Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital

Similar documents
Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

Capital-goods imports, investment-specific technological change and U.S. growth

FISCAL POLICY, ELASTIC LABOR SUPPLY, AND ENDOGENOUS GROWTH * Stephen J. Turnovsky. University of Washington, Seattle WA 98195

Comprehensive Exam. August 19, 2013

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

Reexamining the Interaction between Innovation and Capital Accumulation

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

Quantitative Significance of Collateral Constraints as an Amplification Mechanism

Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States

Non-Renewable Resources and the Sustainability of the Economic Growth under Bilateral Trade

Optimal Capital Income Taxes in an Infinite-lived Representative-agent Model with Progressive Tax Schedules

In the Name of God. Macroeconomics. Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank

Oil Monopoly and the Climate

Retirement, Saving, Benefit Claiming and Solvency Under A Partial System of Voluntary Personal Accounts

Inflation & Welfare 1

National Debt and Economic Growth with Externalities and Congestions

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Optimal Redistribution in an Open Economy

Public Investment, Debt, and Welfare: A Quantitative Analysis

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Growth Effects of the Allocation of Government Expenditure in an Endogenous Growth Model with Physical and Human Capital

Incentives and economic growth

The Impact of Tax Policies on Economic Growth: Evidence from Asian Economies

Midterm Exam. Monday, March hour, 30 minutes. Name:

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

Habit Formation in State-Dependent Pricing Models: Implications for the Dynamics of Output and Prices

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Random innovation subsidies. Amy Jocelyn Glass Department of Economics, Texas A&M University. January 16, Abstract

Taxing or subsidizing factors rents in a simple endogenous growth model with public capital

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

Public Investment in Basic Education and Economic Growth

Optimal Capital Income Taxation

WORKING PAPER NO THE ELASTICITY OF THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE WITH RESPECT TO BENEFITS. Kai Christoffel European Central Bank Frankfurt

Saving Europe? Some Unpleasant Supply-Side Arithmetic of Fiscal Austerity

On Quality Bias and Inflation Targets: Supplementary Material

General Equilibrium Analysis Part II A Basic CGE Model for Lao PDR

1 No capital mobility

Return to Capital in a Real Business Cycle Model

Fiscal Reform and Government Debt in Japan: A Neoclassical Perspective

Taxes and Labor Supply: Portugal, Europe, and the United States (Conference Version)

Redistribution and Education Subsidies are Siamese Twins Bovenberg, Lans; Jacobs, B.

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Partial Equilibrium Model: An Example. ARTNet Capacity Building Workshop for Trade Research Phnom Penh, Cambodia 2-6 June 2008

Tax Competition and Coordination in the Context of FDI

Problem Set 5. Graduate Macro II, Spring 2014 The University of Notre Dame Professor Sims

Achieving Actuarial Balance in Social Security: Measuring the Welfare Effects on Individuals

External Financing and the Role of Financial Frictions over the Business Cycle: Measurement and Theory. November 7, 2014

Savings, Investment and the Real Interest Rate in an Endogenous Growth Model

Tax Reform with Useful Public Expenditures

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

The Role of Trade in Structural Transformation

Home Production and Social Security Reform

SDP Macroeconomics Final exam, 2014 Professor Ricardo Reis

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Convergence, capital accumulation and the nominal exchange rate

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

Working Paper No. 241

1. Money in the utility function (continued)

Aging and Pension Reform in a Two-Region World: The Role of Human Capital

A unified framework for optimal taxation with undiversifiable risk

Mandatory Social Security Regime, C Retirement Behavior of Quasi-Hyperb

Welfare Analysis of Progressive Expenditure Taxation in Japan

Chapter 7 Externalities, Human Capital and Endogenous Growth

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Household Saving, Financial Constraints, and the Current Account Balance in China

A note on testing for tax-smoothing in general equilibrium

Wealth E ects and Countercyclical Net Exports

Advanced Modern Macroeconomics

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Labor-dependent Capital Income Taxation That Encourages Work and Saving

TAXATION AND LONG-RUN GROWTH

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Non-Time-Separable Utility: Habit Formation

Analytical Option Pricing under an Asymmetrically Displaced Double Gamma Jump-Diffusion Model

The Effect of Interventions to Reduce Fertility on Economic Growth. Quamrul Ashraf Ashley Lester David N. Weil. Brown University.

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Growth and Welfare Analysis of Tax Progressivity in a Heterogeneous-Agent Model

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Optimal time consistent taxation with international mobility of capital

CAN CAPITAL INCOME TAX IMPROVE WELFARE IN AN INCOMPLETE MARKET ECONOMY WITH A LABOR-LEISURE DECISION?

