St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010

Similar documents
The cost of living and its implications for inequality and poverty measures for China

International Income Inequality: Measuring PPP Bias by Estimating Engel Curves. for Food

International Income Inequality: Measuring PPP Bias by Estimating Engel Curves. for Food

Financial security of elders in China

International Income Inequality: Measuring PPP bias by estimating Engel curves for food

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2014

Research Report No. 69 UPDATING POVERTY AND INEQUALITY ESTIMATES: 2005 PANORA SOCIAL POLICY AND DEVELOPMENT CENTRE

In detail, the two terms are purchase of living consumer goods (goumai shenghuo xiaofeipin) and purchase of non-goods (goumai feishangpin).

THE SENSITIVITY OF INCOME INEQUALITY TO CHOICE OF EQUIVALENCE SCALES

Revisiting the cost of children: theory and evidence from Ireland

INTERNATIONAL REAL ESTATE REVIEW 2002 Vol. 5 No. 1: pp Housing Demand with Random Group Effects

AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF GENDER WAGE DIFFERENTIALS IN URBAN CHINA

Robustness Appendix for Deconstructing Lifecycle Expenditure Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst

PART 4 - ARMENIA: SUBJECTIVE POVERTY IN 2006

Equality and Fertility: Evidence from China

The Impact of a $15 Minimum Wage on Hunger in America

Estimating the Value and Distributional Effects of Free State Schooling

1. The Armenian Integrated Living Conditions Survey

Estimating Upward Bias of Japanese Title Index Using Engel's Law.

Demand and Supply for Residential Housing in Urban China. Gregory C Chow Princeton University. Linlin Niu WISE, Xiamen University.

Chapter 6 Micro-determinants of Household Welfare, Social Welfare, and Inequality in Vietnam

Online Robustness Appendix to Are Household Surveys Like Tax Forms: Evidence from the Self Employed

Do Domestic Chinese Firms Benefit from Foreign Direct Investment?

A Microeconometric Analysis of Household Consumption Expenditure Determinants for Both Rural and Urban Areas in Turkey

1 For the purposes of validation, all estimates in this preliminary note are based on spatial price index computed at PSU level guided

Abstract. Keywords. 1. Introduction. Tongbo Deng

Welfare Analysis of the Chinese Grain Policy Reforms

Married Women s Labor Supply Decision and Husband s Work Status: The Experience of Taiwan

Empirical evaluation of the 2001 and 2003 tax cut policies on personal consumption: Long Run impact

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

The Changing Participation Rate of Canadians: New Evidence from a Panel of Demographic Groups

LABOR SUPPLY RESPONSES TO TAXES AND TRANSFERS: PART I (BASIC APPROACHES) Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics

Redistributive Effects of Pension Reform in China

Logistic Transformation of the Budget Share in Engel Curves and Demand Functions

One Child Policy Fines Relative to Income Levels in China

WEALTH INEQUALITY AND HOUSEHOLD STRUCTURE: US VS. SPAIN. Olympia Bover

GROWTH, INEQUALITY AND POVERTY REDUCTION IN RURAL CHINA

Robert Dekle Department of Economics University of Southern California Los Angeles, CA U.S.A.

TAXES, TRANSFERS, AND LABOR SUPPLY. Henrik Jacobsen Kleven London School of Economics. Lecture Notes for PhD Public Finance (EC426): Lent Term 2012

County poverty-related indicators

Regional Price Differences in Urban China : Estimation and Implication

Foreign Direct Investment and Economic Growth in Some MENA Countries: Theory and Evidence

Indicator 1.2.1: Proportion of population living below the national poverty line, by sex and age

Exploring the Returns to Scale in Food Preparation

Social-economic Analysis on Gender Differences in Time Allocation. A Comparative Analysis of China and Canada. Sonja Linghui Shan

A Behaviour-based Approach to the Estimation of Poverty in India

Tax Contribution and Income Gap between Urban and Rural Areas in China

Interest rate uncertainty, Investment and their relationship on different industries; Evidence from Jiangsu, China

Heterogeneity in Returns to Wealth and the Measurement of Wealth Inequality 1

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Labor Participation and Gender Inequality in Indonesia. Preliminary Draft DO NOT QUOTE

RELATIONS BETWEEN YOUTH EMPLOYMENT AND ELDERLY EMPLOYMENT IN CHINA

The Effects of Increasing the Early Retirement Age on Social Security Claims and Job Exits

An Empirical Study about Catering Theory of Dividends: The Proof from Chinese Stock Market

