Working Paper No. 807

Similar documents
Dynamic Macroeconomics

1 The Solow Growth Model

Trade and Development

Theory of the rate of return

Eckhard Hein DISTRIBUTION AND GROWTH AFTER KEYNES A Post Keynesian Guide (Edward Elgar 2014) Chapter 1 Introduction

ECON 302 Fall 2009 Assignment #2 1

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

1 Chapter 1: Economic growth

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

National Debt and Economic Growth with Externalities and Congestions

No. 15/ Marzo Why labor income shares seem to be constant? Hernando Zuleta (Documento de Trabajo, citar con autorización del autor) ECONOMÍA

Theories of Growth and Development Fall 2001, Midterm I

Innovations in Macroeconomics

Marx s reproduction schemes and the Keynesian multiplier: a reply to Sardoni

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Working Paper No. 795

LEC 2: Exogenous (Neoclassical) growth model

Chapter 12 Keynesian Models and the Phillips Curve

Midterm Examination Number 1 February 19, 1996

Part 1: Short answer, 60 points possible Part 2: Analytical problems, 40 points possible

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES IMPERFECT COMPETITION AND THE KEYNESIAN CROSS. N. Gregory Mankiw. Working Paper No. 2386

MACRO-ECONOMIC THEORY. A Mathematical Treatment

2014/2015, week 6 The Ramsey model. Romer, Chapter 2.1 to 2.6

If a model were to predict that prices and money are inversely related, that prediction would be evidence against that model.

Eckhard Hein DISTRIBUTION AND GROWTH AFTER KEYNES A Post Keynesian Guide (Edward Elgar 2014)

4.3.1 The critique of the IS-LM representation of Keynes

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

Technical change is labor-augmenting (also known as Harrod neutral). The production function exhibits constant returns to scale:

From Solow to Romer: Teaching Endogenous Technological Change in Undergraduate Economics

TWO PRINCIPLES OF DEBT AND NATIONAL INCOME DYNAMICS IN A PURE CREDIT ECONOMY. Jan Toporowski

LECTURE 3 NEO-CLASSICAL AND NEW GROWTH THEORY

Income Distribution and Economic Growth in a. Multi-Sectoral Kaleckian Model

LECTURE 3 NEO-CLASSICAL AND NEW GROWTH THEORY

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

Solow instead assumed a standard neo-classical production function with diminishing marginal product for both labor and capital.

CARLETON ECONOMIC PAPERS

Test Questions. Part I Midterm Questions 1. Give three examples of a stock variable and three examples of a flow variable.

Macroeconomics Lecture 2: The Solow Growth Model with Technical Progress

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

Economic Importance of Keynesian and Neoclassical Economic Theories to Development

Comments on Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy, by Cúrdia and Woodford

Marx s Reproduction Schema and the Multisectoral Foundations of the Domar Growth Model

WORKING PAPER SERIES. CEEAplA WP No. 05/2006. Teaching Keynes s Principle of Effective Demand and Chapter 19. Corrado Andini.

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

A Note on the Solow Growth Model with a CES Production Function and Declining Population

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Introduction to economic growth (2)

Departamento de Economía Serie documentos de trabajo 2015

The World Bank Revised Minimum Standard Model: Concepts and limitations

Module 4 Macroeconomics. (Lectures 27, 28, 29, 30, 31 & 32)

Lecture notes 10. Monetary policy: nominal anchor for the system

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

Macroeconomic Theory I: Growth Theory

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Chapter 2 Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

Government expenditure and Economic Growth in MENA Region

Discrete models in microeconomics and difference equations

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls UNIVERSITY OF LONDON

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

Government spending in a model where debt effects output gap

Uberrimae Fidei and Adverse Selection: the equitable legal judgment of Insurance Contracts

PART ONE INTRODUCTION

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Notes on classical growth theory (optional read)

Exercise 1 Output Determination, Aggregate Demand and Fiscal Policy

Toshihiro Ihori. Principles of Public. Finance. Springer

CHAPTER 11. SAVING, CAPITAL ACCUMULATION, AND OUTPUT

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 5

What is Macroeconomics?

