Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

Similar documents
A 2 period dynamic general equilibrium model

1. Introduction of another instrument of savings, namely, capital

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Dynamic Macroeconomics: Problem Set 2

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO Joseph L. Rotman School of Management SOLUTIONS

Set 3. Intertemporal approach to the balance of payments

Solving The Perfect Foresight CRRA Consumption Model

Consumption and Savings (Continued)

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Lecture 10: Two-Period Model

Solutions to Problem Set 1

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

A Simple Model of Bank Employee Compensation

Homework 1 Due February 10, 2009 Chapters 1-4, and 18-24

Macroeconomics and finance

Intro to Economic analysis

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

(a) Ben s affordable bundle if there is no insurance market is his endowment: (c F, c NF ) = (50,000, 500,000).

ECON 581. Introduction to Arrow-Debreu Pricing and Complete Markets. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

1 Two Period Production Economy

FISCAL POLICY AND THE PRICE LEVEL CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS. C 1t + S t + B t P t = 1 (1) C 2,t+1 = R tb t P t+1 S t 0, B t 0. (3)

Homework # 8 - [Due on Wednesday November 1st, 2017]

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Problem Set. Solutions to the problems appear at the end of this document.

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Section 9, Chapter 2 Moral Hazard and Insurance

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

1 The Solow Growth Model

Golden rule. The golden rule allocation is the stationary, feasible allocation that maximizes the utility of the future generations.

EC 324: Macroeconomics (Advanced)

ECON385: A note on the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). In this note, we will try to understand the permanent income hypothesis (PIH).

ECON Micro Foundations

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Consumption and Saving

Financial Intermediation and the Supply of Liquidity

Instantaneous rate of change (IRC) at the point x Slope of tangent

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

1 Asset Pricing: Bonds vs Stocks

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

Chapter 19: Intertemporal Choice and Capital Decisions

Chapter 12 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Chapter 6: Risky Securities and Utility Theory

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Homework 2 ECN205 Spring 2011 Wake Forest University Instructor: McFall

THEORETICAL TOOLS OF PUBLIC FINANCE

Professor Scholz Posted March 29, 2006 Economics 441, Brief Answers for Problem Set #3 Due in class, April 5, 2006

Analytical Problem Set

Please do not leave the exam room within the final 15 minutes of the exam, except in an emergency.

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

There are 7 questions on this exam. These 7 questions are independent of each other.

Consumption-Savings Decisions and Credit Markets

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Financial Management I

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

1 Dynamic programming

We are now introducing a capital, an alternative asset besides fiat money, which enables individual to acquire consumption when old.

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Kyunghun Kim ECN101(SS1, 2014): Homework4 Answer Key Due in class on 7/28

ECON 314: MACROECONOMICS II CONSUMPTION

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

Micro Theory I Assignment #5 - Answer key

Revision Lecture Microeconomics of Banking MSc Finance: Theory of Finance I MSc Economics: Financial Economics I

Problem set 1 - Solutions

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 2

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Practice Questions for Mid-Term Examination - I. In answering questions just consider symmetric and stationary allocations!

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

1 Consumption and saving under uncertainty

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Professor Scholz Posted November 27, 2006 Economics 441, Problem Set #4 Due in class, Monday, December 11, 2006

Preferences. Rationality in Economics. Indifference Curves

ECON 200 EXERCISES. (b) Appeal to any propositions you wish to confirm that the production set is convex.

Problem set 2. Filip Rozsypal November 23, 2011

ECONOMICS 723. Models with Overlapping Generations

Corporate Finance - Yossi Spiegel

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

Homework #2 Graphical LP s.

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

TAKE-HOME EXAM POINTS)

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Factor Saving Innovation. Michele Boldrin and David K. Levine

Final Exam Solutions

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Homework # 2 EconS501 [Due on Sepetember 7th, 2018] Instructor: Ana Espinola-Arredondo

Transcription:

