D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS?

Similar documents
D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME H ARM S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO

O PTIMAL M ONETARY P OLICY FOR

OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR

OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY FOR

James Bullard Aarti Singh. This version: 13 February 2017

A Primer on Price Level Targeting in the U.S.

Debt Overhang and Monetary Policy

Optimal Credit Market Policy. CEF 2018, Milan

Economic Inequality and Possible Policy Responses

A New Characterization of the U.S. Macroeconomic and Monetary Policy Outlook 1

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory SPRING 2016

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Capital markets liberalization and global imbalances

Notes II: Consumption-Saving Decisions, Ricardian Equivalence, and Fiscal Policy. Julio Garín Intermediate Macroeconomics Fall 2018

Discussion of Optimal Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy Interaction in a Non-Ricardian Economy

Modern DSGE models: Theory and evidence DISCUSSION OF H. UHLIG S AND M. EICHENBAUM S PRESENTATIONS

Fiscal and Monetary Policies: Background

A Singular Achievement of Recent Monetary Policy

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

State-Dependent Fiscal Multipliers: Calvo vs. Rotemberg *

The Transmission of Monetary Policy through Redistributions and Durable Purchases

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

Macroeconomics. Based on the textbook by Karlin and Soskice: Macroeconomics: Institutions, Instability, and the Financial System

Debt Constraints and the Labor Wedge

Macroeconomics Field Exam August 2017 Department of Economics UC Berkeley. (3 hours)

The Lost Generation of the Great Recession

Monetary Policy Options in a Low Policy Rate Environment

SNEAK PREVIEW: Death of a Theory

Economic stability through narrow measures of inflation

Uncertainty Shocks In A Model Of Effective Demand

ECONOMIC GROWTH 1. THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

Slides III - Complete Markets

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2013

Business cycle fluctuations Part II

7) What is the money demand function when the utility of money for the representative household is M M

James Bullard. 13 January St. Louis, Missouri

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

. Social Security Actuarial Balance in General Equilibrium. S. İmrohoroğlu (USC) and S. Nishiyama (CBO)

Monetary Policy in Pakistan: Confronting Fiscal Dominance and Imperfect Credibility

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Improving the Use of Discretion in Monetary Policy

R-Star Wars: The Phantom Menace

Quiz I Topics in Macroeconomics 2 Econ 2004

Economics 502. Nominal Rigidities. Geoffrey Dunbar. UBC, Fall November 22, 2012

Macroprudential Policies in a Low Interest-Rate Environment

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

AGGREGATE IMPLICATIONS OF WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION: THE CASE OF INFLATION

Sentiments and Aggregate Fluctuations

Discussion of Fiscal Policy and the Inflation Target

ECO 407 Competing Views in Macroeconomic Theory and Policy. Lecture 3 The Determinants of Consumption and Saving

Atkeson, Chari and Kehoe (1999), Taxing Capital Income: A Bad Idea, QR Fed Mpls

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

An Illustrative Calculation of r

Intertemporal choice: Consumption and Savings

Comment on The Central Bank Balance Sheet as a Commitment Device By Gauti Eggertsson and Kevin Proulx

International Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

The Real Business Cycle Model

9. Real business cycles in a two period economy

U.S. Monetary Policy: A Case for Caution

Consumption. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

Foreign Ownership of US Safe Assets. Good or Bad?

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Chapter 11. Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle. Copyright 2008 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved.

LECTURE 5 The Effects of Fiscal Changes: Aggregate Evidence. September 19, 2018

Part III. Cycles and Growth:

The U.S. Economy in the Aftermath of the Financial Crisis

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Fiscal Consolidation Strategy: An Update for the Budget Reform Proposal of March 2013

Exchange Rates and Fundamentals: A General Equilibrium Exploration

Oil Shocks and the Zero Bound on Nominal Interest Rates

Balance Sheet Recessions

James Bullard President and CEO Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. SNB Research Conference Zurich 27 September 2014

Assessing the Risk of Yield Curve Inversion: An Update

The Zero Lower Bound

Exploding Bubbles In a Macroeconomic Model. Narayana Kocherlakota

Intermediate Macroeconomics: Economics 301 Exam 1. October 4, 2012 B. Daniel

Comments on Jeffrey Frankel, Commodity Prices and Monetary Policy by Lars Svensson

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

The U.S. Macroeconomic Outlook

MONETARY POLICY IN A GLOBAL RECESSION

Commentary. Olivier Blanchard. 1. Should We Expect Automatic Stabilizers to Work, That Is, to Stabilize?

