Microeconomics Pre-sessional September Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

Similar documents
Microeconomic Analysis ECON203

2) Indifference curve (IC) 1. Represents consumer preferences. 2. MRS (marginal rate of substitution) = MUx/MUy = (-)slope of the IC = (-) Δy/Δx

Review of Previous Lectures

Johanna has 10 to spend, the price of an apple is 1 and the price of a banana is 2. What are her options?

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

3. Consumer Behavior

MICROECONOMIC THEORY 1

Chapter 3. Consumer Behavior

Intro to Economic analysis

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 1

We want to solve for the optimal bundle (a combination of goods) that a rational consumer will purchase.

CLAS. Utility Functions Handout

Microeconomics. The Theory of Consumer Choice. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich update C H A P T E R

Utility Maximization and Choice

File: ch03, Chapter 3: Consumer Preferences and The Concept of Utility

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

Summer 2016 Microeconomics 2 ECON1201. Nicole Liu Z

Midterm 1 - Solutions

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

14.54 International Trade Lecture 3: Preferences and Demand

(Note: Please label your diagram clearly.) Answer: Denote by Q p and Q m the quantity of pizzas and movies respectively.

Faculty: Sunil Kumar

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Overview Definitions Mathematical Properties Properties of Economic Functions Exam Tips. Midterm 1 Review. ECON 100A - Fall Vincent Leah-Martin

Lecture 4: Consumer Choice

Introduction to economics for PhD Students of The Institute of Physical Chemistry, PAS Lecture 3 Consumer s choice

Midterm #1 Exam Study Questions AK AK AK Selected problems

Chapter Four. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility Functions. Utility

Consumer Theory. Introduction Budget Set/line Study of Preferences Maximizing Utility

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

Marginal Utility, Utils Total Utility, Utils

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Introduction. The Theory of Consumer Choice. In this chapter, look for the answers to these questions:

Topic 4b Competitive consumer

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis July 7, 2010 Instructor: John Parman. Midterm - Solutions

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. The Budget Set for Consumers. Indifference Curves are Like a Topographical Map for Utility.

Simple Model Economy. Business Economics Theory of Consumer Behavior Thomas & Maurice, Chapter 5. Circular Flow Model. Modeling Household Decisions

Introduction to Microeconomics

Lecture 1: The market and consumer theory. Intermediate microeconomics Jonas Vlachos Stockholms universitet

Module 4. The theory of consumer behaviour. Introduction

Economics 101 Fall 2010 Homework #3 Due 10/26/10

Problem Set 5 Answers. A grocery shop is owned by Mr. Moore and has the following statement of revenues and costs:

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Midterm 1

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. Maximizing Utility. The Budget Set for Consumers. Slope =

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

Midterm 1 (A) U(x 1, x 2 ) = (x 1 ) 4 (x 2 ) 2

Chapter 4 Read this chapter together with unit four in the study guide. Consumer Choice

Consumer Choice and Demand

Principle of Microeconomics

Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

1. Compare the following two pairs of goods: (1) Coke and Pepsi, (2) Plane tickets and hotel bookings

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Fall 2018) Consumer Choice Theory

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

ECN 2001 MICROECONOMICS I SLUTSKY EQUATION Class Discussion 6 (Ch. 7) - Answer Key TRUE-FALSE

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY SPRING 2008 ECONOMICS 300/010 & 011 Midterm I March 14, 2008

Chapter 4. Consumer and Firm Behavior: The Work-Leisure Decision and Profit Maximization

Consumer Choice. Theory of Consumer Behavior. Households and Firms. Consumer Choice & Decisions

A b. Marginal Utility (measured in money terms) is the maximum amount of money that a consumer is willing to pay for one more unit of a good (X).

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

Problem Set 2 Solutions

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Professor Bee Roberts. Economics 302 Practice Exam. Part I: Multiple Choice (14 questions)

Midterm 2 - Solutions

Topic 2 Part II: Extending the Theory of Consumer Behaviour

Lecture 3: Consumer Choice

Preferences - A Reminder

Chapter 4 The Theory of Individual Behavior

PRACTICE QUESTIONS CHAPTER 5

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Midterm 1 - Solutions

Preferences. Rationality in Economics. Indifference Curves

MICROECONOMICS I REVIEW QUESTIONS SOLUTIONS

Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, Suggested Solution

Preferences and Utility

Practice Problems: First-Year M. Phil Microeconomics, Consumer and Producer Theory Vincent P. Crawford, University of Oxford Michaelmas Term 2010

The supply function is Q S (P)=. 10 points

Econ 1101 Summer 2013 Lecture 7. Section 005 6/26/2013

Consumer Budgets, Indifference Curves, and Utility Maximization 1 Instructional Primer 2