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle Consumption with a Perfect Capital Market Consider a simple two-period world in which a single consumer must decide between consumption c 0 today (in period 0) and consumption c tomorrow (in period ). The consumer is endowed with money m 0 today and m tomorrow. Consistent with his endowment, the consumer has the opportunity to borrow or lend b 0 today at interest rate r. Borrowing corresponds to a positive b 0, whereas lending corresponds to a negative b 0.. Budget constraint The equations governing the consumer s feasible actions today and tomorrow are, as follows. Consumption in period 0 equals the original endowment adjusted for the borrowing or lending: c 0 = m 0 + b 0. () We assume the consumer prefers more consumption to less, and so we write this constraint as an equality. Since consumption cannot be negative, the consumer cannot lend more than m 0, i.e., b 0 m 0. Consumption in period equals the original endowment adjusted for the repayment or receipt of the principal and interest associated with the borrowing in period 0, i.e., c = m ( + r)b 0. (2) (Once again, since the consumer is assumed to prefer more consumption to less, we write this constraint as an equality.) Since consumption cannot be negative, there is a limit as to how much the consumer can borrow in period 0, namely, b 0 m /( + r). After substituting c 0 m 0 for b 0 in (2), the consumer s budget constraint is c 0 + c + r = m 0 + m + r := W 0. (3) The symbol W 0 represents the consumer s present value of wealth. Example. Suppose m 0 = 00, m = 990, and r = 0%. The present value of wealth is W 0 = 00 + 990/. = 000. The consumption plan (c 0, c ) = (500, 550) satisfies the budget constraint (3). To achieve this consumption plan, the consumer borrows 400 in period 0 and pays back 440 in period. The consumption plan (c 0, c ) = (800, 220) also satisfies the budget constraint (3). To achieve this consumption plan, the consumer borrows 700 in period 0 and pays back 770 in period.

.2 Optimal consumption plan Which consumption plan will the consumer choose? To determine the optimal consumption plan, we assume existence of a utility function U(c 0, c ) such that the consumer prefers (c 0, c ) to (c 2 0, c2 ) if and only if U(c 0, c ) > U(c 2 0, c 2 ). (4) If the utility values are equal, then the consumer is said to be indifferent to the two consumption plans. Under reasonable assumptions on consumer preferences, existence of a utility function that reflects the consumer preferences is guaranteed to exist. For the remainder of this handout, we shall assume that U(c 0, c ) = c 0 + β c. (5) Example 2. We continue with our example. We shall set β = 0.6. The utility of the consumption plan (c 0, c ) = (500, 550) is 36.43, the utility of the consumption plan (c 0, c ) = (800, 220) is 37.8, and the utility of the original endowment (c 0, c ) = (00, 990) is 28.88. Of these three choices, the consumer prefers (800, 220). The ability to borrow definitely helps our consumer. Formally, the consumer s optimization problem is Define MAX {U(c 0, c ) : c 0 + c + r = W 0}. (6) c (c 0 ) := ( + r)(w 0 c 0 ), (7) ψ(c 0 ) := U(c 0, c (c 0 )) = c 0 + β c (c 0 ). (8) The consumer s optimization problem can be equivalently expressed as MAX {ψ(c 0 ) : 0 c 0 W 0 }. (9) Note how the parameter β serves as a discount factor on future consumption. Smaller values of β imply a larger discount factor on future consumption, which implies that our consumer prefers more consumption today. Consider, for example, the two extreme values for β, namely, 0 and +. How do we obtain the optimal first period consumption c 0 and hence the optimal second period consumption c (c 0 )? The form of the utility function implies that consumption in both periods must be positive. (This is because the derivative of x at zero is infinite.) Consequently, the optimal choice for c 0 necessarily lies strictly between 0 and W 0. Accordingly, to find the optimal choice of c 0, we set the derivative of ψ( ) to zero. Using the chain-rule, optimality conditions imply that 0 = ψ (c 0) = U + U dc = c 0 c dc 0 2 c 0 β( + r). (0) 2 c (c 0 ) 2

