Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity

Similar documents
Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Monetary Economics: Problem Set #6 Solutions

A key characteristic of financial markets is that they are subject to sudden, convulsive changes.

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

M. R. Grasselli. February, McMaster University. ABM and banking networks. Lecture 3: Some motivating economics models. M. R.

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Expectations vs. Fundamentals-based Bank Runs: When should bailouts be permitted?

Monetary and Financial Macroeconomics

MFE Macroeconomics Week 8 Exercises

A Diamond-Dybvig Model in which the Level of Deposits is Endogenous

An agent-based model for bank formation, bank runs and interbank networks

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

DARTMOUTH COLLEGE, DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS ECONOMICS 21. Dartmouth College, Department of Economics: Economics 21, Summer 02. Topic 5: Information

The Diamond-Dybvig Revolution: Extensions Based on the Original DD Environment

Macroeconomia 1 Class 14a revised Diamond Dybvig model of banks

Microeconomics II. CIDE, MsC Economics. List of Problems

In Diamond-Dybvig, we see run equilibria in the optimal simple contract.

PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Economics Department Bendheim Center for Finance. FINANCIAL CRISES ECO 575 (Part II) Spring Semester 2003

A Rational, Decentralized Ponzi Scheme

Low Interest Rate Policy and Financial Stability

Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime Chang and Velasco JET 2000 and NBER 6469

Bailouts, Bank Runs, and Signaling

Chapter 8 Liquidity and Financial Intermediation

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Discussion of Calomiris Kahn. Economics 542 Spring 2012

On Diamond-Dybvig (1983): A model of liquidity provision

International Journal of Economic Theory

HW Consider the following game:

Alternative Central Bank Credit Policies for Liquidity Provision in a Model of Payments

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

1. Introduction of another instrument of savings, namely, capital

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Securitization in a Model of Regional Liquidity Shocks and Priv

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

January 26,

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

A Model with Costly Enforcement

Economics and Finance,

Revision Lecture. MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Global Games and Financial Fragility:

6.254 : Game Theory with Engineering Applications Lecture 3: Strategic Form Games - Solution Concepts

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

Game Theory and Economics Prof. Dr. Debarshi Das Department of Humanities and Social Sciences Indian Institute of Technology, Guwahati.

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Game Theory Fall 2003

Institutional Finance

Lawrence J. Christiano

Ilkka Kiema, Research Coordinator, Labour Institute for Economic Research

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

Economia Finanziaria e Monetaria

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Definition of Incomplete Contracts

CHAPTER 14: REPEATED PRISONER S DILEMMA

Illiquidity and Interest Rate Policy

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Banks and Liquidity Crises in Emerging Market Economies

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

Macroeconomics 4 Notes on Diamond-Dygvig Model and Jacklin

Lecture 26 Exchange Rates The Financial Crisis. Noah Williams

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions

In real economies, people still want to hold fiat money eventhough alternative assets seem to offer greater rates of return. Why?

Liquidity. Why do people choose to hold fiat money despite its lower rate of return?

Repeated Games. September 3, Definitions: Discounting, Individual Rationality. Finitely Repeated Games. Infinitely Repeated Games

Where do securities come from

Expectations versus Fundamentals: Does the Cause of Banking Panics Matter for Prudential Policy?

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Banks and Liquidity Crises in an Emerging Economy

April 29, X ( ) for all. Using to denote a true type and areport,let

Lecture XXX: Bank Runs

How do we cope with uncertainty?

14.02 Quiz 1, Spring 2012

SCREENING BY THE COMPANY YOU KEEP: JOINT LIABILITY LENDING AND THE PEER SELECTION EFFECT

Not 0,4 2,1. i. Show there is a perfect Bayesian equilibrium where player A chooses to play, player A chooses L, and player B chooses L.

PROBLEM SET 6 ANSWERS

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

Managing Confidence in Emerging Market Bank Runs

Iterated Dominance and Nash Equilibrium

Delegated Monitoring, Legal Protection, Runs and Commitment

Global Financial Systems Chapter 8 Bank Runs and Deposit Insurance

1 Dynamic programming

In the Name of God. Sharif University of Technology. Graduate School of Management and Economics

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

Part A: Questions on ECN 200D (Rendahl)

Slides III - Complete Markets

Part A: Answer Question A1 (required) and Question A2 or A3 (choice).

