Trade policy, fiscal constraint and their impact on education in the long run

Similar documents
Chapter 4 THE SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX AND OTHER DATA SOURCES

Assessing Development Strategies to Achieve the MDGs in the Arab Region

TMD DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 100 A STANDARD COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL FOR SOUTH AFRICA

Data requirements II: Building a country database for MAMS

Effect of tariff increase on residential sector preliminary results. Dr Johannes C Jordaan

Chapter 6 SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS

Policy Options Beyond 2015 Achieving the MDGs in Bangladesh. Background Paper for European Development Report 2015

Inter temporal macroeconomic trade offs and payoffs of human development strategies: An economy wide modelling analysis

Energy, welfare and inequality: a micromacro reconciliation approach for Indonesia

Melbourne Institute Working Paper Series Working Paper No. 2/09

Growth and employment impacts of public economic infrastructure investment in South Africa: A dynamic CGE analysis. Working Paper

Analyzing Fiscal Space Using MAMS: An Application to Burkina Faso

Documentation of the SAM (Social Accounting Matrix) for Peru

The Controversy of Exchange Rate Devaluation in Sudan

A comparison of economic impact analyses which one works best? Lukas van Wyk, Melville Saayman, Riaan Rossouw & Andrea Saayman

Diamonds aren t Forever: A Dynamic CGE Analysis of the Mineral Sector in Botswana Preliminary DRAFT

Partnership for Economic Policy. Martín Cicowiez (CEDLAS-UNLP) Bernard Decaluwé (Université Laval) Mustapha Nabli

National Minimum Wage in South Africa: Quantification of Impact

Social Accounting Matrix and its Application. Kijong Kim Levy Economics Institute GEM-IWG summer workshop July

General Equilibrium Analysis Part II A Basic CGE Model for Lao PDR

Proposal Title. Impact of Public Infrastructure Investment in South Africa: A Dynamic. Micro-simulation CGE Analysis

MANAGING TRADE POLICY REFORM AND THE REFORM OF

GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS OF FLORIDA AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS TO CUBA

A N ENERGY ECONOMY I NTERAC TION MODEL FOR EGYPT

Impacts of Infrastructure Investment in South Africa: A Dynamic CGE Analysis. Vandudzai Mbanda. MPIA1 - Growth-Public Spending

Endogenous Labour Supply in CGE-Household Micro-Simulation-Top-Down/Bottom Up Model

DSGD DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 11 PROSPECTS FOR GROWTH AND POVERTY REDUCTION IN ZAMBIA,

Session 5 Evidence-based trade policy formulation: impact assessment of trade liberalization and FTA

TMD DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 101 FCND DISCUSSION PAPER NO. 139 CAN SOUTH AFRICA AFFORD TO BECOME AFRICA S FIRST WELFARE STATE?

Appendix A Specification of the Global Recursive Dynamic Computable General Equilibrium Model

Green tax reform in Belgium: Combining regional general equilibrium and microsimulation

Main Features. Aid, Public Investment, and pro-poor Growth Policies. Session 4 An Operational Macroeconomic Framework for Ethiopia

PUBLIC SPENDING, GROWTH, AND POVERTY ALLEVIATION IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA: A DYNAMIC GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non-commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

Towards Sustainable Development OCCASIONAL PAPER. 39. May By Edward Batte Sennoga and John Mary Matovu

Gender in a Macroeconomic Framework: A CGE Model Analysis

A Computable General Equilibrium Model of Southern Region in Taiwan: The Impact of the Tainan Science-Based Industrial Park

Report ISBN: (PDF)

Demographic Transition, Education, and Inequality in India

Assessment of Egypt's Population and Labour. Supply Policies

working paper A static CGE model of the Mongolian economy

What Explains the U-Shape Form of Women s Labor Force Participation Rate?