It follows directly from (0) that the optimal consumption plan necessarily satisfies the condition c c = β( + r), () 0 or, equivalently, c = β 2 ( + r) 2 c 0. (2) Substituting (2) into the budget constraint (3) and solving for c 0 and c, the optimal consumption plan is [ c ] 0 = + β 2 W 0 := ρ 0 W 0 (3) ( + r) [ β c 2 ( + r) 2 ] = + β 2 W 0 := ρ W 0. (4) ( + r) The constants ρ 0 and ρ are independent of present wealth W 0 ; that is, they are known parameters strictly determined by the two discount factors β and r. We shall use this important fact later. Note further that the optimal utility is of the form U (W 0 ) := [ ρ 0 + β ρ ] W 0. (5) Example 3. In our example, c 0 = 0.76W 0, c = 0.32W 0, and U (W 0 ) =.82 W 0. Here Thus, c 0 = 76, c = 32, and U (000) = 37.36. Due to the availability of a capital market at which to borrow or loan, the consumer has increased his utility by almost 30% above the level corresponding to the initial endowment U(00, 990). To obtain the optimal consumption plan, the consumer must borrow b 0 = 76 00 = 66 today, pay back 678 tomorrow, thereby leaving him with 990 678 = 32 to consume in the final period. 2 Consumption and Investment with a Perfect Capital Market We now consider a world in which the consumer has the opportunity to invest I 0 today in production from which he will receive f(i 0 ) tomorrow. The function f(i 0 ) encapsulates the return on the investment opportunities in production available to the consumer. For example, the consumer may wish to obtain an education while he is young, expecting a return on this investment in his working years. It is generally assumed that (i) f(0) = 0, (ii) f( ) is strictly increasing (more investment leads to more return), and (iii) f( ) exhibits diminishing returns in that the marginal return on an incremental rise in investment declines as the total investment increases. When f( ) is differentiable, these assumptions imply the first derivative is positive and the second derivative is negative. (Such a function is called concave.) To ensure at least some investment will be made (to make our subsequent calculations easier), we also assume that the derivative f (0) is infinite. The equations governing the consumer s feasible actions today and tomorrow are now: c 0 + I 0 = m 0 + b 0 (6) 3

c = m + f(i 0 ) ( + r)b 0. (7) Rearranging terms as we did before, the new budget constraint is c 0 + c [ + r = W f(i0 ) ] 0 + + r I 0 := W 0 (I 0 ). (8) The new optimization problem facing the consumer is MAX {ψ(c 0 ) : 0 c 0 W 0 (I 0 ), I 0 0}. (9) An examination of (8) and (9) reveals a fundamental property: All consumers, regardless of their utility function, should first determine the optimal investment plan to increase their wealth! That is, they should select the value of I 0 to maximize W 0 (I 0 ). This is achieved by equating the marginal return of investment f (I 0 ) to + r. When the function f(i 0 ) represents the investment opportunities for a firm in which consumers hold stock, then each consumer that holds stock should insist that the firm optimize its investment opportunity, regardless of each consumer s different desires for consumption today versus tomorrow. Because there exists a capital market for each consumer to borrow or lend, each consumer can redistribute the increases in wealth as they desire. This principle (in various forms) is known as the Fisher Separation Theorem of Finance. Example 4. Suppose f(i 0 ) = 33 I 0. Now f (I 0 ) = 33/[2 I 0 ], and so the optimal choice for investment is I0 = 225. The additional wealth created through investment equals 495/. 225 = 225 so that W 0 (225) = 225. From (3) and (4), the optimal consumption plan is c 0 = 877 and c = 382 with U (225) = 4.34. The utility has increased by about 0.7%, which also corresponds to 00( 225/000 ). To obtain the optimal consumption plan, the consumer must borrow b 0 = 877 + 225 00 = 002 today, pay back 03 tomorrow, thereby leaving him with 990 + 495 02 = 382 to consume in the final period. 3 Consumption and Investment Without a Capital Market We now consider the situation in which the consumer has investment opportunities as described in the previous section, but no longer has the opportunity to borrow or loan, i.e., b 0 = 0. We shall see that without access to a capital market our consumer is far worse off. The equations governing the consumer s feasible actions today and tomorrow are now c 0 + I 0 = m 0 (20) c = m + f(i 0 ). (2) 4

The new budget constraint can be represented as The optimality conditions (0) imply that c (c 0 ) = m + f(m 0 c 0 ). (22) c c 0 = βf (I 0 ), (23) or, equivalently, that the optimal choice for I 0 must satisfy the identity m + f(i 0 ) m 0 I 0 = βf (I 0 ). (24) After substituting the specific choice for f( ) and performing simple algebra, the optimal choice for I 0 must satisfy the identify 990 + 33 I 0 = 980 I 0 98.0. (25) Since the left-hand side of (25) is an increasing function of I 0 that is finite when I 0 = 0 and the right-hand side of (25) is a decreasing function of I 0 that is infinite when I 0 = 0, a unique solution exists, which can be obtained by bisection search. (Alternatively, identity (25) can be transformed into a cubic equation, which has a closed-form solution.) The optimal value I0 is about 8.25 with a corresponding consumption plan of c 0 = 9.75 and c8 = 085 with U = 29.34. The utility has dropped considerably to almost the level corresponding to the original endowment. 4 Homework Problems. Jones is endowed with money m 0 = 55, 000 today and m = 88, 000 tomorrow. He desires to consume c 0 = 80, 000 today and c = 66, 000 tomorrow. (a) If there is no opportunity to borrow or lend can Jones achieve his consumption objective? Explain. (b) Suppose there is a perfect capital market in which Jones may borrow or lend as much as he desires at the market interest rate of 0%. Can Jones now achieve his consumption objective? Explain. (c) Suppose that in addition to a perfect capital market Jones has an opportunity to invest I 0 = 00, 000 today and receive f(i 0 ) tomorrow. Determine the minimum value for f(i 0 ) for which Jones will be able to exactly achieve his consumption objective. (d) Explain exactly what Jones must do using the capital market and investment opportunity available to him so that he may exactly achieve his consumption objective. 5