Optimal Financial Crises

Séptimas Jornadas de Economía Monetaria e Internacional La Plata, 9 y 10 de mayo de 2002

On the Optimality of Financial Repression

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

THE PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIVERSITY. Department of Economics. January Written Portion of the Comprehensive Examination for

Behavioral Competitive Equilibrium and Extreme Prices. Faruk Gul Wolfgang Pesendorfer Tomasz Strzalecki

Introduction to Game Theory

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Economics 109 Practice Problems 1, Vincent Crawford, Spring 2002

Strategic Traders and Liquidity Crashes

CMSC 474, Introduction to Game Theory 16. Behavioral vs. Mixed Strategies

Transcription:

Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity Douglas W. Diamond University of Chicago Philip H. Dybvig Washington University in Saint Louis Washington University in Saint Louis August 13, 2015 Diamond, Douglas W., and Philip H. Dybvig, 1983, Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity, Journal of Political Economy 91, 401 19. Free download of a clean reprint at http://minneapolisfed.org/research/qr/qr2412.pdf.

Motivation Originally Model Bank Runs as a Rational Phenomenon of Multiple Equilibrium Additional Understanding New Workhorse Model of Liquidity and Banking Deposits as Optimal Contracts for Sharing Risk under Asymmetric Information Further thoughts Toy model (not a realistic model) Simplicity (crystal or poem) for clarity and allows generalization 2

Results Bank runs can happen rationally even if bank assets are riskless(and obviously they can still happen with bank assets are risky) Banks create liquidity iff runs are possible Improved risk sharing can be interpreted as demand for liquidity Bank runs can be eliminated by deposit insurance or discount window New role for policy in the context of multiple equilibria traditional role: move an equilibrium trading off benefits against distortions role here: eliminate a bad equilibrium but leave the good equilibrium alone 3

Model: bank assets Bank asset payoffs in periods 0, 1, and 2, choice made at 1: -1 0 R 1 0 Asset illiquidity in technology is for convenience; illiquidity due to information assymmetry (lemons problem) is probably more important. If the liquidation payoff is less than 1 the results are only strengthened. 4

Model: depositor preferences Agents maximize E[u(c 1,c 2 ;θ)], where u(c U(c 1,c 2 ;θ) = 1 ) if Type 1 in state θ ρu(c 1 +c 2 ) if Type 2 in state θ u is C 2 on R ++ and C 0 on R + u (0) =,u ( ) = 0 1 ρ > R 1 ( c 1)( cu (c) u (c) > 1) A fraction t is of type 1 (needs liquidity). The paper analyzes t constant and t random, but I will only talk about t constant. An agent s type is that agent s private information revealed at the start of time 1. There is a continuum of agents and we will finesse the measurability issues in the usual natural way. 5

Endowments, Competitive and Perfect Information solutions Endowments: 1 at time 0, 0 each at times 1 and 2 Equilibrium prices without public information: (1,1,R 1 ), and equilibrium consumption c 1 1 = 1, c 1 2 = c 2 1 = 0, and c 2 2 = R. This equilibrium requires no trade if agents invest themselves: type 1 s always interrupt production but Type 2 s never do. Perfect information (types publicly observable at time 1): c 1 2 = c 2 1 = 0 (patient peopleconsumelaterandimpatientpeopleconsumeearlier), u (c 1 1 ) = ρru (c 2 2 ) (marginal rates of substitution in production and consumption are equal), and tc 1 1 +(1 t)c 2 /R = 1 (the resource constraint). Because ρr > 1 and relative risk aversion > 1, it can be shown that c 1 1 > 1 and c 2 2 < R. This optimal allocation is in fact incentive-compatible (since c 1 < c 2 ), so we should be able to find a mechanism to implement it. 6

Competitive Model: Choice Problem Choose nonnegative c 1 1, c 2 1, c 1 2, c 2 2, and I, and choose L 1 and L 2 in [0,1], to maximize tu(c 1 1)+(1 t)ρu(c 2 1+c 2 2) subject to: p 1 c 1 1+p 2 c 1 2 = p 0 (1 I)+p 1 IL 1 +p 2 I(1 L 1 )R and p 1 c 2 1+p 2 c 2 2 = p 0 (1 I)+p 1 IL 2 +p 2 I(1 L 2 )R Market clearing: I = 1, (tl 1 +(1 t)l 2 )I = (tc 1 1+(1 t)c 2 1), and R (1 (tl 1 +(1 t)l 2 ))I = (tc 1 2+(1 t)c 2 2) Equilibrium: p 0 = 1, p 1 = 1, p 2 = R 1 c 1 1 = 1, c 2 2 = R, c 2 1 = c 1 2 = 0 I many solutions, all have total investment I = 1 L 1,L 2 many solutions, all have total liquidation (tl 1 +(1 t)l 2 )I = t same consumption as autarky solution I = 1, L 1 = 1, L 2 = 0 7