CGE Simulation of the ASEAN Economic Community and RCEP under Long-term Productivity Scenarios 1

THE IMPACT OF EAST AFRICA COMMUNITY CUSTOMS UNION ON UGANDA ECONOMY: A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM (CGE) ANALYSIS. Charles Ayai Okello 1

Construction of Financial Social Accounting Matrix for Tunisia

Economic Growth and Income Distribution: Linking Macroeconomic Models with Household Surveys at the Global Level

Linking Microsimulation and CGE models

Intertemporal and Inter-Industry Effects of Population Ageing: A General Equilibrium Assessment for Canada

Essential Policy Intelligence

1 See for example, Kemal (1994), Amjad and Kemal (1997), Anwar (1998), Siddiqui and

Effects of the Global Financial and Economic Crisis on the Bolivian Economy: A CGE Approach

A Static CGE Model of the Mongolian Economy

Global Value Chains and the Cost of Protection: Insights from the New OECD Trade Model

REMOVING TRADE BARRIERS IN BRAZIL

For students electing Macro (8702/Prof. Smith) & Macro (8701/Prof. Roe) option

own working paper The Impact of Trade Reforms on Employment and Welfare in ECOWAS Countries: The case of Senegal

2005 Social Accounting Matrix for Guinea

CHAPTER 23 OUTPUT AND PRICES IN THE SHORT RUN

Preliminary draft, please do not quote

A 2009 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for South Africa

Evidence Based Trade policy Making: Using statistical tools for policy making

Financing strategies to achieve the MDGs in Latin America and the Caribbean

Bernd Meyer and Gerd Ahlert / GWS 2016

Session Two: SPECIFICATION

Are we there yet? Adjustment paths in response to Tariff shocks: a CGE Analysis.

Groupe de Recherche en Économie et Développement International. Cahier de recherche / Working Paper 07-24

The Economic Impact of Belarus Accession to the WTO: A Quantitative Assessment

Australian. Manufacturing. Sector. Executive Summary. Impacts of new and retained business in the

Agricultural Trade Liberalization and Poverty in China: A Dynamic CGE Model Analysis

AGRODEP Technical Note 0015

The Economic Impacts of Private Tourism-Related Investments in Jamaica

Steel & Aluminum Tariffs Produce Minimal Impact on Jobs, GDP: CPA Economic Model Refutes Alarmist Trade Partnership Study

Economic Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Concepts and Measurement

Investigating the Relationship between Green Tax Reforms and Shadow Economy Using a CGE Model - A Case Study in Iran

SOCIAL ACCOUNTING MATRIX (SAM) AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR MACROECONOMIC PLANNING

The global economic crisis and child well being in South Africa: summary results

Is China's GDP Growth Overstated? An Empirical Analysis of the Bias caused by the Single Deflation Method

LABOUR MARKET CLOSURES AND CGE ANALYSIS

INTRODUCTION THE JAPANESE ECONOMY AND THE 2005 INPUT-OUTPUT TABLES

COMMISSION: Commission on the Political and Constitutional Future of Québec (Bélanger- Campeau)

Economic Impacts of a Universal Pension in Bangladesh

Patterns of Growth and Public Spending in Uganda: Alternative Scenarios for

MDGs Example from Latin America

What types of policy decisions is CGE model findings most useful for

A poverty module of the MIRAGE model of the world economy

AEA poster presentation. Contact: Karen Thierfelder

The Economic implication of retirement age extension in China. --A Dynamic general equilibrium analysis

B.A. SOCIAL SCIENCE - ECONOMICS. Semester - I. Title of The Paper - MICRO ECONOMICS

World Food Prices and Human Development

Effects of Globalization on Poverty and Distribution in Argentina in the 1990s

Restoring confidence in South Africa to oil wheels for growth Dimanche, 05 Août :10 - Mis à jour Dimanche, 05 Août :12

The Impact of Electricity Price Increases and Eskom s Six-Year Capital Investment Programme on the South African Economy

Macroeconomic Modelling at the Central Bank of Brazil. Angelo M. Fasolo Research Department

The Development of a Computable General Equilibrium Model of the Economic Impact of a Science-Based Industrial Park in Taiwan

AN ANALYSIS OF SOUTH AFRICA S VALUE ADDED TAX. Delfin S. Go, World Bank. Marna Kearney, South Africa National Treasury