Response Mode and Bias Analysis in the IRS Individual Taxpayer Burden Survey

Private sector valuation of public sector experience: The role of education and geography *

The Moldovan experience in the measurement of inequalities

2. Data and Methodology. 2.1 Data

Comment on Counting the World s Poor, by Angus Deaton

Financial Risk Tolerance and the influence of Socio-demographic Characteristics of Retail Investors

Volume 35, Issue 1. Effects of Aging on Gender Differences in Financial Markets

Financial Liberalization and Money Demand in Mauritius

METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

HOUSEHOLDS INDEBTEDNESS: A MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS BASED ON THE RESULTS OF THE HOUSEHOLDS FINANCIAL AND CONSUMPTION SURVEY*

Fluctuations in hours of work and employment across age and gender

Bargaining with Grandma: The Impact of the South African Pension on Household Decision Making

FARMERS' EXPENDITURE IN GREECE: AN APPLICATION OF TRANSFORMATION OF THE VARIABLES

Dynamic Demographics and Economic Growth in Vietnam. Minh Thi Nguyen *

The use of linked administrative data to tackle non response and attrition in longitudinal studies

Notes on the Farm-Household Model

DYNAMIC DEMOGRAPHICS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN VIETNAM

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 76, No. 4. (Nov., 1994), pp

IJSE 41,5. Abstract. The current issue and full text archive of this journal is available at

Globalization and the Feminization of Poverty within Tradable and Non-Tradable Economic Activities

Gender wage gaps in formal and informal jobs, evidence from Brazil.

Supplementary Appendix

Population Aging, Economic Growth, and the. Importance of Capital

UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES OF A GRANT REFORM: HOW THE ACTION PLAN FOR THE ELDERLY AFFECTED THE BUDGET DEFICIT AND SERVICES FOR THE YOUNG

TRUE HOUSEHOLD EQUIVALENCE SCALES AND CHARACTERISTICS OF THE POOR IN THE UNITED STATES

Is Higher Volatility Associated with Lower Growth? Intranational Evidence from South Korea

NST TUTE FOR RESEARCH

Asian Journal of Economic Modelling MEASUREMENT OF THE COST-OF-LIVING INDEX IN THE EASI MODEL: EVIDENCE FROM THE JAPANESE EXPENDITURE DATA

Household Budget Share Distribution and Welfare Implication: An Application of Multivariate Distributional Statistics

Intermediate Quality report Relating to the EU-SILC 2005 Operation. Austria

Table 1 sets out national accounts information from 1994 to 2001 and includes the consumer price index and the population for these years.

Keywords: China; Globalization; Rate of Return; Stock Markets; Time-varying parameter regression.

Extending the Aaron Condition for Alternative Pay-As-You-Go Pension Systems Miriam Steurer

A Study on the Government Performance Evaluation Based on the Government Work Report of State Council and of Governments at Provincial Level

Jamie Wagner Ph.D. Student University of Nebraska Lincoln

A Reply to Roberto Perotti s "Expectations and Fiscal Policy: An Empirical Investigation"

Labour Quality and Inward FDI: A Firm-level Empirical Study in China

The model is estimated including a fixed effect for each family (u i ). The estimated model was:

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Expenditure and Income Inequality in Australia to

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

Fiscal Expenditure Competition of China s Local Governments: The Characteristics and Its Effects on Capital Allocation

The Distributions of Income and Consumption. Risk: Evidence from Norwegian Registry Data

The Performance Evaluation of China's Enterprise Annuity Investment Operations

Automated labor market diagnostics for low and middle income countries

Transcription:

Session Number: First Poster Session Time: Monday, August 23, PM Paper Prepared for the 31st General Conference of The International Association for Research in Income and Wealth St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010 China s Growth Miracle - Still Awaiting the Real Great Leap Forward? Ingvild Almas and Ashild Auglænd Johnsen For additional information please contact: Name: Ashild Auglænd Johnsen Affiliation: University of Oslo Email Address: aaajohnsen@gmail.com This paper is posted on the following website: http://www.iariw.org

