IDIOSYNCRATIC RISK AND AUSTRALIAN EQUITY RETURNS

Similar documents
The mathematical model of portfolio optimal size (Tehran exchange market)

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Module 6 Portfolio risk and return

The Cost of Capital for the Closely-held, Family- Controlled Firm

Measuring the Systematic Risk of Stocks Using the Capital Asset Pricing Model

The UNIVERSITY WITHOUT BORDERS Journal of ECONOMICS & BUSINESS

ECO 317 Economics of Uncertainty Fall Term 2009 Tuesday October 6 Portfolio Allocation Mean-Variance Approach

Procedia - Social and Behavioral Sciences 109 ( 2014 ) Yigit Bora Senyigit *, Yusuf Ag

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

Testing Capital Asset Pricing Model on KSE Stocks Salman Ahmed Shaikh

The Capital Asset Pricing Model in the 21st Century. Analytical, Empirical, and Behavioral Perspectives

University 18 Lessons Financial Management. Unit 12: Return, Risk and Shareholder Value

Financial Economics: Capital Asset Pricing Model

in-depth Invesco Actively Managed Low Volatility Strategies The Case for

Do stock fundamentals explain idiosyncratic volatility? Evidence for Australian stock market

Predictability of Stock Returns

DISCUSSION PAPERS IN ECONOMICS, FINANCE AND INTERNATIONAL COMPETITIVENESS

The Capital Asset Pricing Model as a corollary of the Black Scholes model

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

MULTI FACTOR PRICING MODEL: AN ALTERNATIVE APPROACH TO CAPM

CHAPTER 9: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL

BUSM 411: Derivatives and Fixed Income

Research Factor Indexes and Factor Exposure Matching: Like-for-Like Comparisons

The Effect of Kurtosis on the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Risk and Return. Nicole Höhling, Introduction. Definitions. Types of risk and beta

Expected Return and Portfolio Rebalancing

STRATEGY OVERVIEW. Long/Short Equity. Related Funds: 361 Domestic Long/Short Equity Fund (ADMZX) 361 Global Long/Short Equity Fund (AGAZX)

Theory Appendix to. Idiosyncratic Volatility, Growth Options, and the Cross-Section of Returns. Alexander Barinov

THE PENNSYLVANIA STATE UNIVERSITY SCHREYER HONORS COLLEGE DEPARTMENT OF FINANCE

An Analysis of Theories on Stock Returns

IDIOSYNCRATIC RISK AND REAL ESTATE SECURITIES RETURN

Financial Mathematics III Theory summary

Stock Price Sensitivity

Periodic Returns, and Their Arithmetic Mean, Offer More Than Researchers Expect

Common Macro Factors and Their Effects on U.S Stock Returns

Revisiting Idiosyncratic Volatility and Stock Returns. Fatma Sonmez 1

Sharpe Ratio over investment Horizon

Capital Asset Pricing Model - CAPM

Liquidity skewness premium

Journal of Asia Pacific Business Innovation & Technology Management

Risk and Return and Portfolio Theory

The Fisher Equation and Output Growth

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Factor Investing: Smart Beta Pursuing Alpha TM

The Capital Assets Pricing Model & Arbitrage Pricing Theory: Properties and Applications in Jordan

CHAPTER 9: THE CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL

Leverage Aversion, Efficient Frontiers, and the Efficient Region*

Validation of Fama French Model in Indian Capital Market

LECTURE NOTES 3 ARIEL M. VIALE

Prospect Theory and the Size and Value Premium Puzzles. Enrico De Giorgi, Thorsten Hens and Thierry Post

Decimalization and Illiquidity Premiums: An Extended Analysis

Log-Robust Portfolio Management

CHAPTER 8 Risk and Rates of Return

Archana Khetan 05/09/ MAFA (CA Final) - Portfolio Management

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

Long-run Consumption Risks in Assets Returns: Evidence from Economic Divisions

Financial Economics.