Macroeconomics. Part Two: Unemployment and Money. Dr. Ali Moghaddasi Kelishomi. Warwick Economics Summer School 2016

The Implications for Fiscal Policy Considering Rule-of-Thumb Consumers in the New Keynesian Model for Romania

Tariff Reduction and Income Distribution: A CGE-based Analysis for Urban and Rural Households in Pakistan

Simple Macroeconomic Model for MDGs based Planning and Policy Analysis. Thangavel Palanivel UNDP Regional Centre in Colombo

ECA. An empirical assessment of the African Continental Free Trade Area modalities on goods. November 2018

Transcription:

Vol. 6(12), pp. 284-289, December, 2014 DOI: 10.5897/JEIF2014.0573 Article Number: A82FBAA49377 ISSN 2141-6672 Copyright 2014 Author(s) retain the copyright of this article http://www.academicjournals.org/jeif Journal of Economics and International Finance Full Length Research Paper Trade policy, fiscal constraint and their impact on education in the long run Maisonnave Hélène University of the Free State, South Africa. Received 17 February, 2014; Accepted 7 November, 2014 Many studies have evaluated the impact of trade liberalisation in South Africa. Our study proposes to evaluate the consequences of trade liberalisation when fiscal constraints and budget discipline lead government to reallocate the fiscal adjustment induced. More precisely, we will focus on the consequences on the education system and the consequences of students performances at school in long run. To evaluate the impacts of this tariff removal, we will use a Computable General Equilibrium model (CGE) to be able to capture the economy wide effects, and especially on the education sector. We present a tariff removal combined with three different fiscal options, and analyse the results on the education sectors. We found that the decrease in government spending has dramatic impacts on students behaviours in the long run, whereas an increase in the indirect tax on commodities affects the post-secondary education sector. Key words: Trade policy, fiscal constraints, impacts of trade liberalisation, impact on education. INTRODUCTION Trade liberalisation in South Africa The South African trade policy was mainly geared towards import substitution before 1970s according to Bell (1992, 1997). From then, quantitative restrictions started to reduce until South Africa joined the World Trade Organisation in 1994. Since then, the country reduced most of its tariffs except for agricultural commodities, textile and the automobile sector. Most of the Computable General Equilibrium models (CGE) applied to South Africa deal with trade issues. Gelb et al. (1992) developed a dynamic one sector CGE to evaluate the impact of a negative external shock and the setting of a program of government stimuli. Then, Van der Mensbrugghe (1995, 2005), Devarajan and Van der Mensbrugghe (2000) developed a CGE to understand the impacts of trade liberalisation and increases in public spending. Thurlow and Van Seventer (2002) propose a standard CGE modelling framework for South Africa. Mabugu et al. (2010) evaluate gender discrimination on labour market after trade liberalisation. An originality of their work is that it takes into account household s home production. They find that trade liberalisation has a better impact on men s salaries than on women s, due to the sectoral employment repartition. Thurlow (2006) finds that trade liberalisation has affected men and women differently and that it has worsened inequality in the country. E-mail: helene.maisonnave@ecn.ulaval.ca Author agree that this article remain permanently open access under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License 4.0 International License