Risk Shocks. Lawrence Christiano (Northwestern University), Roberto Motto (ECB) and Massimo Rostagno (ECB)

Monetary Policy Report: Using Rules for Benchmarking

Classes and Lectures

Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2007

INTERMEDIATE MACROECONOMICS

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

Distortionary Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy Goals

Concerted Efforts? Monetary Policy and Macro-Prudential Tools

Transcription:

D OES A L OW-I NTEREST-R ATE R EGIME P UNISH S AVERS? James Bullard President and CEO Applications of Behavioural Economics and Multiple Equilibrium Models to Macroeconomic Policy Conference July 3, 2017 London, United Kingdom Any opinions expressed here are the author s and do not necessarily reflect those of the FOMC.

Overview

THIS TALK This is an academic talk, and the arguments presented here are preliminary and theoretical in nature. In the model presented here, household credit markets will play an essential role in the economy. There are no sticky prices. Instead, the key friction in the economy is non-state contingent nominal contracting (NSCNC) in household credit markets. Monetary policy will be able to overcome this friction entirely by using a version of nominal GDP targeting. There will be a high-interest-rate and a low-interest-rate regime. Under the optimal monetary policy, the allocation of resources will be first-best in either the high or the low regime. In this sense, a low-interest-rate regime will not be detrimental to savers (or any other households). I will discuss important caveats to this conclusion.

Low Interest Rates and Saving

LOW INTEREST RATES AND SAVING Since the 2007-2009 financial crisis and recession, interest rates in advanced economies have been exceptionally low compared with postwar norms. A criticism of monetary policy in advanced economies following the crisis has been that the low-interest-rate regime has been detrimental for savers. I have been sympathetic to this criticism, but I did not have, nor have I seen, an analysis that I thought got to the core of the issue. I now have what I think is a better analysis, and it has tempered my views on this issue somewhat. This presentation sketches the argument and provides a list of important caveats at the end.

LOW INTEREST RATES EMPIRICALLY FIGURE: Source: Federal Reserve Board, U.S. Department of the Treasury, Bank of England, European Central Bank and Japan s Ministry of Finance. Last observation: June 26, 2017.

Credit Market Friction

THE RETURN OF HOUSEHOLD CREDIT MARKETS The 2007-2009 financial crisis increased attention on household credit markets. Could monetary policy be used to help keep household credit markets working well?

HOUSEHOLD CREDIT IN A DSGE MODEL I study an economy with a large private credit market that is essential to good macroeconomic performance. This market has an important friction: NSCNC. The role of monetary policy will be to keep this large credit market functioning properly (i.e., complete). When large and persistent negative shocks hit the economy, the zero lower bound (ZLB) will threaten. The monetary authority can maintain a smoothly operating credit market even when the ZLB threatens. I will not emphasize ZLB issues in this talk (see Azariadis, Bullard, Singh and Suda, 2015).

INCOME AND WEALTH INEQUALITY There is a lot of income and wealth inequality in this stylized model. The role of credit markets, if they work correctly, will be to reallocate uneven income across the life cycle into perfectly equal per capita consumption. The model equilibrium will naturally rank the wealth Gini coefficient as the highest, the income Gini coefficient as somewhat lower, and the consumption Gini coefficient as the lowest.

HOW LARGE ARE THESE MARKETS? According to Mian and Sufi (AER, 2011), the ratio of household debt to GDP in the U.S. was about 1.15 before it ballooned to 1.65 during the 2000s. In today s dollars, that would be equivalent to going from about $19.5 trillion to about $28 trillion in household debt, comprised mostly of mortgage debt. Disrupting these markets might be quite costly for the economy, so the NSCNC friction could be quite important.

What I Do

WHAT I DO Simple, stylized, endowment DSGE T-periods (quarterly) life-cycle model of privately-issued debt, real interest rates and inflation. Privately-issued debt = mortgage-backed securities. The economy has a large credit sector and a small cash sector. In this paper, the cash sector 0. Friction: NSCNC. Aggregate labor productivity growth is the only source of uncertainty. This will follow a regime-switching process. Monetary policy can substitute for the missing state-contingent contracts by choice of the price level. Labor supply will be heterogeneous but independent of monetary policy choices. For more on this, see Bullard and Singh (2017).

THE MONETARY POLICY IMPLICATIONS Optimal monetary policy is a version of nominal GDP targeting countercyclical price level movements. The stochastic driving process has high productivity growth and low productivity growth. These will be associated with relatively high real interest rates and relatively low real interest rates, respectively. The optimal monetary policy will work well (perfectly) in either the high- or the low-real-interest-rate regime. In particular, savers will get as good an allocation as they can in either regime the low-rate regime does not punish savers. These results may help inform the debate on monetary policy in a low-real-interest-rate environment.