Heterogeneous Firm, Financial Market Integration and International Risk Sharing

International Debt Deleveraging

Growth and Inclusion: Theoretical and Applied Perspectives

Government spending shocks, sovereign risk and the exchange rate regime

Inflation, Nominal Debt, Housing, and Welfare

TFP Persistence and Monetary Policy. NBS, April 27, / 44

Endogenous Money, Inflation and Welfare

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Networks in Production: Asset Pricing Implications

THE TRANSITIONAL DYNAMICS OF FISCAL POLICY: LONG-RUN CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND GROWTH

Transcription:

University of A Coruna From the SelectedWorks of Manuel A. Gómez April, 2000 Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital Manuel A. Gómez Available at: https://works.bepress.com/manuel_gomez/2/

Welfare-maximizing tax structure in a model with human capital Manuel A. Gómez* Departamento de Economía Aplicada II, Universidad de A Coruña, Spain Abstract This paper studies the welfare-maximizing tax structure in a two-sector model of endogenous growth with human capital. ere, tax structure refers to the mix of taxes which satisfy an exogenously given government budget constraint. eywords: Taxation; Endogenous growth; Welfare cost JEL classification: 21; O41 *Manuel Alberto Gómez Suárez, Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales, Campus da Zapateira, 15071 A Coruña, Spain. Tel.: +34-981-167000; fax: +34-981- 167070; e-mail: mago@udc.es.

1. Introduction Quantitative assessments of tax reforms in endogenous growth models with human capital accumulation are relatively recent (e.g., Lucas, 1990; Pecorino, 1994; Stokey and Rebelo, 1995). While these studies concentrated basically on the relationship between tax rates and long-run growth, the focus in this paper is on the determination of the welfare-maximizing tax structure. ere, tax structure refers to the mix of taxes on physical capital income, labor income and consumption which satisfy an exogenously given government budget constraint. The government budget is assumed to balance every period and government debt is zero. This point is what singles out this work from other optimal taxation studies (e.g., Jones, Manuelli and Rossi, 1997; Judd, 1999). Section 2 describes the model. Section 3 discusses the calibration of the model to U.S. data. Section 4 presents the simulation results, and Section 5, the conclusions. 2. The model We consider a two-sector economy inhabited by an infinitely-lived representative household, whose preferences are described by the intertemporal utility function U ( C L η 1 σ ρt t t = e 0 ) 1 σ 1 dt. (1) C t and L t denote consumption and leisure at time t, ρ is the rate of time preference, σ is the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution and η reflects preferences for leisure. The household owns the stocks of physical capital and human capital and rents them out each period to the firms. The budget constraint faced by the household is given by ( 1 ) R + p (1 ) R (1 L) + S= (1+ C ) C+ p (1 s ) I + I. (2) 1

I is the new physical capital, I, the new human capital, j R i, the rate of return of factor i (i=,) in sector j (j=,), p, the relative price of human capital, s, a proportional j subsidy to investment in education, i, the tax rate on factor i (i=,) in sector j (j=,), C, the tax rate on consumption and S denotes government transfers. As in Pecorino (1994), reflects the extent to which the human capital input into production of human capital is considered to be foregone earnings. The laws of motion of the stocks of physical and human capital are given by & = I δ, (3) & = I δ, (4) where δ and δ are the rates of depreciation of physical and human capital. Physical output Y and human capital Y are produced with Cobb-Douglas technologies: = α 1 α Y A( v) ( u ), (5) = β 1 β Y B(( 1 v) ) ( z ), (6) where v (u) is the share of () devoted to the production of goods, and z is the share of devoted to education. We follow Pecorino (1994) in assuming that the (explicit) expenditure on education, E, is E = E + E = R x+ ( 1 ε p R z. (7) ) ε is the percentage of the human input into production of human capital which represents foregone earnings. E and E are the physical and human capital (explicit) costs in the expenditure on education. Total output, Y, is given by Y = Y + E. (8) 2

Earnings foregone to accumulate human capital are not counted in GDP and this is reflected in (8). The government is assumed to run a balanced budget and government debt is zero: + R v R x+ p R u+ p R z+ CC= S+ G+ p s I. (9) G is government spending on goods and services. Government spending as a percentage of output, g, is assumed to be constant in the long-run. 3. Calibration of the model Predetermined parameters and data to be matched by the model are summarized in Table 1. Parametrization of preferences and technology follows Lucas (1990) and Pecorino (1994), except for σ which is set equal to 1.5. A high value of σ would produce counterfactual cross-country interest differentials and, in Lucas s view, even σ=2 seems high (Lucas, 1990: p. 306). Tax rate estimates are taken from Mendoza, Milesi-Ferretti and Asea (1997: Table 2). Tax rates on income earned vary only by factor, = and = ( 1 ε). ereafter, and will denote the tax rates on incomes of physical capital and labor ( = ), respectively. Long-run GDP ratios are based on data of the 1998 Economic Report of the President (table B-2) over the period 1965-1991. Neglecting imports and exports, GDP was divided in the fractions 0.6448 to private consumption, 0.1371 to gross investment on physical capital and 0.2181 to government spending. Data of expenditure on education are based on the Digest of Education Statistics 1996 (Table 30) and 1997 (Table 409) (U.S. Department of Education). The share of expenditure on education averaged 6.689% of GDP over the 1965-1991 period, and public expenditure on education, G E, averaged 75.34% of total expenditure on education 3