Maisonnave 285 Table 1. Structure of the South African trade. Sectors Share of import in total absorption (%) Share of import in total imports (%) Share of export in total production (%) Share of exports in total exports (%) Agriculture 6.8 1.9 15.6 4.4 Coal 5.7 0.3 50.6 5.3 Gold 0.0 0.0 92.8 14.7 Other mining 64.5 7.1 81.4 16.0 Food 6.3 4.4 7.8 5.1 Textile 12.8 2.9 10.1 2.0 Footwear 20.5 14.4 3.2 0.1 Petrol 20.1 1.1 15.0 9.4 Other non iron mineral 13.7 21.2 10.6 0.8 Steel 33.9 2.8 32.0 19.0 Electronic Equipment 25.3 8.7 11.9 1.0 Radio 58.0 14.7 12.8 0.9 Transport equipment 35.8 8.3 16.0 4.7 Other manufacturies 15.7 0.0 19.1 7.7 Electricity 0.0 0.0 1.7 0.3 Water 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 Construction 0.6 0.2 0.1 0.0 Trade 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 Hotel and restaurant 11.8 1.5 14.5 1.8 Transport services 16.8 7.2 9.6 3.6 Communications 5.3 1.2 3.3 0.7 Financial intermediation 2.0 1.2 3.7 2.0 Real estate 0.4 0.1 0.1 0.0 Business activities 3.7 0.8 2.0 0.4 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source: Computations from the SAM (2001). Hérault (2006) uses a static model to analyse the impact of trade liberalisation using all the information contained in household s survey. He finds that whatever the closure, neoclassical or Keynesian, trade liberalisation seems to be pro-poor. Employment creation in the formal sector seems to be the cause of this decrease on poverty. In terms of inequality, intra group inequalities decrease whereas inter group increase. Chitiga and Mabugu (2007) analyze the impact of protection in textile sector on poverty levels, using a dynamic micro simulation CGE. They find that increasing protections in this sector is not good for the whole economy, welfare decreases and poverty increases. Finally, Chitiga and Mabugu (2009) review the different attempts to evaluate the impacts of trade liberalisation on South Africa. Our paper deals with the impact on trade liberalisation on the education sector, and specifically on students behaviour given fiscal constraints. From the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) we use in the model, we can illustrate the relations between South Africa and the rest of the world. Table 1 points out the penetration rate of imports as well as the export intensity. It gives as well export intensity in sectoral production, and the share of each sector in total exports. It is relevant to notice that the two thirds of other mineral supply are imported. Moreover, radio equipment and transports equipment also strongly depend on imports. Given this structure, one can think that an increase in imports due to a decrease of tariffs will have strong consequences in these sectors. However, the three main sectors in total imports are the sector of other non-iron mineral products (Othnon, 21.2%): the Radio sector (14.7%) and the footwear sector (14.3%). South Africa exports most of its production of mineral and precious metal, but we can also highlight its exports in hotel and restaurant sectors (14.5%), or in other industries (19.1%). Precious metal and mineral represent 65.2% of total exports of the country. An external shock on mineral price would have strong effects on the economy. However, South Africa also exports transports services, transports equipment and