2. Jones is endowed with money m 0 = 40, 000 today and m = 99, 000 tomorrow. He desires to consume c 0 = 00, 000 today and c = 55, 000 tomorrow. (a) If there is no opportunity to borrow or lend can Jones achieve his consumption objective? Explain. (b) Suppose there is a perfect capital market in which Jones may borrow or lend as much as he desires at the market interest rate of 0%. Can Jones now achieve his consumption objective? Explain. (c) Suppose that in addition to a perfect capital market Jones has an opportunity to invest I 0 = 50, 000 today and receive f(i 0 ) tomorrow. Determine the minimum value for f(i 0 ) for which Jones will be able to exactly achieve his consumption objective. (d) Explain exactly what Jones must do using the capital market and investment opportunity available to him so that he may exactly achieve his consumption objective. 3. Smith s utility function is U(c 0, c ) = ln c 0 + 0.4 ln c. Smith is endowed with money m 0 = 90, 000 today and m = 500, 000 tomorrow. There is a perfect capital market for borrowing and lending at the market rate of interest of 25% per period. (a) Determine the optimal consumption plan for Smith. Explain exactly what Smith must do each period to achieve his optimal consumption plan. (Recall that d dx ln x = /x.) (b) Smith has an opportunity to invest I 0 = 80, 000 today and receive f(i 0 ) = 35, 000 tomorrow. Should he take advantage of this opportunity? If not, explain why not. If so, explain exactly what he should do each period to achieve his new optimal consumption plan. (c) If Smith no longer has access to the capital market (he cannot borrow or lend), then should he take advantage of the investment opportunity presented in (b)? Explain your reasoning. 5 Homework Solutions Problem a. No. Desired consumption c 0 exceeds his endowment m 0. b. No. The P V of his wealth 55+88/. = 35 is less than the P V of his desired consumption 80 + 66/. = 40. c. Jones needs to add 5 to the P V of his wealth. Consequently, f(i 0). 00 = 5, which means that the smallest value for f(i 0 ) is 5.5. d. In the first period, Jones consumes 80, invests 00 and borrows 25. In the second period, his endowment of 88 plus his investment payout of 5.5 generates a supply of 203.5 of which 37.5 is needed to pay back the loan, thereby leaving 66 for consumption, as desired. 6

Problem 2 a. No. Desired consumption c 0 exceeds his endowment m 0. b. No. The P V of his wealth 40+99/. = 30 is less than the P V of his desired consumption 00 + 55/. = 50. c. Jones needs to add 20 to the P V of his wealth. Consequently, f(i 0). means that the smallest value for f(i 0 ) is 77. 50 = 20, which d. In the first period, Jones consumes 00, invests 50 and borrows 0. In the second period, his endowment of 99 plus his investment payout of 77 generates a supply of 76 of which 2 is needed to pay back the loan, thereby leaving 55 for consumption, as desired. Problem 3 a. The first-order optimality conditions imply that + 0.4 (.25) = 0, (26) c 0 c which implies that c = 0.5c 0. Since c 0 +0.8c = W 0 = 490, we conclude that c 0 = W 0 /.4; thus, Smith should consume 350 now and 75 next period. To achieve this plan, Smith needs to borrow 260 today, and pay back 325 next period from the 500 supply, which leaves 75 to consume, as desired. b. Since the NP V created by the investment opportunity is 35/.25 80 = 28 > 0, Smith should invest in the project. His new P V of wealth will be 58. He should consume 58/.4 = 370 now and 85 next period. To achieve this plan, Smith needs to borrow 360, and pay back 450 next period from the 500 + 35 total supply, which leaves 75 to consume, as desired. c. Since Smith cannot use a capital market he is faced with 2 choices: either invest in the project, which will give him a utility of ln(0) + 0.4 ln(635) = 4.884, or simply consume his initial endowment, which will give him a utility of ln(90) + 0.4 ln(500) = 6.986. Smith should not invest. 7