Desirable properties for a good model of portfolio credit risk modelling

Similar documents
Financial Risk: Credit Risk, Lecture 2

2.4 Industrial implementation: KMV model. Expected default frequency

Financial Risk Management

Review of the Topics for Midterm I

Continuous Processes. Brownian motion Stochastic calculus Ito calculus

Contagion models with interacting default intensity processes

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

CREDIT RATINGS. Rating Agencies: Moody s and S&P Creditworthiness of corporate bonds

Application of Stochastic Calculus to Price a Quanto Spread

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2011, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam.

u (x) < 0. and if you believe in diminishing return of the wealth, then you would require

3.4 Copula approach for modeling default dependency. Two aspects of modeling the default times of several obligors

Mathematics in Finance

Statistics for Business and Economics

Homework Assignments

Derivation Of The Capital Asset Pricing Model Part I - A Single Source Of Uncertainty

Course information FN3142 Quantitative finance

2 Control variates. λe λti λe e λt i where R(t) = t Y 1 Y N(t) is the time from the last event to t. L t = e λr(t) e e λt(t) Exercises

Lecture 17. The model is parametrized by the time period, δt, and three fixed constant parameters, v, σ and the riskless rate r.

Portfolio Credit Risk Models

Systematic Risk in Homogeneous Credit Portfolios

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Definition 9.1 A point estimate is any function T (X 1,..., X n ) of a random sample. We often write an estimator of the parameter θ as ˆθ.

Tangent Lévy Models. Sergey Nadtochiy (joint work with René Carmona) Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance University of Oxford.

Version A. Problem 1. Let X be the continuous random variable defined by the following pdf: 1 x/2 when 0 x 2, f(x) = 0 otherwise.

Week 1 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Basic Statistics A

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2012, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

16. Inflation-Indexed Swaps

Dependence Modeling and Credit Risk

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2009, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

1. Covariance between two variables X and Y is denoted by Cov(X, Y) and defined by. Cov(X, Y ) = E(X E(X))(Y E(Y ))

The University of Chicago, Booth School of Business Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2010, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay Solutions to Final Exam

Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago Business 41202, Spring Quarter 2007, Mr. Ruey S. Tsay. Solutions to Final Exam

Bonn Econ Discussion Papers

Forwards, Swaps, Futures and Options

Theoretical Problems in Credit Portfolio Modeling 2

Introduction Credit risk

Reading: You should read Hull chapter 12 and perhaps the very first part of chapter 13.

The Vasicek Distribution

Problem 1: Random variables, common distributions and the monopoly price

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Regime-dependent robust risk measures with application in portfolio selection

The Experts In Actuarial Career Advancement. Product Preview. For More Information: or call 1(800)

Utility Indifference Pricing and Dynamic Programming Algorithm

1/2 2. Mean & variance. Mean & standard deviation

Comparison results for credit risk portfolios

Rough volatility models: When population processes become a new tool for trading and risk management

AMH4 - ADVANCED OPTION PRICING. Contents

A Generic One-Factor Lévy Model for Pricing Synthetic CDOs

High-Frequency Data Analysis and Market Microstructure [Tsay (2005), chapter 5]

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

Lecture 8. The Binomial Distribution. Binomial Distribution. Binomial Distribution. Probability Distributions: Normal and Binomial

Chapter 3 - Lecture 5 The Binomial Probability Distribution

4.2 Bernoulli Trials and Binomial Distributions

Optimal Hedging of Variance Derivatives. John Crosby. Centre for Economic and Financial Studies, Department of Economics, Glasgow University

Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns A

STK 3505/4505: Summary of the course

S t d with probability (1 p), where

P2.T6. Credit Risk Measurement & Management. Malz, Financial Risk Management: Models, History & Institutions

Pricing CDOs with the Fourier Transform Method. Chien-Han Tseng Department of Finance National Taiwan University

IMPA Commodities Course : Forward Price Models

Multi-dimensional Term Structure Models

No-arbitrage theorem for multi-factor uncertain stock model with floating interest rate

We consider three zero-coupon bonds (strips) with the following features: Bond Maturity (years) Price Bond Bond Bond

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY 6.265/15.070J Fall 2013 Lecture 11 10/9/2013. Martingales and stopping times II

Dynamic Relative Valuation

Resolution of a Financial Puzzle

RISKMETRICS. Dr Philip Symes

Illiquidity, Credit risk and Merton s model

Approximating a multifactor di usion on a tree.