FINANCIAL SECTOR SHOCKS IN A CREDIT VIEW MODEL WORKING PAPER SERIES

Traditional growth models Pasquale Tridico

Some Simple Analytics of the Taxation of Banks as Corporations

IN THIS LECTURE, YOU WILL LEARN:

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

CENTRE FOR ECONOMIC RESEARCH WORKING PAPER SERIES

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

0. Finish the Auberbach/Obsfeld model (last lecture s slides, 13 March, pp. 13 )

Dr Piketty on wealth and capital: Accumulation vs. finance

Alternative theories of the business cycle

The Bowley Ratio. Abstract

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

A Re-examination of Economic Growth, Tax Policy, and Distributive Politics

Nº 4 On the Long-Run Inflation-Unemployment Trade-Off Francisco L. Lopes

Aggregate Supply. Reading. On real wages, also see Basu and Taylor (1999), Journal of Economic. Mankiw, Macroeconomics: Chapters 9.4 and 13.1 and.

Aggregate Supply. Dudley Cooke. Trinity College Dublin. Dudley Cooke (Trinity College Dublin) Aggregate Supply 1 / 38

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Eckhard Hein DISTRIBUTION AND GROWTH AFTER KEYNES A Post Keynesian Guide (Edward Elgar 2014)

Principles of Macroeconomics

Texas Christian University. Department of Economics. Working Paper Series. Keynes Chapter Twenty-Two: A System Dynamics Model

The Theory of Economic Growth

The Theory of Economic Growth

Savings, Investment and Economic Growth

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

Non-Separable Preferences, Fiscal Policy Puzzles and Inferior Goods*.

Lecture notes 2: Physical Capital, Development and Growth

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

The trade balance and fiscal policy in the OECD

A REINTERPRETATION OF THE KEYNESIAN CONSUMPTION FUNCTION AND MULTIPLIER EFFECT

Incentives and economic growth

The Facts of Economic Growth and the Introdution to the Solow Model

Transcription:

Working Paper No. 807 Income Distribution Macroeconomics by Olivier Giovannoni* Levy Economics Institute of Bard College June 2014 * Assistant Professor of Economics, Bard College; Research Scholar, Levy Economics Institute; Member, University of Texas Inequality Project (UTIP). To correspond with author: 30 Campus Road, Annandale-on- Hudson, NY, 12504. Phone: 845-758-7565. E-mail: ogiovann@bard.edu. I thank Hui Yi Chin for research assistance. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright Levy Economics Institute 2014 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X

Abstract Recent research stresses the macroeconomic dimension of income distribution, but no theory has yet emerged. In this note, we introduce factor shares into popular growth models to gain insights into the macroeconomic effects of income distribution. The cost of modifying existing models is low compared to the benefits. We find, analytically, that (1) the multiplier is equal to the inverse of the labor share and is about 1.4; (2) income distribution matters mostly in the medium run; (3) output is wage led in the short run, i.e., as long as unemployment persists; (4) capacity expansion is profit led in the full-employment long run, but this is temporary and unstable. Keywords: Economic Growth; Income Distribution; Multiplier; Factor Share; Output Capacity; Instability JEL codes: D33, E25 1

1 INTRODUCTION Much of the literature on income distribution and economic growth uses in equality measures and a microeconomic analysis. In a different approach, this note echoes a recent trend relating income distribution to macroeconomic outcomes, as suggested in Galbraith (2012), Krugman (2007), Piketty (2014), Reich (2013) and Stiglitz (2012), among others. Our approach is macroeconomic and we will consider factor shares as a measure of income distribution. 2 Little attention has been paid to factor shares in recent decades. Part of the reason is that factor shares were constant in the postwar era and that this constancy became a stylized fact not worth discussing. The most -used macroeconomic growth models, the Cobb-Douglas production function and Solow growth models, feature constant factor shares. In the case of perfect competition and constant returns, income distribution is irrelevant to the growth process (Bertola et al. 2006). As a result, the questions of production and distribution have largely been divorced, and little progress has been made in income distribution macroeconomics over the past fifty years (Giovannoni 2014a). In this sense the question is new: no standard model has yet appeared. In this note I show that rather powerful insights can be gained from relativel y simple modifications of the traditional growth models to account for income distribution. What follows are extensions of the Keynesian cross, Solow and Harrod- Domar models. 2 In Giovannoni (2014b), we show that the profit share, inequality and top incomes have behaved in the same way over sixty years in the United States, describing what has be en deemed fractal inequality 2