China s growth miracle - still awaiting the real Great Leap Forward? Ingvild Almås and Åshild Auglænd Johnsen Very preliminary Abstract (JEL: D1, E31, F01) 1 Introduction Since reforms were initiated in 1978, the economic development of China has been tremendous. The World Bank reports that the poverty reduction has been significant in this period. The poverty measures are however subject to debate and uncertainty (Chen and Ravallion, 2008; The World Bank, 2009). Correcting for the cost of living is essential to poverty measurement, making prices a central part of the poverty reduction discussion. Considering the geography and large population of China, regional price levels are likely to differ. First, we have reasons to expect prices to differ across provinces; Alwyn Young (2000) documents that provincial protectionism evolved throughout the reform process, which contributed to increasing price level differences. Second, we have reasons to expect price variation also within provinces; e.g., it has been suggested that urban prices are Alms: Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration, Bergen, and University of Oslo, email: ingvild.almas@nhh.no. Johnsen: ESOP, University of Oslo, email: aaajohnsen@gmail.com Thanks to Olav Bjerkholt, Cheng Chang Sheng, Erik Sørensen, and Cheng Yuan for valuable comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies. 1

systematically higher than those in rural areas (Brandt and Holz, 2006). Hence, failing to adjust for regional price levels may have a significant impact on poverty estimates. More specifically, as we expect prices to be relatively lower in rural areas, this has the potential to lead to an overestimation of rural poverty relative to urban poverty. However, identifying price levels that allow for comparisons across provinces and across rural and urban areas within provinces, i.e. Spatial Price Indexes (SPI), is challenging methodologically as well as empirically. The methodological challenges for SPIs are analogue to those of CPIs which... The empirical challenges occurs because we lack sufficiently detailed price data for China... In this paper we identify Chinese SPIs by applying a simple, but empirically robust, economic theory - namely Engel s law - on household data. Incomes are then adjusted using the new price estimates given by the SPI, providing new estimates of real income. Subsequently new inequality and poverty estimates are calculated and compared to those not adjusted for SPI, i.e., those based on nominal incomes. This paper reports two main findings. First, national poverty rates are significantly lower when adjusting for spatial price differences. Second, however, the reduction in poverty shown by the nominal incomes is substantially overestimated in the period between 1995 and 2002. The most commonly used measure of prices in the economic literature is the consumer price index (CPI). More precisely, the CPI is constructed with the intention to measure changes in the cost of living. Hence, the CPI measures only inter-temporal changes in prices across provinces; it does not provide spatial price level differences for provinces (Brandt and Holz 2006). We need a Spatial Price Index (SPI) in order to provide price level differences across provinces, and this paper measures and uses such indices. In this sense, the SPI is analogous to the CPI. The construction of both the CPI and SPI rely on detailed and extensive price data. Furthermore, the procedure usually means compromising between data availability and the consistency with consumer preferences, leading to well-known problems such as the quality, substitution, outlet and weighting biases (Moul- 2

ton 1996; Costa 2001; Hamilton 2001; Brandt and Holz 2006; Almås 2007). The construction of a SPI requires highly detailed price data at a regional level, which is usually not available. Without such data, income can not be adjusted for systematic differences in spatial price levels (Brandt and Holz, 2006). The problems related to the construction of the CPI are dealt with by Hamilton (2001). Hamilton uses Engel s law to estimate bias in the consumer price index. Engel s law states that a household s budget share for food is inversely related to household real income (ibid.). This theory implies that there is a unique relationship between the budget share for food and total expenditures. Hamilton s main idea is to see the potential in applying Engel s law to measure the cost of living. If two households with identical characteristics, observed in different periods, have the same budget share for food, they should also have the same real income. As real incomes are produced by deflating nominal income by the CPI, a difference in their measured real incomes reveals a CPI bias. Hamilton suggests that the Engel curve approach could be extended and used in the estimation of movements in the cost of living (ibid.). By acknowledging the analogy between the SPI and the CPI we are able to deal with the problems related to the construction of the SPI and CPI directly - by applying the method proposed by Hamilton to estimate spatial price levels for Chinese provinces. This allows us to investigate whether provinces have different price levels, and furthermore whether the price levels differ according to whether a household is located in the urban or rural part of the provinces. Engel s law provides the theoretical background, and the method is based on the same principles as Hamilton s method. Consequently, the idea is that if two identical households located in different provinces have the same budget share for food but different nominal income; this reveals a price level difference. The chosen approach in this paper has two clear advantages. For one, even in cases where regional price data actually exists, the construction of a SPI is a time-consuming and a complex procedure (see Brandt and Holz (2006) for a thorough explanation). The Engel curve approach however, is much more straightforward and less tedious approach. 3