Risk Measurement in Credit Portfolio Models

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

Financial Risk: Credit Risk, Lecture 1

University of California Berkeley

Lattice Model of System Evolution. Outline

ERM (Part 1) Measurement and Modeling of Depedencies in Economic Capital. PAK Study Manual

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Multiname and Multiscale Default Modeling

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Optimizing Portfolios

Probability and Random Variables A FINANCIAL TIMES COMPANY

Mean-Variance Optimal Portfolios in the Presence of a Benchmark with Applications to Fraud Detection

Converting to the Standard Normal rv: Exponential PDF and CDF for x 0 Chapter 7: expected value of x

Introduction Dickey-Fuller Test Option Pricing Bootstrapping. Simulation Methods. Chapter 13 of Chris Brook s Book.

Aspects of Financial Mathematics:

Sampling and sampling distribution

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.pr] 23 Nov 2017

Implied Systemic Risk Index (work in progress, still at an early stage)

Brooks, Introductory Econometrics for Finance, 3rd Edition

Mixed Logit or Random Parameter Logit Model

Calculating VaR. There are several approaches for calculating the Value at Risk figure. The most popular are the

The Use of Importance Sampling to Speed Up Stochastic Volatility Simulations

6. THE BINOMIAL DISTRIBUTION

ROM SIMULATION Exact Moment Simulation using Random Orthogonal Matrices

Lecture 5. Predictability. Traditional Views of Market Efficiency ( )

Risks For The Long Run And The Real Exchange Rate

Probability Distributions II

IEOR E4703: Monte-Carlo Simulation

Transcription:

3.3 Default correlation binomial models Desirable properties for a good model of portfolio credit risk modelling Default dependence produce default correlations of a realistic magnitude. Estimation number of parameters should be limited. Timing risk producing clusters of defaults in time, several defaults that occur close to each other Calibration (i) Individual term structures of default probabilities (ii) Joint defaults and correlation information Implementation Empirical evidence There seems to be serial dependence in the default rates of subsequent years. A year with high default rates is more likely to be followed by another year with an above average default rate than to be followed by a low default rate.

Some definitions Consider two obligors A and B and a fixed time horizon T. p A = prob of default of A before T p B = prob of default of B before T p AB = joint default probability that A and B default before T p A B = prob that A defaults before T, given that B has defaulted before T p A B = p AB, p p B A = p AB B p A ρ AB = linear correlation coefficient p = AB p A p B. p A (1 p A )p B (1 p B ) Since default probabilities are very small, the correlation ρ AB can have a much larger effect on the joint risk of a position p AB = p A p B + ρ AB p A (1 p A )p B (1 p B ) p A B = p A + ρ AB pa p B (1 p A )(1 p B ) p B A = p B + ρ AB pb p A (1 p A )(1 p B ). and

For N obligors, we have N(N 1)/2 correlations, N individual default probabilities. Yet we have 2 N possible joint default events. The correlation matrix only gives the bivariate marginal distributions, while the full distribution remains undetermined. Price bounds for first-to-default (FtD) swaps fee on CDS on worst credit fee on FtD swap portfolio of CDSs on all credits s C s FtD s A + s B + s C With low default probabilities and low default correlation s FtD s A + s B + s C. To see this, the probability of at least one default is so that p = 1 (1 p A )(1 p B )(1 p C ) = p A + p B + p c (p A p B + p A p C + p B p C ) + p A p B p C p p A + p B + p C for small p A, p B and p C.