over the 1988-1993 period. Since private expenditure on education constitutes investment on human capital in this model, it must be subtracted from private consumption in the national income accounts to obtain a 62.83% consumption s share of GDP. In this paper, public expenditure on education is treated either as an inframarginal in-kind transfer (as in Pecorino, 1994) or as a subsidy (as in Trostel, 1993). In any case, it must be subtracted from government spending to obtain the figure in Table 1. Using ing and Levine s (1994) estimates, the stock of physical capital to GDP ratio is found to average 1.6894 over the period 1965-88. The long-run growth rate, γ, is set equal to 1.5% (as in Lucas, 1990 and Pecorino, 1994), and the share of physical capital costs in the expenditure on education, E /E, is set equal to the average in the range 17-22% found in Bowen (1987). Parameter values found in the calibration are reported in Table 2. 4. Simulation results In this section, the welfare-maximizing tax structure is determined. ere, tax structure refers to the mix of taxes which satisfy the government budget constraint. The values of g and s are exogenously given by their pre-tax-reform values displayed in Tables 1 and 2, respectively. The post-tax-reform share of lump-sum transfers on GDP at the new balanced growth path is also set equal to its pre-tax-reform value reported in Table 2. Following Lucas (1990), the net welfare effect of a reform is measured as the constant percentage increase, κ in C t that leaves the household indifferent between the lifetime utility obtained by remaining in the pre-tax-reform equilibrium, and the lifetime utility obtained by undertaking the tax reform. Optimal tax structures are reported in Table 3. 4

If public expenditure on education is treated as a subsidy, a movement to the welfare-maximizing structure of income taxation involves lowering by 24.08 and increasing by 12.52 percentage points. As a result, a 0.2% growth fall and a 3.93% welfare gain are achieved. If C is optimally set too, the optimal is 30.83% and falls to 16.35%. Therefore, welfare rises by 4.06% and growth falls by 0.07 percentage points. If public expenditure on education is treated as an inframarginal in-kind transfer, the optimal becomes almost zero, and the lost revenue is replaced with higher consumption taxation. Now the welfare-maximizing structure of income taxes relies more heavily on. 5. Conclusions Welfare-maximizing tax structure is considered when only income taxes are optimally set and when, in addition to these, consumption tax is optimally set, too. This issue is important because the composition of the income tax as well as the use of income versus consumption taxes lie in the center of discussion over tax policy. Simulation results strongly suggest that higher reliance upon consumption taxation would increase welfare. The optimal is significantly nonzero (over 16%) and considerably lower than its estimate. These results are robust to considering public expenditure on education as an inframarginal in-kind transfer or as a subsidy. owever, optimal depends markedly on the treatment of public expenditure on education. When only income taxes are optimally set, optimal is higher than, and ranges between 33-38%, which indicates that shifting the burden of taxation from physical capital to labor would increase welfare. 5

Acknowledgments Financial support by the Xunta de Galicia under project PGIDT99PXI10005A is gratefully acknowledged. References Bowen,.R., 1987. The costs of higher education. Jossey-Bass Publishers, San Francisco. Jones, L.E., Manuelli, R.E. and Rossi, P.E., 1997. On the optimal taxation of capital income. Journal of Economic Theory 73, 93-117. Judd,.L., 1999. Optimal taxation and spending in general competitive growth models. Journal of Public Economics 71, 1-26. ing, R.G. and Levine, R., 1994. Capital fundamentalism, economic development and economic growth. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 40, 259-292. Lucas, R.E. Jr., 1990. Supply-side economics: an analytical review. Oxford Economic Papers 42, 293-316. Mendoza, E.G., Milesi-Ferretti, G.M. and Asea, P., 1997. On the ineffectiveness of tax policy in altering long-run growth: arberger's superneutrality conjecture. Journal of Public Economics 66, 99-126. Pecorino, P., 1994. The growth rate effects of tax reform. Oxford Economic Papers 46, 492-501. Stokey, N.L. and Rebelo, S., 1995. Growth effects of flat-rate taxes. Journal of Political Economy 103, 419-50. Trostel, P.A., 1993. The effect of taxation on human capital. Journal of Political Economy 101, 327-350. 6

Table 1. Parametrization of the model Technology and preference parameters A σ η ρ δ 1 1.5 0.5 0.034 0.02 Data to match γ C/Y /Y E/Y E /E G E /E 0.015 0.6283 1.6894 0.06689 0.195 0.7534 Fiscal policy parameters C g 0.42719 0.2536 ( 1 ε) 0.05648 0.1677 7

Table 2. Results of the calibration B α β δ ε s s Expenditure on education as a subsidy 0.1075 0.3737 0.02976 0.066 0.8733 0.1338 0.1149 Expenditure on education as an inframarginal in-kind transfer 0.1291 0.3737 0.0377 0.066 0.8379 0.1841 0 8

Table 3. Welfare-maximizing tax structure (in percent) C γ κ Expenditure on education as a subsidy Optimal and 18.64 37.88 --- 1.295 3.93 Optimal, and C 16.35 30.83 16.09 1.429 4.06 Expenditure on education as an inframarginal in-kind transfer Optimal and 28.27 33.76 --- 1.343 1.76 Optimal, and C 18.83 0.466 51.73 2.025 4.107 9