Module 2 THEORETICAL TOOLS & APPLICATION. Lectures (3-7) Topics

The Theory of Consumer Behavior ZURONI MD JUSOH DEPT OF RESOURCE MANAGEMENT & CONSUMER STUDIES FACULTY OF HUMAN ECOLOGY UPM

ANSWER KEY 3 UTILITY FUNCTIONS, THE CONSUMER S PROBLEM, DEMAND CURVES. u(c,s) = 3c+2s

Economics. The Theory of Consumer Choice 11/8/2012. Introduction. Principles of. The budget constraint. Answers

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

Chapter 5: Utility Maximization Problems

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Practice Exam 1 with Solutions

Econ 323 Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 2, Question 1

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

CPT Section C General Economics Unit 2 Ms. Anita Sharma

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis November 13, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 2

Possibilities, Preferences, and Choices

PART II PRODUCERS, CONSUMERS, AND COMPETITIVE MARKETS CHAPTER 3 CONSUMER BEHAVIOR

Microeconomics (Week 3) Consumer choice and demand decisions (part 1): Budget lines Indifference curves Consumer choice

Transcription:

Microeconomics Pre-sessional September 2016 Sotiris Georganas Economics Department City University London

Organisation of the Microeconomics Pre-sessional o Introduction 10:00-10:30 o Demand and Supply 10:30-11:10 Break o Consumer Theory 11:25-13:00 Lunch Break o Problems Refreshing by Doing 14:00-14:30 o Theory of the Firm 14:30-15:30 Break n Problems Refreshing by Doing 15:45-16:30 2

Consumer Theory q q q q q q Description of Consumer Preferences Utility Function Indifference Curves Marginal Rate of Substitution Consumer Maximisation Problem Individual and Aggregate Demand Curves 3

Description of Consumer Preferences Consumer Preferences tell us how the consumer would rank (that is, compare the desirability of) any two combinations or allotments of goods, assuming these allotments were available to the consumer at no cost These allotments of goods are referred to as baskets or bundles. These baskets are assumed to be available for consumption at a particular time, place and under particular physical circumstances. 4

Basket of Food and Clothing Units of Clothes A (1,5 ) C (4,5 ) B (8,1 ) Units of Food 5

Properties of Consumer Preferences Completeness Preferences are complete if the consumer can rank any two baskets of goods (A preferred to B; B preferred to A; or indifferent between A and B) Transitivity Preferences are transitive if a consumer who prefers basket A to basket B, and basket B to basket C also prefers basket A to basket C Monotonicity Preferences are monotonic if a basket with more of at least one good and no less of any good is preferred to the original basket (more is better?) 6

The Utility Function The utility function assigns a number to each basket so that more preferred baskets get a higher number than less preferred baskets Utility is an ordinal concept: the precise magnitude of the number that the function assigns has no significance 7

Example Basket of One Good 8

Marginal Utility Marginal utility of a good x is the additional utility that the consumer gets from consuming a little more of x when consumption of all the other goods in the consumer s basket remains constant ΔU/Δx (y held constant) = MU x ΔU/Δy (x held constant) = MU y Marginal utility is measured by the slope of the utility function The principle of diminishing marginal utility states that marginal utility falls as the consumer gets more of a good 9

Example Basket of One Good The more, the better? 10

Example Basket of One Good The more, the better? 11

Example Basket of One Good Diminishing marginal utility? 12

Indifference Curves An Indifference Curve (or Indifference Set) is the set of all baskets for which the consumer is indifferent An Indifference Map illustrates a set of indifference curves for a given consumer 13

Example Single Indifference Curve u ( x, y) = xy 14

u ( x, y) = xy 3D Graph of a Utility Function 15

Properties of Indifference Maps Completeness Each basket lies on one indifference curve 16

Properties of Indifference Maps Completeness Each basket lies on one indifference curve Transitivity Indifference curves do not cross 17

Properties of Indifference Maps 18

Properties of Indifference Maps Completeness Each basket lies on one indifference curve Transitivity Indifference curves do not cross Monotonicity Indifference curves have negative slope and are not thick 19

Properties of Indifference Maps Completeness Each basket lies on one indifference curve Transitivity Indifference curves do not cross Monotonicity Indifference curves have negative slope and are not thick 20

Properties of Indifference Maps Completeness Each basket lies on one indifference curve Transitivity Indifference curves do not cross Monotonicity Indifference curves have negative slope and are not thick 21

Assumption Average Preferred to Extremes y A (.5A,.5B) indifference curves are bowed toward the origin (convex to the origin) IC 2 B IC 1 x 22

What does the slope mean? y A B IC 1 x 23

Marginal Rate of Substitution The marginal rate of substitution is the decrease in good y that the consumer is willing to accept in exchange for a small increase in good x (so that the consumer is just indifferent between consuming the old basket or the new basket) The marginal rate of substitution is the rate of exchange between goods x and y that does not affect the consumer s welfare MRS x,y = -Δy/Δx (for a constant level of utility) MU MRS x,y = MU x y 24