2 DISTRIBUTION, MULTIPLIER AND GROWTH The set-up is the textbook case of a closed economy operating below capacity where we consider disposable income Assume classic linear functions for consumption and investment such as (Samuelson 1939): ( ) ( ) (1) Complications such as borrowing, or the presence of assets or a foreign sector would distract us from the main point and need not be introduced for the model to be insightful. The intuition is to introduce a breakdown of YD on the right-hand side into wages and profits ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) (2) At this point it is customary to move the variables endogenous with respect to to the left-hand side and leave the remaining exogenous variables on the right-hand side, which prompts the question of what the endogenous variables are. This is an important choice which influences the rest of this analysis, although not fundamentally. In what follows we will assume that profits are endogenous, on the grounds that profits can only exist if production has already taken place profits depends on the profit-maximizing level of output. Thus profits are a function of disposable income, and by definition ( ), where the labor share α is allowed to vary. Replacing this value in equation (2) introduces the distribution of income in the discourse. Solving for we get ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) But since this collapses to 3 ( ) ( ) ( ) (3) 3 Empirically on US data, the elasticity of consumption and investment to disposable income are 0.81 and 0.23, respectively. The balance (G T) + (X M) is nearly zero.

2.1 Features Let the multiplier for variable Φ be. Equation (3) leads to identical multipliers Magnitude of. A labor share between 0.65 and 0.80 (see Giovannoni 2014a) puts the multiplier 1/α between 1.2 and 1.5, which is in line with the literature (see Chinn 2013 for a survey). The finding that - and - multipliers are greater than one legitimizes the use of fiscal and monetary policies. It is also reassuring to find that the multiplying effect of 1/α is the same regardless of where the money comes from. A dollar spent is a dollar spent. Finally, note that we are talking about a multiplying effect on disposable in - come. Because of this, the balanced budget multiplier is, and not unity, as commonly assumed. A net injection of zero in the circular flow produces no change. Is the economy wage- or profit-led? In our setting we assumed that profits were endogenous so that the economy is necessarily wage-led. Had we assumed instead in equation (2) that wages, instead of profits, are endogenous, we would have gotten a multiplier equal to, which is considerably more than any estimate in the literature. Our multiplier seems more reasonable. To prove the same point we can consider the elasticities of disposable income to wages and to profits: (4) All this makes the case for a wage-led economy in the short-run which is, again, compatible with the literature (Lavoie and Stockhammer 2012). Recall that the present setup deals with effective production, not production capacity, which is assumed fixed and not achieved capacity will be dealt in the section after the representation below.

2.2 Representation The present exposition lends itself to the traditional 45-degree line diagram. Start with equation (2) whose left side we rename aggregate demand,. Figure 1 Increase in Aggregate Demand and Substantial Fall in the Labor Share Rearranging, we get { (5) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) The slope of aggregate demand, ( ), is positive. Exogenous changes cause the aggregate demand line to shift. A novelty compared to the textbook model appears with the slope of aggregate demand being a function of α, generating the possibility of rotations of the line depending on the distribution of income. At business cycle frequencies, the labor share varies so little 4 basis points at best that the rotation is negligible. However, for a sustained fall in the labor share of 15 points, such as the one that took place over the last thirty years in many developed countries (Giovannoni 2014a), the slope of aggregate demand increases from 0.20 to 0.35, which is more substantial (see effect on Fig. 1).

3 LONG-RUN GROWTH Along the balanced growth path (Solow 1956) I = S or ( ) (6) where s is the exogenous savings rate, represents capital depreciation, technical progress grows at a rate, ( ) features constant returns, and is the capital stock per effective worker. Multiplying through by the profit rate and rearranging, we get the profit share (see e.g., Gollin 2008) ( ) (7) This profit share is constant since s11, s w, 8, r and ga are constant in the long run. Thus, factor shares are exogenous in the long run and there is no feedback from distribution to macroeconomic developments (Bertola, Foellmi and Zweimüller 2006). However, the distribution of income will change if, for instance, technology is biased, if markets are imperfect, if the production function is not Cobb-Douglas, or still if taxes and subsidies exist or change. 3.1 Modification #1: Heterogeneous Savings Rates Along the Balanced Growth Path The profit share can be rewritten using a Kaldor (1956) decomposition of the savings rate. Let and be the savings rates out of wages and out of profits, respectively, so that The savings rate can then be shown to be ( ) (8) Replacing this value in equation (7) and solving for the profit share we get, after rearranging and simplifications, the general expression ( ) (9)