286 J. Econ. Int. Finance other industries. As previously mentioned, South Africa has already cut its tariffs. However, for some commodities, tariffs remain quite high (for instance, footwear, other mineral and electronic equipment). These commodities will be sharply vulnerable to a tariff cut. Moreover, these sectors use a lot of intermediaries consumptions, meaning that a decrease in the production of these sectors will have consequences on other sectors, notably trade and petrol sectors. The model and data used Our model is inspired by Decaluwé et al. s (2001) 1 model. We have changed several assumptions to better represent the South African economy. The labour force is disaggregated by population group and skill levels so that we end up with twelve different labour categories. Each activity uses capital and the different types of labour. We assume that there is unemployment on each labour market. We have also disaggregated households such that we have households by population groups (African, Coloured, Indian and White). Then, we have specified households consumption with a Linear Expenditure System (LES) of Stone Geary (1954) function, and we assume that transfers between institutions are significant. Finally, we consider that South Africa cannot export as much as it wants by introducing an export demand function with determined elasticity. We also assume that aggregate capital-skilled labour has a CES between capital and skilled labour, but is presumed to be very low (quasi-leontief, at 0.1). This indicates that capital and skilled labour are complementary: some kinds of physical capital (such as a new type of electronic machinery) cannot be used to produce anything in the absence of skilled people. In order to model students behaviour, we follow Lofgren and Diaz-Bonilla (2006). Students are classified into three educational sectors (primary, secondary and post-secondary). Each year, a student graduates (dip), drops out (aban) or repeats a grade (red). Moreover, we assume that when a student graduates, she can go on studying (contdip) or enter the labour market (quitdip). What determines the students behaviour? We assume that a student s decision is influenced by three variables: (a) The quality of education, a variable which is directly linked to government spending. Indeed, if the government decides to increase the number of primary school teachers, we would expect improved quality due to a lower student to teacher ratio. Such an improvement in school quality would offer students more incentive to stay in school. 1 Chapitre 9 of Decaluwé, Martens et Savard (2001) (b) The wage differential between semi-skilled and lowskilled labour. If the average semi-skilled wage is sufficiently higher than the low-skilled one, the expectation of a higher income would act as an incentive for the student to continue their studies. (c) The wage differential between semi-skilled and skilled labour. Continuing on to more advanced schooling would become more attractive if the average skilled wage is sufficiently higher than the semi-skilled one. These changes in student s behaviours have impacts on labour supply. Following Lofgren and Diaz-Bonilla (2006), we assume that for a given year, labour supply is equal to what it was the previous years plus the volume of students that enter the labour market depending on their success at school. We assume that students who graduate from their primary education level would enter the labour market as low skilled workers. Students who would graduate from the secondary education level would enter the labour market as a semi-skilled worker whereas a student that graduates from the tertiary education level would enter the labour market as a skilled worker. The students who do not manage to graduate and drop out would enter the labour market at the next lower level. Therefore, it is easy to understand the potential links between a given policy and the education sector: for instance, if skilled wage rate drops after a shock in the economy, students might be willing to enter the labour market as semi-skilled workers and they will not be keen in going on in the tertiary level. In the same way, a negative shock on public expenditure will probably affect the education quality, and therefore students behaviours. To calibrate our model, we use the same Social Accounting Matrix as Cockburn et al. (2005). We used the same elasticity values as them for income and trade. To calibrate unemployment rates, we use the Labor Force Survey (2001) and use a wage curve (Blanchflower and Oswald, 1995), given the elasticities computed by Kingdon and Knight (2006). For the closure rules, the nominal exchange rate is fixed and is the numeraire of the model. As South Africa is a small country, world prices are fixed. The current account balance is exogenous. Labour supplies are fixed at the first period and then depend on students achievements. Capital demand is specific and exogenous at the first period, and then grows given the new investments made in the activity 2 SCENARIOS AND RESULTS We analyse three scenarios of total tariff removal with different fiscal policies. In the first scenario, government 2 We choose Bourguignon et al (1989) specification for the accumulation demand function

Maisonnave 287 Table 2. Impact on total investment (in % to Business As Usual). Scenario 1 Scenario 2 Scenario 3 Impact on total investment -22.6% -9.02% -5.3% does not offset the decrease in its tariffs income; in other words, government savings is endogenous and there is no fiscal policies set up. In the two other scenarios, we assume that government savings is fixed. To compensate the loss in its income tariffs, in the second scenario we assume that government sets up an indirect tax on products. In the third scenario, we assume that to keep its deficit constant, government reduces its public spending. Impacts on government s income and the relations with the rest of the world The removal of tariffs leads, ceteris paribus, to two direct consequences: On the one hand, receipts will decrease. This decrease in the receipts leads to a decrease in government s income as well as a decrease in its savings if no mechanism is set up to balance the cut of duty receipts. That is what happens in the first scenario, government s income decreases by -3.1% and its savings drop strongly (- 16.6%). In the two other scenarios, by hypothesis, public deficit remains constant. On the other hand, import prices are decreasing and this decrease will be stronger for former protected sectors. We expect that imports would increase, notably in footwear sector (+39.05%), in textile sector (+7.2%) and in electronic equipment (+4.6%). Moreover, the price of imports is decreasing, and this fall off will be greater for former protected sectors. Former protected sectors will have to adjust to price decreasing, and so, they will have to decrease their price to remain competitive. Given that, we expect a decrease of production in some of these sectors, as well as a decrease of the working force. The decrease of the production in these sectors will decrease in the same proportion intermediate consumptions that will have a strong impact for trade sector. The current account balance is fixed by hypothesis; the increase in imports must be joined to an increase of exports. We also assumed that South Africa cannot export as much as it wants, meaning that to export more, South Africa has to be more competitive. In other words, local producers have to decrease their prices. Impacts on institutions income and total investment: We saw that producers have to be competitive to export more. Thus, whatever the scenario, it infers that the workforce decreases. It comes that wage rates are decreasing and unemployment rates are increasing. Given the decrease in the wage rate, households income decrease as well as their savings, which is a proportion of their disposable income. In the second scenario, we introduced an indirect tax on products. In other words, households do not really benefit from the decrease of import prices because they have to pay a new tax. In this scenario, the decrease of households consumption is greater than in the other. Firm s income is mainly composed by capital income. We know that, given the numbers of firings, capital is relatively more abundant than labour. In the same way, the price decrease leads to a decrease of marginal productivity of capital; its return rate is decreasing. Thus, firm s income is decreasing as well as its savings. Whatever the scenario analysed, total investment is decreasing (Table 2), and the decrease is stronger in the first scenario given the damage of public savings. Impact on the educational system Previous effects are traditionally observed in short term for a trade liberalisation. Our aim is to analyse what happens on the education system, and notably if government has to reduce its spending in education to keep its deficit constant. Moreover, we know that trade liberalisation can have effects on wage rates, and these changes can have impacts on students behaviours. Indeed, as wage rate variations create incentives for students to go on studying or to enter the labour market, it is interesting to see how trade liberalisation affects students behaviours. We saw that students behaviour is determined by the supply of education services (assumed constant in the two first scenarios), wage differential between skilled and semi-skilled, and wage differential between semi-skilled and unskilled. As education supply is assumed fixed in the two first scenarios, only these two variables can infer any changes on students behaviours. Effects on education in these two scenarios are very low: given the decrease of the average wage rate, and the fact that the average skilled wage rate decreases more than the average semi-skilled wage rate, we can notice that the share of students that leaves secondary to enter the labour market is increasing slightly. In the third scenario, we assume that government keeps its deficit constant by decreasing its public spending. We