Second, and perhaps the most important argument, the strength of the Engel curve approach is that the cost of living is inferred directly from consumer behavior (Hamilton 2001). In the literature, other methods to identify SPIs have been proposed. First, nominal values could be used as an approximation to real income, thus ignoring spatial differences. This approach contradicts the basic premise on which this paper is based, namely that prices matter. As we expect that there will be considerable spatial price differences, in particular with regards to rural/ urban price levels, this approach is far from ideal for a country such as China. Second, we could assume that prices were the same in all regions in a specific base year and then use the regional CPIs to lead us from this base year to comparable cross-regional price levels for the year that we study. Brandt and Holz (2006) follow the second solution and construct spatial deflators based on this method for 1990. It is possible to argue that this method is attractive in the case of transitional economies with former centralized pricing systems, such as China. However, this method has to two disadvantages. First, prices can differ in the base year. Second, the method relies on the CPI, which is a biased measure of price changes. Gluschenko (2006) compares such a CPI proxied price level with a SPI constructed for Russian regions and he concludes that this method fails to provide precise estimates of cross-regional price variation. Thus, neither of these proposed methods proves themselves to be ideal for identifying regional price levels. Gong and Meng (2008) apply the Hamilton method to identify SPIs for households in the urban parts of different provinces for the period 1986-2001. The approach here has many similarities to theirs, but with one major difference. The strength of this analysis is the inclusion of a large number of rural as well as urban households covering several provinces in all of China s regions, whereas they cover only urban households. When considering poverty rates, inclusion of rural areas is of utmost importance. This allows for the investigation of the relative price levels of the less advanced economic regions compared to urban areas. 4

2 Methodology 2.1 Econometric specification Following the approach of Hamilton (2001), cross-provincial Engel curves for food for the years 1995 and 2002 are estimated by the quadratic extension of the Almost Ideal Demand System (Deaton and Muellbauer, 1980), namely the Quadratic Almost Ideal Demand System (QUAIDS) proposed by Banks Blundell and Lewbel (1997). Household data for several provinces and municipalities in China for 1995 and 2002 are used to estimate the relationship between the budget share for food and household income. Based on the assumptions that the demand function is correctly specified, that consumer s preferences are stable throughout the period, and that the variables contain no systematic errors, a set of urban and rural dummy variables reveal a set of price levels. Based on the dummy coefficient estimates, the SPIs are constructed. According to Hamilton (2001) and Costa (2001), food is an ideal indicator good for measuring real income for the following reasons. First, the indicator good should be sensitive to variation in income, which is the case for food as the income elasticity of food is substantially different from unity. Second, food can be characterized as a nondurable good. Expenditures and consumption of food in one period are nearly identical, as opposed to a durable good, which is bought in one period but consumed throughout several periods of time. Third, the definition of food is straightforward, as opposed to other goods such as leisure (Hamilton, 2001). The QUAIDS system is given by: m h,c,p,u = a+b 1 (lny h,c,p,u lnp p,u )+b 2 (lny h,c,p,u lnp p,u ) 2 +γ(lnp f,c,p,u lnp n,c,p,u )+θx h,p,u +ε h,p,u, (1) where m h,c,p,u is the budget share for food for household h, in county c province p in rural/urban area, u. P p,u is a price index, homogenous of degree 1 in prices. P f,c,p,u and P n,c,p,u are prices for food and non-food, respectively. X h,c,p,u is a vector of demographic control variables, and ε h,c,p,u is the residual. 5

Table 1: Comparison of the surveys 1995 2002 Individuals Households Mean hh size Individuals Households Mean hh size Rural 34 739 7 998 4.35 37 969 9 200 4.14 Urban 21 687 6 931 3.13 20 632 6 835 3.02 Total 56 426 14 929 3.79 58 601 16 035 3.66 Note: The cost-of-living is a function of the three prices of the system: lnc(v,p f,p,u,p n,p,u ) = lnp p,u + vb 1 vl, (2) where v is the utility level, b = P b 1 f,r,s, j P b 1 n,r,s, j and l = Pλ f,r,s, j P λ n,r,s, j, λ = b 2 b. 3 Data 3.1 Micro data from household surveys Household data used in the estimation are provided by the Chinese Household Income Project, collected in 1995 and 2002. Both data sets are separated into a rural and an urban part, based on information provided by rural and urban households. These households were selected from larger samples consisting of approximately 65 000 rural households and 35 000 urban households in 1995 drawn by the State Statistical Bureau. Two sets of household survey questionnaires accompany the data sets. As we can see from Table 3.1, the average household size for rural households is larger than the urban average for both years. The total number of provinces, autonomous regions (AR) and Direct-control municipality (DM) in China is 30 in 1995 and 31 in 2002 (excluding Taiwan), and data covers all provinces but four. The missing provinces, autonomous regions and municipalities are listed in Table 3.1., the largest of the four municipalities, was not established 6