Full Information Optimal Solution Assume (correctly) a symmetric solution. Choose nonnegative c 1 1, c 2 1, c 1 2, and c 2 2 to maximize tu(c 1 1)+(1 t)ρu(c 2 1+c 2 2) subject to: (tc 1 1+(1 t)c 2 1)+(tc 1 2+(1 t)c 2 2)/R = 1 Solution: c 2 1 = c 1 2 = 0 first-order condition: u (c 1 1 ) = ρru (c 2 2 ) Since ρr > 1, c 2 2 > c 1 1. Also, RRA > 1 implies c 1 1 > 1 and c 2 2 < R 8

Banking Contracts Per dollar invested, a bank deposit pays r 1 in period 1 and pays off the residual value in the bank (if any) in period 2. Depositors must put all their money in the bank and they cannot trade deposits; this is an important assumption. Depositors in the bank play a simultaneous-move game and decide whether to withdraw based on expectations about how many others will withdraw. Depositors arrive sequentially, each with a uniform distribution over place in line, and the bank liquidates assets as necessary to pay each depositor until assets are exhausted. Once assets are exhausted, the bank fails and all remaining depositors receive nothing (whether or not they tried to withdraw). If bank assets are not exhausted, then all depositors who do not withdraw share equally in the assets in the last period. This mutual bank assumption avoids the necessity of modelling another agent (the bank owner) and avoids any issues of industrial organization that are not part of what we want to study. Note: the bank deposit contract satisfies the sequential service constraint. 9

Bank Depositor Withdrawal Choice Problem For type 1 agents, withdrawing is a dominant strategy because not withdrawing implies consumption is always 0 but withdrawing implies a positive probability of consuming a positive amount. So we can reasonably assume that type 1 agents always withdraw. 1 Note that the fraction of all agents who withdraw is therefore f = t+(1 t)f 2 [t,1] where f 2 [0,1] is the fraction of type 2 agents who withdraw. Then, letting W 2 be the withdrawal choice of a type 2 depositor, the type 2 depositor s objective function for f < 1 is max(1 1/(fr 1 ),0)ρu(0)+min(1/(fr 1 ),1)ρu(W 2 r 1 +(1 W 2 )max( 1 fr 1 1 f R,0)). 1 There are examples when elimiation of dominated strategies can lead to strange results, but not so in this model. 10

Payoffs When f = 1 For f = 1, the factor 1 f in the denominator indicates there is a problem and in fact fixing the problem is a little subtle. If r 1 < 1, the payoff from waiting is infinite because a single infinitessimal agent gets claim to a non-infinitessimal residual in the bank. For r 1 = 1, waiting pays off R because not withdrawing leaves just the agent s own claim in the bank, and the agent will optimally choose not to withdraw. This observation can be used to show that r 1 = 1 leads to the autarky solution. The remaining case, when r 1 > 1, is the normal case and the most interesting. In this case, f = 1 exhausts the bank s assets even if the agent under consideration does not withdraw, and the payoff for f = 1 and r 1 > 1 is therefore max(1 1/(fr 1 ),0)ρu(0)+min(1/(fr 1 ),1)ρu(W 2 r 1 ). 11

Banking Equilibrium For 1 < r 1 c 1 1, there are two types of pure strategy equilibria: run: f = W 1 = W 2 = 1 Impatient depositors always withdraw in period 1 because consumption in period 2 is worthless to them. Patient depositors will withdraw if they think they will get more money now than later. If r 1 > 1, then the bank will exhaust its money at time 1 if everyone withdraws, so everyone withdrawing at time 1 is an equilibrium. This is a bank run, which is purely rational, not a psychological phenomenon. If r 1 = 1, there will be no bank run, but neither will there be any improvement over autarky. no run: W 1 = 1, W 2 = 0, and f = t (First-best if r 1 = c 1 1, which implies 1 fr 1 1 f R = c2 2 ) This is a good equilibrium in which agents only withdraw when impatient, provided r 1 is no larger than the amount that is left over if only impatient agents withdraw. 12