Example Marginal Rate of Substitution y u ( x, y) = xy A A à B 1 B 1/2 0 1 2 U=1 x 25

Example Marginal Rate of Substitution y 1 U( x, y) = xy = 1 0 1 x 26

Indifference curves (usually) exhibit diminishing rate of substitution The more of good x you have, the less of good y you are willing to give up to get a little more of good x The indifference curves get flatter as we move out along the horizontal axis and steeper as we move up along the vertical axis 27

Special Functional Forms 1. Cobb-Douglas: U(x,y) = Ax α y β where: α + β = 1; A, α,β positive constants 2. Perfect substitutes U(x,y) = ax + by 3. Perfect complements U(x,y) = min {ax, by} 4. Quasi-linear: U(x,y) = v(x) + by 28

1. Cobb-Douglas: U = Ax α y β where: α + β = 1; A, α,β positive constants y MRS = Preference direction IC 2 IC 1 x " 29

2. Perfect substitutes U(x,y) = ax + by 3 Pepsi 2 Example: U=x+y MRS = 1 0 1 2 3 COKE 30

3. Perfect complements U(x,y) = min {ax, by} Example: U=10min{x,y} MRS = 1 U=10 0 1 2 x 31

4. Quasi-linear: U(x,y) = v(x) + by Where: b is a positive constant. MU x = v (x), MU y = b, MRSx.y = v (x)/ b 32

Assume only two goods available (x and y) P x Price of x P y Price of y I Income The Budget Constraint Total expenditure on basket (X,Y): P x X + P y Y The basket is affordable if total expenditure does not exceed total income: P x X + P y Y I 33

Example A Budget Constraint Y, Clothes I/P A Y = 5 Two goods available: X and Y D I = $10, P x = $1,P y = $2 1X+2Y=10 Or Y=5-1/2X Slope -P X /P Y = -1/2 C B I/P X = 10 X, Food 34

Definitions The set of baskets that are affordable is the consumer s budget set: P x X + P y Y = I The budget constraint defines the set of baskets that the consumer may purchase given the income available: PxX + PyY I The budget line is the set of baskets that are just affordable: Y = I/P y (P x /P y )X 35

Example A Change in Income Y 6 5 I 1 = $10, I 2 = $12 P X = $1 P Y = $2 Y = 5 - X/2 BL1 Y = 6 - X/2 BL2 BL 2 BL 1 10 12 X 36

Example A Change in Price (good Y) Y If the price of Y rises, the budget line gets flatter and the vertical intercept shifts down If the price of Y falls, the budget line gets steeper and the vertical intercept shifts up 5 3.33 BL 1 I = $10 P X = $1 P Y1 = $2, P Y2 = $3 BL 2 Y = 5-X/2 BL 1 Y = 3.33 - X/3. BL 2 10 X 37

Consumer Choice Assume: Only non-negative quantities "Rational choice: The consumer chooses the basket that maximizes his satisfaction given the constraint that his budget imposes Consumer s Problem: Max U(X,Y) subject to: PxX + PyY I 38

Solving the Consumer Choice Consumer s Problem: Max U(X,Y) subject to: PxX + PyY I The solution could be: i) Interior solution (graphically and/or algebraically) Tangency condition i) Corner solution (graphically) 39

Interior Consumer Optimum Y B D F 0 BL X 40

Interior Consumer Optimum Y B 0 D F Preference direction U=30 U=10 U=5 BL X 41

Example Interior Consumer Optimum Y 20X + 40Y = 800 800= 20X+40Y (constraint) Py/Px = 1/2 (tangency condition) Tangency condition: MRS = - MUx/MUy = -Px/Py 10 U = 200 0 20 X 42

Optimization: Tangency condition MRS = - MU x /MU y Slope of budget line -P x /P y Optimality implies: MRS has to equal slope of budget So optimal choice: MU x /MU y = P x /P y 43

Corner Consumer Optimum A corner solution occurs when the optimal bundle contains none of one of the goods The tangency condition may not hold at a corner solution How do you know whether the optimal bundle is interior or at a corner? Graph the indifference curves Check to see whether tangency condition ever holds at positive quantities of X and Y 44

Example Interior Consumer Optimum U(X,Y) = min(x,y) I = $1000 P x = $50 P Y = $200 Budget line Y = $5 - X/4 45

Example Corner Consumer Optimum Y X + 2Y = 10 0 X 46

Individual Demand Curves The price consumption curve of good x is the set of optimal baskets for every possible price of good x, holding all other prices and income constant 47

Y (units) Example A Price Consumption Curve 10 P Y = $4 I = $40 0 X A =2 P X = 4 20 X (units) 48