until 1997. Prior to that, it was a part of, and hence included in the 1995 sample, since is included in both years. In 2002 is included as a separate entity. In 1997 Hong Kong came under China s rule, while Macau was handed over in 1999. Neither of these are included in the samples of 1995 and 2002. Large economic centers such as Shanghai and Tianjin are not included, and more remote areas such as Tibet and Inner Mongolia are excluded as well. Ideally, the data set would contain information on all provinces, municipalities and autonomous regions in China at that particular time. But based on own calculations, we can state that population numbers for regions in 1995 (NBS, 1996) show that the included provinces cover approximately 83 percent of the national population (excluding Taiwan). For 2002, the same number is 88 percent (excluding Taiwan, Macao and Hong Kong) (NSB, 2003). The main specification includes the following control variables: elders, age, and gender of head of household. Furthermore, it is restricted to households of two adults and one child, in order to make these households comparable (see e.g. Logan () and Deaton () for a discussion of how demographic characteristics can shift Engel curves). However, as showed in Section 5, in this study the main result is maintained when including the whole sample and applying an equivalence scale to make households with different demographic characteristics comparable. Income is measured by household consumption expenditures. Deaton argues that measuring income by consumption is the most appropriate for developing countries where household expenditure surveys are available (Deaton and Zaidi, 2002). First, consumption is a more satisfactory measure of well-being. Second, income can be erratic, especially in agricultural societies. Self-employment can involve several sources of income, which can lead to large variations in annual income. Expenditures however, capture consumptionsmoothing. Third, consumption data can be cheaper to collect relative to income data in developing countries compared to more formalized industrial economies, and on occasion consumption data can be the only available information. Consumption is smoother over 7

Table 2: Regions Included regions Missing regions 1995 2002 1995 2002 Provinces AR/DM Provinces AR/DM Fujian Fujian - Rural provinces 19 22 Hainan Inner Mongolia Hainan Inner Mongolia Heilongjiang Ningxia Heilongjiang Ningxia Urban provinces 11 12 Qinghai Shanghai (DM) Qinghai Shanghai (DM) Tianjin (DM) Tianjin (DM) Tibet Tibet - Both rural and urban area covered 11 12 Special administered regions/other: Hong Kong, Macao, Taiwan Note: 8

the period of a year, and more reliable in the sense that it reflects actual behavior. Fourth, there are no obvious reasons to underreport consumption expenditures as compared to income. With income data, the survey reporters might underreport income if they e.g. suspect that these data could become available to the tax authorities (Deaton and Zaidi, 2002). Thus, measuring income in terms of consumption has clear advantages in the case of China, and hence we use expenditure data to measure income. From here on, we refer to expenditures as income. The age and sex of head of household is included in the main regression. Head of household is restricted to individuals older than 15. In the rural data set for 1995 all but 328 (352 in 2002) individuals are male head of households, while 2289 (2220 in 2002) out of the urban heads of household are female. A variable denoting total members of household is constructed. Average number of members in a household included in the analysis is 3.1 (largest 8) for urban households and 4.3 for rural (largest 10) for 1995. The variable for number of adults was constructed by subtracting number of children from total members of household. Children are defined as being younger than 16. Elders are defined by the official retirement age in China, which is 60 for men, and 55 for women. Education of head of household is included in a robustness check in chapter 5. Education is defined by seven categories in the urban section. The rural questionnaire also includes an additional question regarding illiteracy. We construct three dummy variables on the basis of these categories, defined as higher, middle and lower education for head of household, provided that he or she is older than fifteen. The questionnaire for 2002 included nine categories for level of education. These were divided in order to match the definition for 1995. Other variables were also considered, such as temperature (capturing difference in tastes), but finding the corresponding temperature for each village and city was not feasible. Minority was considered. Besides the majority group Han, 56 ethnic minority groups are recognized in China, which represent approximately 10% of the total popula- 9

tion. However, this variable is highly correlated with income, and was consequently left out. In addition to the gender of head of household, a variable for the ratio of female to household was also tested. 4 Analysis and Findings The estimated SPIs are shown in??. As we can see from table 1 the preliminary estimation results suggest a positive relationship between price level and nominal income. Further we can see that the spread in price levels in 1995 is larger than the spread in 2002. 4.1 Inequality In 1995, we find a gini of 0.484 for nominal incomes and 0.682 for real incomes. In 2002, we find a gini of 0.409 for nominal income and 0.447 for real incomes. Hence, we can see that we find a reduction in inequality for both nominal and real incomes. 4.2 Poverty 5 Robustness Analysis 5.1 Household composition 6 Concluding Remarks In this paper we identify Chinese SPIs by applying a simple, but empirically robust, economic theory - namely Engel s law - on household data. Incomes are then adjusted using the new price estimates given by the SPI, providing new estimates of real income. Subsequently new inequality and poverty estimates are calculated and compared to those not adjusted for SPI, i.e., those based on nominal incomes. 10