Basic mixed binomial model Mixture distribution randomizes the default probability of the binomial model to induce dependence, thus mimicking a situation where a common background variable affects a collection of firms. The default events of the firms are then conditionally independent given the mixture variable. Binomial distribution Suppose X is binomially distributed (n, p), then E[X] = np and var(x) = np(1 p). We randomize the default parameter p. Recall the following relationships for random variables X and Y defined on the same probability space E[X] = E[E[X Y ]] and var(x) = var(e[x Y ]) + E[var(X Y )].

Suppose we have a collection of n firms, X i = D i (T ) is the default indicator of firm i. Assume that p is a random variable which is independent of all the X i. Assume that p takes on values in [0, 1]. Conditional on p, X 1,, X n are independent and each has default probability p. We have and p = E[ p] = 1 0 pf(p) dp. E[X i ] = p and var(x i ) = p(1 p) cov(x i, X j ) = E[ p 2 ] p 2, i j. (i) When p is a constant, we have zero covariance. (ii) By Jensen s inequality, cov(x i, X j ) 0. (iii) Default event correlation ρ(x i, X j ) = E[ p 2 ] p 2 p(1 p).

Define D n = i=1 X i, which is the total number of defaults; then E[D n ] = np and var(d n ) = np(1 p) + n(n 1)(E[ p 2 ] E[ p] 2 ) (i) When p = p, corresponding no randomness, var(d n ) = np(1 p), like usual binomial distribution. (ii) When p = 1 with prob p and zero otherwise, then var(d n ) = n 2 p(1 p), corresponding to perfect correlation between all default events. (iii) One can obtain any default correlation in [0, 1]; correlation of default events depends only on the first and second moments of f. However, the distribution of D n can be quite different. ( ) Dn p(1 p) n(n 1) (iv) var = + n n n 2 var( p) var( p) as n, that is, when considering the fractional loss for n large, the only remaining variance is that of the distribution of p.

Large portfolio approximation When n is large, the realized frequency of losses is close to the realized value of p. [ ] [ ] Dn Dn P < θ = < θ f(p) dp. Note that D n n we have n 1 0 P n p = p p for n when p = p, since var P [ Dn n < θ p = p ] n { 0 if θ < p 1 if θ > p. Furthermore, [ ] Dn 1 P n < θ n 1 θ {θ>p} f(p) dp = 0 0 Summary ( ) Dn n = f(p) dp = F (θ). p(1 p). n Firms share the same default probability and are mutually independent. The loss distribution is 1 P [D n = k] = n C k 0 zk (1 z) n k df (z), k n. The above loss probability is considered as a mixture of binomial probabilities with the mixing distribution given by F.

Choosing the mixing distribution using Merton s model Consider n firms whose asset values Vt i follow dvt i = rvt i dt + σvt i dbt i with B i t = ρ B0 t + 1 ρ 2 Bi t. The GBM driving V i can be decomposed into a common factor B0 t and a firmspecific factor Bi t. Also, B0, B1, B2, are independent standard Brownian motions. Also, the firms are identical in terms of drift rate and volatility. Firm i defaults when (( ) ) V0 i exp r σ2 T + σbt i < D i 2 or ) ( ) ln V0 i ln D i + (r σ2 T + σ ρ B0 T + 1 ρ 2 BiT < 0. 2 We write Bi T = ɛ i T, where ɛi is a standard normal random variable. Then firm i defaults when ln V0 i ln Di + ( ) r σ2 2 T σ + ρɛ 0 + 1 ρ 2 ɛ i < 0. T

Conditional on a realization of the common factor, say, ɛ 0 = u for some u R, firm i defaults when ɛ i < c i + ρu 1 ρ 2 where ln V i ( ) 0 D c i = i + r σ2 2 T σ. T Assume that c i = c for all i, for given ɛ 0 = u, the probability of default is P (u) = N c + ρu 1 ρ 2 Given ɛ 0 = u, defaults of the firms are independent. The mixing distribution is that of the common factor ɛ 0, and N transforms ɛ 0 into a distribution on [0, 1]..