288 J. Econ. Int. Finance Table 3. Impact of trade liberalisation on students behaviours in the short run (scenario 3). Behaviour by cycle African Coloured Indian White Primary -0,24-0,11-0,10-0,10 Graduate (dip) Secondary -1,43-1,35-0,42-0,58 Post-secondary -1,43-1,19-0,39-0,23 Drop out (aban) Repeat (red) Primary 3,33 3,33 10,00 10,00 Secondary 0,94 1,21 2,73 2,31 Post-secondary 1,00 1,33 1,50 2,00 Primary 0,0 0,0 0,0 0,0 Secondary 0,50 0,33 0,00 0,00 Post-secondary 0,40 0,36 0,00 0,00 Continue diploma (contdip) Primary -0,11-0,11-0,11-0,11 Secondary -0,67-1,25-0,43-0,11 We only present results for the third scenario given that changes in the two first are really very low know that public spending in education plays a key role in students behaviours. Thus, to balance a loss of duty receipts, government reduces its spending, that leads to a decrease of the quality of education in each sector (- 2.77%). This decrease of the quality is followed by an increase of drop out and repetition rates and a decrease of graduation rate for each level of education. In the same way, the share of students that leave school after primary and enter the labour market is decreasing, whatever the population group (Table 3). In the short term, effects of full trade liberalisation are harmful for the South African economy as well as in the education sectors. If in the first scenario we observe a crowding-out effect, in the two other scenario, the layoffs lead to a decrease in wage rate and so a decrease in households income. Impacts on the education sectors are greater in the third scenario, given that the decrease in public spending is added to the changes in relative wages. In the long run, for the first scenario, the loss in government s income leads to an increase in its current deficit. This, as expected, has a negative impact on total investment. The drop in total investment affects most of the productive sectors that fire workers. Unemployment is going up while wage rate is going down. The drop in the wage rate, especially for skilled workers has an impact on students behaviour that does not continue after secondary education level. In the second scenario, government s savings is constant and the loss in tariff revenues is compensated by an increase in indirect taxes. This fiscal measure has quite a bad impact on the economy as it affects households consumption and firms intermediate consumption. In other words, the benefits from trade liberalisation in terms of price decrease are lowered by the increase in the indirect tax. Here again, unemployment rates are increasing and we observe the same mechanism as in the first scenario for the impact on education. It is actually in the third scenario that we observe huge impacts on education. Regarding the rest of the economy, we have the same effects as in the short run. The education sector faces in the long run a sharp decrease of its resources, as government spending adjusts. It means that the number of teachers is decreesing, or eventually schools are closing. This decrease in the supply of education services leads to a decline in the quality of the education system. Therefore, we observe that dropout rates and repetition rates are increasing, and graduation rate is therefore decreasing. Conclusion The aim of this paper is to analyze the impact of trade liberalisation on students behaviours. We evaluated this impact through two transmission channels, differential wage rates and public spending in education under three different fiscal scenarios. From our results, we find that setting up a full trade liberalisation without fiscal scenario is not sustainable in the long run, as the government s deficit hampers total investment and GDP in the long run. The education sectors, and especially the post-secondary education sector, are affected through the decrease in skilled wages. Compensating the losses by increasing the indirect tax rate on commodities is as well harmful for the economy and the education sectors. From the last scenario, we can conclude that the variations of public spending have a stronger effect on students behaviours than wage rate changes. Then, given our results, we can say that a trade liberalisation policy that would lead government to decrease its public spending would have harmful consequences on education sectors as well as