Environment

SEGMENTED MARKETS Standard T-periods (quarterly) DSGE life-cycle endowment economy with segmented markets. Any T 3 will work; I prefer T = 241 (quarterly); odd values are convenient. Households are divided into two types: participants in the credit markets and non-participants. I set the non-participant sector 0. There are two assets in the model: privately-issued debt (consumption loans) and currency. I set currency 0 ( cashless limit ). In this cashless limit, we can simply think of the monetary policymaker as controlling the price level directly.

PREFERENCES All participant households entering the economy at date t have log preferences with no discounting T V t = E t [η ln c t (t + j) + (1 η) ln l t (t + j)], j=0 where η (0, 1], c t (t + j) > 0 is the date t + j consumption of the household born at date t, and l t (t + j) (0, 1) represents the fraction of a unit time endowment devoted to leisure. Households that entered the economy at previous dates have similar preferences and carry a net-asset-holding position into date t. Other assumptions: Within-cohort agents are identical, no population growth, no capital, no default, flexible prices, no borrowing constraints.

KEY FRICTION: NSCNC Loans are dispersed and repaid in the unit of account that is, in nominal terms and are not contingent on income realizations. There are two aspects to this friction: (1) The non-state contingent aspect means that real allocations will be perturbed by this friction, and (2) the nominal aspect means that the monetary authority may be able to repair the distortion.

STOCHASTIC STRUCTURE Aggregate real output is produced as Y (t) = Q (t) L (t), where L (t) is the labor input and Q (t) is the level of technology. The technology improves at stochastic rate λ (t, t + 1). Labor supply with η (0, 1) will turn out to be independent of the real wage. The real wage w (t) is then given by where w (0) > 0. w (t + 1) = λ (t, t + 1) w (t), (1) I assume the mean of λ (t, t + 1) > 1, so that the economy grows on average. For sufficiently large, negative shocks to λ, the ZLB will threaten and policy would have to respond (see Azariadis, Bullard, Singh and Suda, 2015).

REGIME SWITCHING I follow Bullard and Singh (IER, 2012, Section 2.4) to define a two-state regime-switching process for λ. There is a high-growth state with mean λ H and a low-growth state with mean λ L. Within each regime, there is additive noise described by σɛ (t), where σ is a scale factor and ɛ (t) i.i.d. N (0, 1). A latent variable s (t) determines the regime and follows a first-order Markov process. The resulting process for λ (t, t + 1) can be written as an AR (1) process with a nonstandard error term.

TIMING PROTOCOL At the beginning of date t, nature moves first and chooses λ (t 1, t), which implies a value for w(t). The policymaker moves next and chooses a value for the price level, P (t). Households then decide how much to consume and save.

COMPLETE MARKETS WITH NSCNC For convenience, I assume a net inflation target of zero. The countercyclical price level policy rule delivers complete markets allocations: P (t) = E t 1 [λ (t 1, t)] λ r P (t 1), (2) (t 1, t) where λ r indicates a realization of the shock. This is similar to Sheedy (BPEA, 2014) and Koenig (IJCB, 2013). Households will consume equal amounts of available production in the credit sector. This is equity share contracting, which is optimal under the homothetic preferences assumed here. Consumption and asset holdings fluctuate from period to period, but in proportion to the value of w (t). This price level rule renders the households decision problem deterministic because it insures the household against future shocks to income.

LIFE-CYCLE PRODUCTIVITY All participant households are endowed with an identical productivity profile over their lifetime. The profile begins at a low value, rises to a peak in the middle period of life, and then declines to the low value. I assume the low value is bounded away from zero for this talk. Agents can sell productivity units in the labor market at the competitive wage. The productivity profile is symmetric.

LIFE-CYCLE PRODUCTIVITY = CROSS SECTION 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 50 100 150 200 FIGURE: A schematic productivity endowment profile for credit market participants also represents the cross section of households at date t. The profile is symmetric and peaks in the middle period of the life cycle. About 50 percent of the households earn 75 percent of the labor income in the credit sector for η = 1.

LABOR INCOME CHANGES IN CROSS SECTION 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 50 100 150 200 FIGURE: How labor income changes across cohorts when the real wage increases 10 percent for η = 1.

Nominal Interest Rates

NOMINAL INTEREST RATE Participant households contract by fixing the nominal interest rate one period in advance. The non-state contingent nominal interest rate, the contract rate, is given by [ ] R n (t, t + 1) 1 ct (t) P (t) = E t. (3) c t (t + 1) P (t + 1) This rate depends on the expected rate of consumption growth and the expected rate of inflation. In the equilibrium I study, consumption growth rates are the same for all households, so this condition is also the same for all households.