The Effects of Responsible Investment: Financial Returns, Risk, Reduction and Impact

Cross-Sectional Returns and Fama-MacBeth Betas for S&P Indices

Accounting Beta: Which Measure Is the Best? Findings from Italian Market

Journal of Finance and Banking Review. Single Beta and Dual Beta Models: A Testing of CAPM on Condition of Market Overreactions

Do Mutual Fund Managers Outperform by Low- Balling their Benchmarks?

Investment Advisory Whitepaper

Modern Portfolio Theory -Markowitz Model

Factors in Implied Volatility Skew in Corn Futures Options

The Conditional Relationship between Risk and Return: Evidence from an Emerging Market

The Asymmetric Conditional Beta-Return Relations of REITs

The Value Premium and the January Effect

DOES FINANCIAL LEVERAGE AFFECT TO ABILITY AND EFFICIENCY OF FAMA AND FRENCH THREE FACTORS MODEL? THE CASE OF SET100 IN THAILAND

Pay-For-Delay & Stock Prices: Smoking Gun Or Damp Squib?

Chilton Investment Seminar

MUTUAL FUND PERFORMANCE ANALYSIS PRE AND POST FINANCIAL CRISIS OF 2008

Australia. Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics.

Credit Risk and Underlying Asset Risk *

OPTIMAL RISKY PORTFOLIOS- ASSET ALLOCATIONS. BKM Ch 7

Module 3: Factor Models

Differential Pricing Effects of Volatility on Individual Equity Options

The mean-variance portfolio choice framework and its generalizations

Macro Factors and Volatility of Treasury Bond Returns 1

Non-Standardized Form of CAPM and Stock Returns

Testing the validity of CAPM in Indian stock markets

+ = Smart Beta 2.0 Bringing clarity to equity smart beta. Drawbacks of Market Cap Indices. A Lesson from History

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

Ulaş ÜNLÜ Assistant Professor, Department of Accounting and Finance, Nevsehir University, Nevsehir / Turkey.

From optimisation to asset pricing

RISK NEUTRAL PROBABILITIES, THE MARKET PRICE OF RISK, AND EXCESS RETURNS

CHAPTER 10. Arbitrage Pricing Theory and Multifactor Models of Risk and Return INVESTMENTS BODIE, KANE, MARCUS

APPLICATION OF CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL BASED ON THE SECURITY MARKET LINE

UNIVERSIDAD CARLOS III DE MADRID FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Testing Short Term and Long Term Applicability of CAPM: A Case of Pakistani Cement Industry

Keywords: Performance Measures, Equity Linked Savings Scheme, Risk Adjusted Returns.

Introduction and Subject Outline. To provide general subject information and a broad coverage of the subject content of

Investing at Full Tilt

FIN 6160 Investment Theory. Lecture 7-10

Modeling Portfolios that Contain Risky Assets Risk and Reward III: Basic Markowitz Portfolio Theory

Monetary Economics Risk and Return, Part 2. Gerald P. Dwyer Fall 2015

Sight. combining RISK. line of. The Equity Imperative

Diversified or Concentrated Factors What are the Investment Beliefs Behind these two Smart Beta Approaches?

PRINCIPLES of INVESTMENTS

Transcription:

IDIOSYNCRATIC RISK AND AUSTRALIAN EQUITY RETURNS Mike Dempsey a, Michael E. Drew b and Madhu Veeraraghavan c a, c School of Accounting and Finance, Griffith University, PMB 50 Gold Coast Mail Centre, Gold Coast, Queensland, 9726, Australia. b School of Economics and Finance, Queensland University of Technology, GPO Box 2434, Brisbane, Queensland, 4001, Australia. Abstract In this paper we investigate the relationship between portfolio returns and idiosyncratic risk for Australian stocks. We report that the portfolio with highest idiosyncratic volatility generates an average annual return of over 45%. We observe additionally that the outcome is consistent with an exponential growth process for stock prices. Further, consistent with Malkiel and Xu, we observe that a stock s idiosyncratic volatility is inversely correlated with the size of the underlying firm. Thus, our model advances an interpretation of the Fama and French finding that portfolios of stocks of small firms offer superior risk-adjusted returns. Moreover, our findings challenge the portfolio theory of Markowitz (1959) and the asset-pricing model of Sharpe (1964). JEL Classification: Keywords: G120, G150 (To confirm) Idiosyncratic risk, Capital Asset Pricing Model, Size effect 1. Introduction In their article (Risk and Return Revisited, 1997), Malkiel and Xu, confirm the controversial finding of Fama and French (1992) 1 that beta does not appear as an explanatory variable when attempting to model the annual returns on US stocks from 1963 through 1990. In addition, they confirm the Fama and French finding of a clear tendency for the portfolios of smaller companies to produce rates of return that are greater than the returns from portfolios of larger companies. The revelation that the returns of firms with respect to beta remain essentially flat and that the size of a company appears to be a far better proxy for risk than beta naturally remain controversial. Malkiel and Xu find additionally that portfolios of smaller companies have a higher idiosyncratic or non-market correlated volatility, and that portfolios of smaller companies post significantly higher average returns 2. In this article, we confirm the findings of Malkiel and Xu in the context of Australian firms. In addition, we are able to advance an alternative explanation as to why the market might reward idiosyncratic risk. We advance the hypothesis that the portfolios of firms with higher idiosyncratic Correspondence: E-mail: M.Dempsey@mailbox.gu.edu.au; Tel: 61-7-5594-8501; Fax: 61-7-5594-8068. We thank Pavlo Taranenko for excellent research assistance. The authors acknowledge the financial support from a School of Accounting and Finance Grant, Griffith University. We are, of course, responsible for any remaining errors. 1 Also see Fama and French (1993, 1995, 1996 and 1998) 2 See Malkiel and Xu (2000) for the relationship between idiosyncratic risk and security returns. They observe that idiosyncratic volatility is more powerful than either beta or firm size effect in explaining the cross-section of stock returns. Also see Campbell et al (2001) for a detailed study of volatility of common stocks at the market, industry and firm levels. 1

risk have higher returns, not because investors price them down in response to such risk, but because the higher risk of itself leads to higher returns. As we show, such a view is consistent with an organic or exponential growth model of capital appreciation. In developing these ideas, the remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In section II, we present our findings for Australian firms with regard to our observed portfolio returns and the idiosyncratic risk of portfolio assets. Sections III and IV present our explanation of our findings. Thus we advance an organic or exponential growth model of capital appreciation. Here, we consider the implications of the model for portfolio diversification, and demonstrate that the predictions of the model are in accord with the empirical findings. Section V presents concluding comments. 2. The observed relationship between return and idiosyncratic risk Malkiel and Xu (1997) form ten portfolios of companies according to their idiosyncratic volatility. Over the thirty-one years from 1963 through 1994, the average annual returns display a monotonically increasing dependence on the portfolio s idiosyncratic volatility. Thus the portfolio with lowest idiosyncratic volatility (5% per month) has an average annual return of just under 12%, while the portfolio with the highest idiosyncratic volatility (13% per month) has an average annual return of just under 19%. The results are summarized in Exhibit 1.0. 2

Exhibit 1.0 Relationship of Return and Idiosyncratic Volatility (Reporduced from Malkiel and Xu (1997)) 20 18 16 Average Annual Returns 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 5.05 5.62 6.03 6.55 7.03 7.71 8.47 9.3 10.46 13.14 Idiosyncratic Volatility 3