Maisonnave 289 the whole economy. However, we need to qualify our results as we simulated a full trade liberalisation in one shot. In this paper, we were more interested in understanding the mechanisms between trade liberalisation, different fiscal options and students behaviours. Conflict of Interests The author has not declared any conflict of interests. REFERENCES Bell T (1992). Should South Africa further liberalise its foreign trade?, Economics Trends Working paper no. 16, Department of Economics and Economic History, Rhodes University. Bell T (1997). «Trade Policy» in Michie. J, Padayachee V (eds.) The Political Economy of South Africa s Transition, Dryden Press, London. Blanchflower DG, Oswald AJ (1995). An introduction to the Wage Curve, J. Econ. Perspect. 9(3):153-167. Chitiga M, Mabugu R (2007). La protection du secteur des textiles et la pauvreté en Afrique du Sud : une analyse en équilibre général calculable dynamique micro-simulé, Cahier de recherche MPIA n 1, PEP, Université Laval. Chitiga M, Mabugu R (2009). Liberalizing trade in South Africa: a survey of computable general equilibrium modelling studies, S. Afr. J Econ. 77(3):445-464 Decaluwé B, Martens A, Savard L (2001). La politique économique du développement et les modèles d équilibre général calculable, Les Presses de l Université Montréal, Canada Devarajan S, Van Der MD (2000). Trade Reform in South Africa: Impacts of Households, Mimeo, The World Bank, Washington. Gelb S, Gibson B, Taylor L, Van Seventer J (1992). Modeling the South African Economy- Real Financial interactions, Macro Economic Research Group, Working Paper. Hérault N (2006). Building And Linking A Micro simulation Model To A CGE Model For South Africa, S. Afr. J. Econ. 74(1):34-58, 03. Kingdon G, Knight J (2006). How flexible are wages in response to local unemployment in South Africa?, Ind. Labour Relat. Rev. 59(3):471-495. Lofgren H, Diaz-Bonilla C (2006). MAMS: An Economy wide Model for Analysis of MDG Country Strategies, Technical Documentation, DECPG, World Bank. Mabugu R, Chitiga M, Cockburn J, Decaluwé B, Fofana I (2010). Case Study: A Gender-focused Macro-Micro Analysis of the Poverty Impacts of Trade Liberalization in South Africa, Int. J Micro Simulations 3(1):104-108 Statistics South Africa, (2001). Labor Force Survey, South Africa. Thurlow J (2006). Has Trade liberalization in South Africa affected men and women differently? DSGD Discussion Paper No 36, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington. Thurlow J, Van Seventer D (2002). A standard Computable General Equilibrium Model for South Africa, TMD Discussion Paper No 100, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington. Van Der MD (2005). Prototype Model for Single Country Real Computable General Equilibrium Model, Development Prospects Groups, World Bank. Van Der MD (1995). Technical description of the World Bank CGE of the South African Economy, Unpublished Rapport, OECD Development Centre, Paris.