STATIONARY EQUILIBRIA We let t (, + ). We only consider stationary equilibria under the perfectly credible policy rule governing P (t). We let R (t) be the gross real rate of return in the credit market. Stationary equilibrium is a sequence {R (t), P (t)} + t= such that markets clear, households solve their optimization problems, and the policymaker credibly adheres to the stated policy rule. The key condition is that net aggregate asset holding, A (t), nets out among participant households.

Graphs

NET ASSET HOLDING 15 10 5 5 50 100 150 200 10 15 FIGURE: Net asset holding by cohort along the complete markets balanced growth path with η = 1. Borrowing, the negative values to the left, peaks at stage 60 of the life cycle (age ~35), while positive assets peak at stage 180 of the life cycle (age ~65). About 25 percent of the population holds about 75 percent of the assets.

CHANGE IN NET ASSET HOLDING 20 10 50 100 150 200 10 20 FIGURE: How net asset holding changes by cohort when the real wage increases by 10 percent when η = 1.

CONSUMPTION 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 50 100 150 200 FIGURE: Schematic representation of consumption, the flat line, versus labor income, the bell-shaped curve, by cohort along the complete markets balanced growth path with w (t) = 1 and η = 1. The private credit market completely solves the point-in-time income inequality problem.

CHANGE IN CONSUMPTION 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 50 100 150 200 FIGURE: How labor income and consumption change by cohort when the real wage increases by 10 percent with η = 1.

HOUSEHOLD LABOR SUPPLY FIGURE: Schematic hump-shaped labor supply and U-shaped leisure by cohort under log-log preferences and interior solutions. Participant households in peak earning years work more, and those at the beginning and end of the life cycle work less, independent of consumption choices. The vertical axis is percent of available household time per period.

Complete Markets

COMPLETE MARKETS VIA NGDP TARGETING I have assumed a regime-switching process for productivity growth in this paper, and this corresponds to high- and low-real-interest-rate regimes. In principle, this economy could be mired in the low-interest-rate regime for a long time, depending on assumptions concerning the persistence of the regimes. Nevertheless, monetary policy can deliver first-best allocations via the price level rule described earlier. This occurs both within regimes and across regimes. The policymaker is undoing the NSCNC friction and restoring the Wicksellian natural rate of interest. There is no sense in which savers are hurt in the low-interest-rate regime (nor are borrowers helped ).

CAVEATS The policymaker here is allowed to observe the shock and then offset it with the appropriate setting for P (t). This is unrealistic, but similar to baseline New Keynesian models in which policymakers can appropriately offset incoming shocks. The low-real-interest-rate regime is associated with a slower rate of growth in real wages and real output. Households would rather be in the higher growth regime in this sense. But the productivity growth regime is taken as an exogenous process chosen by nature here. Monetary policy cannot switch the economy to the high-growth regime, but it can conduct an optimal policy given the regime. Monetary policy can be useful, but not so useful as to create high real growth.

CAVEATS I focus on an equilibrium where the real interest rate equals the output growth rate every period in the stochastic economy. There may be other equilibria. The policymaker and the private sector agents have rational expectations, meaning they understand the nature of the regime-switching process driving the economy. What if they had a misspecified model in which they expected the economy to return to a fixed mean? This may be occurring in actual monetary policy.

POLICYMAKER PERCEPTIONS FIGURE: Source: Federal Reserve Board and author s calculations. Last observation: May 2017.

PRIVATE SECTOR PERCEPTIONS FIGURE: Source: FRB of Philadelphia and author s calculations. Last observation: 2017-Q2.

Conclusions

CONCLUSIONS The desire behind many actual policy choices over the last several years has been to help credit markets perform better. This paper features a credit market that is essential to good macroeconomic performance. The friction in the market is NSCNC. The credit market here can be interpreted as a residential mortgage market mortgage-backed securities. Monetary policy can alleviate this friction and restore the smooth functioning of the credit market. This policy result remains even if the economy switches infrequently between high- and low-real-interest-rate regimes.

NATURAL VS. UNNATURAL REAL INTEREST RATES Here the monetary policymaker can restore the first-best allocation of resources by moving the price level to achieve the Wicksellian natural real rate of interest for the economy, with the natural rate itself fluctuating according to a regime-switching process. This analysis can provide a good baseline for thinking about the current situation in advanced economies if low real interest rates can be mostly attributed to factors exogenous to monetary policy. However, if low real interest rates are attributed to monetary policy itself (as many critics no doubt would argue), then it may be the case that those rates are distortionary and could hurt some segments of society. That could be analyzed here, say by having the policymaker set the wrong value for P (t) each period. That would require a computational solution as opposed to the pencil-and-paper solution used in this talk.