If the saving rates are undifferentiated ( ) equation (9) collapses to the original equation (7). We note in passing a peculiar case 4 when s w = 0. Besides those particular values the steady-state profit share is positive and constant. Thus, income distribution is irrelevant to the growth process along the balanced growth path (Bertola, Foellmi and Zweimüller 2006). But could distribution matter during the transition path? 3.2 Modification #2: Endogenous Savings Rate Along the Transition Path We can endogenize the savings rate in equation (6) by using the same Kaldorian decomposition ( ) ( ) so that ( ) ( ) ( ) (10) Assuming that saving out of profits is greater than saving out of wages, ( ) So a higher profit share leads to a new position where the savings rate and output per worker are permanently higher (see Fig. 2). The profit share, in turn, can change for the reasons mentioned above. However, the permanent rise in the profit share only leads to a temporary increase in the rate of growth. After the transition is completed the economy settles in to a steady state where growth is given by the rate of depreciation and the rate of technological change, not by income distribution. There remains, however, that the transition path is profit-led. 4 The profit share becomes null, despite. In this case capital-owners get what workers save: nothing, which is the reverse of the proposition (attributed to Kalecki) ac cording to which workers spend what they get, capitalists get what they spend. This case is unlikely because, as the labor share grows, is likely to grow as well.

Figure 2 The Transition Path, with Income Distribution Effect 3.3 HARROD-DOMAR Alternatively, one may start from the Harrodian growth framework (Harrod 1939). Along the warranted growth path actual growth equals the warranted growth where is the marginal productivity of capital. Introducing again the Kaldorian savings rate decomposition, we have [ ( ) ] (11) Thus the warranted growth path (production capacity) is profit-led. Note that this doesn t affect the classic instability of the warranted growth path, which still prevails.

4 C O N C L U D I N G R E M A R K S The model extensions presented above are simple and could be used for teaching purposes. The modifications led to the conclusion that income distribution indeed matters, but in specific ways that ought to be reflected in the design of institutions and economic policies. In the short run, counter-cyclical policies ought to target the stability of aggregate wages. In the long run, institutions should facilitate profit accumulation and capacity expansion with the provision that profit-led expansions are only temporary and unstable.

5 R E FE R E N C E S Bertola, G., Foellmi, R. and J. Zweimüller (2006) Income Distribution in Macroeconomic Models, Princeton: Princeton University Press Chinn, M. (2013) Fiscal Multipliers, in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Palgrave Macmillan. Galbraith, J. (2012) Inequality and Instability, Oxford: Oxford Univer sity Press Giovannoni, O. (2014a) What Do we Know About the Labor Share and the Profit Share? Part III: Measures and Structural Factors, The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Working Paper No. 805. (2014b) Fractal Inequality, The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, Working Paper No. forthcoming. Gollin, D. (2008) Labour s Share of Income, New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London: Macmillan Harrod, R. (1939) An Essay in Dynamic Theory, Economic Journal, 49, 193, 14 33 Kaldor, N. (1956) Alternative Theories of Distribution, The Review of Economic Studies, 23, 2, 83-100 Krugman, P. (2007) Conscience of a Liberal, W. W. Norton & Company, New York Lavoie, M. and E. Stockhammer (2012) Wage-led growth: concepts, theories and policies, ILO Working Papers no. 41, Geneva: International Labour Organization. Piketty, T. (2014) Capital in the 21st Century, Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press Reich, R. (2013) Aftershock, Vintage Books Samuelson, P. (1939) Interactions Between the Multiplier Analysis and the Principle of Acceleration, Review of Economic Statistics, 21, 2, 75-78 Solow, R. (1956) A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 1, 65-94 Stiglitz, J. (2012) The Price of Inequality, New York: W. W. Norton & Company