Technical Comments Measure theoretic issue: if we draw uncountably many random variables indexed by the unit interval independently, the realized function is not measurable, so the population average does not exist. This problem was emphasized by Ken Judd. Solutions include using the limit of a sequence economy (messy). The usually practice of taking the population mean equal to the mean of the distribution can be justified by Loeb measure in a hyperfinite economy (Bob Anderson) or the measure-theoretic solution of Ed Green (unpublished article on his web site). We want to assume u(0) finite and ( c [1,R]) cu (c)/u (c) > 1. This is different from the paper, which implicitly assumes u(0) finite and explicitly assumes ( c R) cu (c)/u (c) > 1. Unfortunately the two are inconsistent. )-: 13

Role of Government Policy Usually, government policy(e.g. optimal taxation) is modelled as something(e.g. introducing transfers) that moves the equilibrium allocation in a good direction, usually reflecting a trade-off between a desireable outcome (transfer on income to poor people) at the expense of some distortion (because of taxes, the marginal rates of substitution in production and consumption are no longer equal, so that production is not efficient). Preventing runs in banks is different. We want a governmental policy (or private sector fix) that will eliminate the bad equilibrium without affecting the good equilibrium. 14

Deposit Insurance, Suspension of Convertibility, and the Discount Window To eliminate runs, we need to reassure patient depositors that there will be enough money available to pay them off in the period 2. One way is through deposit insurance, which will pay off the shortfall from the promise in the second period. Given that deposit insurance is in place, the patient agents have no incentive to withdraw in period 1 and there is no run equilibrium. Suspension of convertibility (can be very costly if t random). The idea is to stop paying if too many depositors come to the bank in period 1. Discount window (may not be credible for reasons outside the model) Timing issues, sequential service, timing of credit injection 15

Deposit Insurance Let s focus on r 1 = c 1 1. It would be nice if we could design a policy that eliminates the run equilibrium without disrupting the optimal no-run equilibrium. In fact, a guarantee to people that wait that they will get money back when they wait (perhaps backed by seignorage and/or taxation authority) will do so. Let the guarantee be G (r 1,R]. A guarantee in period 2 does not affect the incentives of a type 1 agent. For a type 2 agent, the payoff if f < 1 becomes max(1 1/(fr 1 ),0)ρu(0)+min(1/(fr 1 ),1)ρu(W 2 r 1 +(1 W 2 )max( 1 fr 1 1 f R,G)), which is decreasing in W 2. Similarly, if f = 1 the payoff is max(1 1/(fr 1 ),0)ρu(0)+min(1/(fr 1 ),1)ρu(W 2 r 1 +(1 W 2 )G), which is also decreasing in W 2. 16

Discount Window, Practical Considerations Use of riskless borrowing at the discount window could also prevent runs, but the policy for using the discount window would have to be designed carefully. If unlimited borrowing is available at a low rate, there is an arbitrage and the discount window could be used to finance investment. However, if the rate is high it will not help the bank any (assuming the bank will repay the borrowing). So, the central bank will probably need to use discretion in deciding there is a run before lending, but in this case maybe it is not credible that the discount window will necessarily be available when the bank needs it. For example, the central bank might decide the bank is unsound and refuse access to the discount window. Note that deposit insurance costs the guarantor nothing in our model, but in practice risky assets would make deposit insurance costly so that the guarantor would have to have some type of incentive scheme and monitoring to guard against risky assets. 17

Suspension of Convertibility, Sequential Service, Random t Suspension of convertibility can stop a run (for example, if only the first t depositors are paid off in period 1 and the rest have to wait), but such a rigid policy can do a lot of damage if t is random. With sequential service and random t, in general it is optimal to offer a contract that pays more to early withdrawers. If it were possible, it would be nice to wait and see how many total withdrawers arrive before deciding how much money to give everyone, but we think that is impractical. 18

Review of ideas Bank runs can be generated by rational agent behavior, even when assets are riskless. Bank deposits can improve on the competitive outcome because they provide liquidity. Providing liquidity improves risk sharing, but makes runs possible. The basic approach can be used to model many issues in banking. The basic approach can also be used to model liquidity in many contexts. more on policy: Diamond, Douglas W., and Philip H. Dybvig, 1986, Banking Theory, Deposit Insurance, and Bank Regulation, Journal of Business 59, 55 68 some recent work: http://phildybvig.com/somepapers.html 19