Table 3: Estimation results without relative prices Variables Estimates Constant 1.281942*** Log of real income -.0671228*** Squared log of real income -.0000299*** Age.0016494*** Children.0074616*** Adults.0093748*** R95 1.1720152*** R95 2.0107864** R95 3.0098941** R95 4.0217603** R95 5.0442907*** R95 6.0262544*** R95 7.1198496*** R95 8.0143149** R95 9.0187171** R95 10.025215*** R95 11.0037919* R95 12.0062516* R95 13.0177045** R95 14.1599957*** R95 15.0068603** R95 16.0033427* R95 17.0274835*** R95 18.0027028* R95 19.0027666* U95 2.2696447*** U95 3.6910768*** U95 4.9118125*** U95 5.8368938*** U95 6.3961496*** U95 7.6809125*** U95 8 2.64109*** U95 9.7468727*** U95 10.6565064*** U95 11.576594*** U02 1 1.100656*** U02 2.1305015*** U02 3.487229*** U02 4.6238241*** U02 5.5526987*** U02 6.1722194*** U02 7.4271954*** U02 8 2.133436*** U02 9 11.4793249*** U02 10.5338218*** U02 11.6919187*** U02 12.2491937***

Table 4: Estimation results without relative prices (cont) Variables Estimates R02 1.0785641*** R02 2.0599272*** R02 3.0590931*** R02 4.0971205*** R02 5.0425667*** R02 6.1471299*** R02 7.1927661*** R02 8.1593259*** R02 9.2015201*** R02 10.1009786*** R02 11.0624257*** R02 12.1385193*** R02 13.174293*** R02 14.5349498*** R02 15.1529218*** R02 16.2255398*** R02 17.3227444*** R02 18.1859809*** R02 19.8309236*** R02 20.0391682*** R02 21.1214111*** R02 22.2625218*** 12

0.1.2.3.4 SPI_2 7.5 8 8.5 9 9.5 logmeanc Rural 1995 0 2 4 6 SPI_2 9.2 9.4 9.6 9.8 10 10.2 logmeanc Urban 1995 0.5 1 1.5 2 SPI_2 8.5 9 9.5 logmeanc Rural 2002 0 1 2 3 4 5 SPI_2 9.4 9.6 9.8 10 10.2 10.4 logmeanc Urban 2002 Figure 1: 13

References [1] A. Deaton, [2] A. Deaton and J. Muellbauer, 1980. An Almost Ideal Demand System, American Economic Review, 70(3): 312 326. [3] F. Denton and D. Mountain, 2004. Aggregation Effects on Price and Expenditure Elasticities in a Quadratic Almost Ideal Demand System, The Canadian Journal of Economics, 37(3): 613 628. [4] B. Hamilton, 2001. Using Engel s Law to Estimate CPI Bias, American Economic Review, 91(3): 619 630. [5] A. Heston, R. Summers, and B. Aten, 2002. Penn World Table Version 6.1, Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP), Philadelphia. [6] C. Leser, 1963. Forms of Engel Functions, Econometrica, 31(4): 694 703. Appendix A The calculation of non-food prices We know that P p,u is a function of P n p,u and P f p,u, given by the following equality: lnp p,u = a 0 + alnp f p,u + (1 a)lnp n p,u + 1 2 γ((lnpf p,u) 2 (lnp n p,u) 2 ). (3) Hence, we can express the following equality: 1 2 γ(lnpn p,u) 2 (1 a)lnp n p,u + ( a 0 alnp f p,u 1 2 γ(lnpf p,u) 2 + lnp p,u ) = 0, (4) 14

and we can solve for P n p,u: lnpp,u n = (1 a)2 + (1 a) 4 2 1γ( a 0 alnpp,u f 1 2 γ(lnpf p,u) 2 + lnp p,u ) 2 1 2 γ. (5) This can in turn be imputed in the regression equation and the only unknown is then P p,u which we find a solution for using iteration technique. 15