Money growth M4.62.6.4.87 Commodity price inflation.43.73.2.42 Change in FTSE.88.45.94.47 Notes: The table reports F-statistics and P-values for the null hypothesis that all coefficients β i are equal to zero. The standard errors are corrected for the possible presence of serial correlation and heteroskedasticity using a Newey-West variance covariance matrix. E2. The inflation response in a conventional VAR after 992 FIGURE E. SMALL-SCALE VAR WITH BANK RATE.6 Inflation.4.2 -.2 -.4 -.6 6 2 8 24 3 36 Notes: Impulse responses to a one percentage point contractionary monetary policy shock with corresponding 68 and 95 per cent confidence intervals. VAR with industrial production, RPIX2m inflation, commodity prices and Bank Rate. P=2.