This distribution function F (θ) for the distribution of the mixing variable p = P (ɛ 0 ) is F (θ) = P [P (ɛ 0 ) θ] = P = P = N [ ɛ 0 1 ρ ( 1 ρ N c + ρɛ 0 1 ρ 2 θ ( 1 ρ 2 N 1 (θ) + c ) ( 1 ρ 2 N 1 (θ) N (p)) 1 where p = N( c). Note that F (θ) has the appealing feature that it has dependence on ρ and p. The probability that no more than a fraction θ default is P [ Dn n ] θ = 1 0 nθ k=0 ) ] nc k p(u) k [1 p(u)] n k f(u) du. When n, [ ] Dn θ P n θ n f(u) du = F (θ). 0 F (θ) is the probability of having a fractional loss less than θ on a perfectly diversified portfolio with only factor risk.

The figure shows the loss distribution in an infinitely diversified loan portfolio consisting of loans of equal size and with one common factor of default risk. The default probability is fixed at 1% but the correlation in asset values varies from nearly 0 to 0.2. Remarks 1. For a given default probability p, increasing correlation increases the probability of seeing large losses and of seeing small losses compared with a situation with no correlation. 2. Recent reference The valuation of correlation-dependent credit derivatives using a structural model, by John Hull, Mirela Predescu and Alan White, Working paper of University of Toronto (March 2005).

Randomizing the loss Assume that the expected loss given p is l( p) and it is strictly monotone. We expect the loss in default increases when systematic default risk is high, perhaps because of losses in the value of collateral. Define the loss on individual loan as then Define L i ( p) = l( p)1 {Di =1}, E[L i p = p] = pl(p) = (p). L = 1 n i=1 L i n so that the loss-weighted loss probability is 1 pl( p) P [L θ]n 1 {pl(p) θ} f(p) dp = F 0 ( 1 (θ)) where F is the distribution function of p and.

Contagion model Reference Davis, M. and V. Lo (2001), Infectious defaults, Quantitative Finance, vol. 1, p. 382-387. Drawback in earlier model It is the common dependence on the background variable p that induces the correlation in the default events. It requires assumptions of large fluctuations in p to obtain significant correlation. Contagion means that once a firm defaults, it may bring down other firms with it. Define Y ij to be an infection variable. Both X i and Y ij are Bernuolli variables The default indicator of firm i is P [X i ] = p and P [Y ij ] = q. Z i = X i + (1 X i ) 1 (1 X j Y ji ) j i.

Note that Z i equals one either when there is a direct default of firm i or if there is no direct default and (1 X j Y ji ) = 0. The latter case occurs when at least one of the factor X j Y ji is 1, which happens when firm j defaults and infects firm i. j i Define D n = Z 1 + + Z n, Davis and Lo (2001) find that where E[D n ] = n[1 (1 p)(1 pq) n 1 ] var(d n ) = n(n 1)βn pq n]) 2 βn pq = p 2 + 2p(1 p)[1 (1 q)(1 pq) n 2 ] +(1 p) 2 [1 2(1 pq) n 2 + (1 2pq + pq 2 ) n 2 ]. cov(z i, Z j ) = β pq n var(d n/n) 2.

Binomial approximation using diversity scores Seek reduction of problem of multiple defaults to binomial distributions. If n loans each with equal face value are independent, have the same default probability, then the distribution of the loss is a binomial distribution with n as the number of trials. Let F i be the face value of each bond, p i be the probability of default within the relevant time horizon and ρ ij between the correlation of default events. With n bonds, the total principal is mean and variance of the loss of principal P is E[ P ] = var( P ) = i=1 p i F i i=1 j=1 i=1 F i F j ρ ij p i (1 p i )p j (1 p j ). F i and the We construct an approximating portfolio consisting D independent loans, each with the same face value F and the same default probability p.

Solving the equations i=1 i=1 F i = DF p i F i = DF p var( P ) = F 2 Dp(1 p). p = D = ni=1 p i F i ni=1 F i ni=1 p i F i ni=1 (1 p i )F i ni=1 nj=1 F i F j ρ ij ρi (1 p i )ρ j (1 p j ) F = i=1 F i /D. Here, D is called the diversity score.