Y (units) Example A Price Consumption Curve 10 P Y = $4 I = $40 0 P X = 4 P X = 2 X A =2 X B =10 20 X (units) 49

Y (units) Example A Price Consumption Curve 10 P Y = $4 I = $40 P X = 1 0 P X = 4 P X = 2 X A =2 X B =10 X C =16 20 X (units) 50

Y (units) 10 Example A Price Consumption Curve The price consumption curve for good x can be written as the quantity consumed of good x for any price of x. This is the individual s demand curve for good x P Y = $4 I = $40 Price consumption curve P X = 1 P X = 4 P X = 2 0 X A =2 X B =10 X C =16 20 X (units) 51

Example Individual Demand Curve P X P X = 4 P X = 2 P X = 1 U increasing X A =2 X B =10 X C =16 X 52

Note: The consumer is maximizing utility at every point along the demand curve The marginal rate of substitution falls along the demand curve as the price of x falls (if there was an interior solution). As the price of x falls, utility increases along the demand curve. 53

Y (units) 10 Remember A Price Consumption Curve The price consumption curve for good x can be written as the quantity consumed of good x for any price of x. This is the individual s demand curve for good x P Y = $4 I = $40 Price consumption curve P X = 1 P X = 4 P X = 2 0 X A =2 X B =10 X C =16 20 X (units) 54

Income Consumption Curve The income consumption curve of good x is the set of optimal baskets for every possible level of income. We can graph the points on the income consumption curve as points on a shifting demand curve. 55

Y (units) I=92 I=68 Example: Income Consumption Curve U 3 I=40 U 1 U 2 Income consumption curve 0 P X 10 18 24 X (units) $2 I=40 I=68 I=92 The consumer s demand curve for X shifts out as income rises 10 18 24 X (units) 56

57

Engel Curves The income consumption curve for good x also can be written as the quantity consumed of good x for any income level. This is the individual s Engel Curve for good x. When the income consumption curve is positively sloped, the slope of the Engel curve is positive. 58

I ($) Engel Curve graph X is a normal good 92 68 40 0 10 18 24 X (units) 59

I ($) Engel Curve graph 92 Engel Curve X is a normal good 68 40 0 10 18 24 X (units) 60

Y (units) I=400 I=300 U 3 Engel Curve graph A good can be normal over some ranges and inferior over others I=200 U U 1 2 0 I ($) 400 300 200 13 16 18 Engel Curve X (units) 13 16 18 X (units) 61

Definitions of good If the income consumption curve shows that the consumer purchases more of good x as her income rises, good x is a normal good. Equivalently, if the slope of the Engel curve is positive, the good is a normal good. If the income consumption curve shows that the consumer purchases less of good x as her income rises, good x is an inferior good. Equivalently, if the slope of the Engel curve is negative, the good is an inferior good. 62

How does a change in price affect the individual demand? So far, we have used a graphical approach. Here, we refine our analysis by breaking this effect down into two components: A substitution effect An income effect 63

Substitution effect As the price of x falls, all else constant, good x becomes cheaper relative to good y. This change in relative prices alone causes the consumer to adjust his/ her consumption basket. This effect is called the substitution effect. Always negative if the price rises Always positive if the price falls 64

Income effect Definition: As the price of x falls, all else constant, purchasing power rises. This is called the income effect of a change in price. ð The income effect may be positive (normal good) or negative (inferior good). 65

Substitution + Income effects Usually, a move along a demand curve will be composed of both effects. Graphically, these effects can be distinguished as follows 66

Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects 67

Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects 68

Example: Normal Good: Income and Substitution Effects 69

Example: Inferior Good: Income and Substitution Effects 70

If a good is so inferior that the net effect of a price decrease of good x, all else constant, is a decrease in consumption of good x, good x is a Giffen good. For Giffen goods, demand does not slope down. When might an income effect be large enough to offset the substitution effect? The good would have to represent a very large proportion of the budget. Example: Giffen Good: Income and Substitution Effects 71

Example: Giffen Good: Income and Substitution Effects 72

Aggregate Demand The market, or aggregate, demand function is the horizontal sum of the individual demands. In other words, market demand is obtained by adding the quantities demanded by the individuals (or segments) at each price and plotting this total quantity for all possible prices. 73

Network externalities If one consumer's demand for a good changes with the number of other consumers who buy the good, there are network externalities. If one consumer s demand for a good increases with the number of other consumers who buy the good, the externality is positive. If the amount a consumer demands increases when fewer other consumers have the good, the externality is negative. 74

Example: The Bandwagon Effect Bandwagon Effect (increased quantity demanded when more consumers purchase) 75

The Snob Effect Snob Effect (decreased quantity demanded when more consumers purchase) 76