For our Australian sample of one hundred and twenty six firms from 1990 through 2000, four portfolios (P 1 through P 4 ) were constructed due to limitations of sample size. Our analysis of idiosyncratic risk and return is restricted to firms with available returns data, on the Datastream 3 return files from 1990 through 2000. We adopt the approach of Malkiel and Xu (1997) in constructing portfolios of idiosyncratic volatility. Portfolio P 1 consists of firms with lowest idiosyncratic volatility and P 4 with highest idiosyncratic volatility. Our results display a remarkable similarity with those of Malkiel and Xu. Our portfolio with lowest idiosyncratic volatility (3.2% per month) has an average annual return of approximately 13.58% (monthly return: 1.132%). The second portfolio with idiosyncratic volatility of 7.3% per month has an average annual return of 16.90% (monthly return: 1.409%). The third portfolio with idiosyncratic volatility of 11.4% per month has an average annual return of 19.83% (monthly return: 1.65%). These three portfolios cover the range of idiosyncratic risk observed by Malkiel and Xu. Our final portfolio with idiosyncratic volatility of 15.5% per month actually has an average annual return of approximately 45.5% (monthly return: 3.83%). The results are summarized in Table 1.0 and Exhibit 2.0. Table 1.0 Portfolio Idiosyncratic Volatility Average Annual Sample Size Returns P 1 3.2% 13.584% 73 P 2 7.3% 16.908% 34 P 3 11.4% 19.836% 11 P 4 15.5% 45.948% 8 3 Primark Corporation is a global information services company. We used Datastream, a Primark brand to obtain the data for this study. 4

Exhibit 2.0 Idiosyncratic Volatility and Return 50 45 40 35 Average Annual Returns 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 3.238 7.331 11.425 15.518 Idiosyncratic Volatility 5

3. The organic or exponential growth process Exponential or organic growth occurs commonly in nature and in the biological sciences. Such growth may be represented as the outcome of continuously applied growth rates that are selected independently across time from a normal distribution. For such growth, the outcome valuation at the end of a time period is the starting valuation multiplied by exp(y) where y is normally distributed; or, stated alternatively, the starting valuation multiplied by exp(µ+x) where µ represents the underlying mean or drift exponential growth rate for the period and x is normally distributed about zero with standard deviation (volatility), σ. The assumption that stock market growth can be modelled by such a process is justified by the evidence of past stock price performance (for example, Fama, 1976, ch. 2; and more recently, Jones and Wilson, 1999); while Fama (1976) observes that an a priori expectation for such a process is reinforced by the mathematics of selection as captured by the Central Limit Theorem. Investors, however, assess stock prices not in terms of their potential exponential growth characteristics, but in terms of their expected periodic return, by which we mean the expected percentage increase in wealth generated over some discrete period (a month, a year). Such return is familiarly expressed: expected periodic return = [expected wealth outcome of investing X for a single period - X ] / X (1) In order to generalize the relationship between the above periodic return in effect, the surface return which market participants seek to measure - and the sub-surface continuously-applied parameters µ and σ which generate the return, we commence by defining the exponential growth rate for expected wealth over a period, r, with the statement: $X exp(r) = expected wealth outcome of investing $X for a single period (2) which provides: r = ln [expected wealth outcome of investing $1 for a single period] (3) where ln represents the natural log function. Since the wealth outcome of investing $1 for a single period is assumed to be distributed as exp(y) where y is normally distributed with mean µ and standard deviation σ, the above equation may be expressed: r = µ + ½ σ 2 (4) as utilized in the continuous time framework of the Black-Scholes model. Combining equations 1, 2 and 4, we arrive at the relationship between an investment s expected periodic return and the parameters µ and σ as: expected periodic return = exp (µ + ½ σ 2 ) 1 (5) Since ½ σ 2 is necessarily positive, equation 5 confirms that the volatility of returns (σ) in an exponential growth process necessarily acts to increase the expected periodic return. 6

To illustrate the above insights, consider an asset which, with equal likelihood, may grow at an exponential rate 15%, or, alternatively, decline at a rate 15%. Notwithstanding that the mean exponential growth rate (µ) is zero, the asset grows by an expected factor [exp(0.15) + exp(-0.15)] / 2 = 1.01127; which is to say, with an exponential growth rate for expected wealth r (equation 3) equal to ln (1.01127) = 0.01121, or 1.121%. Note that in this example, the volatility or standard deviation (σ) of the allowed exponential growth rates is 15%. With outcome exponential growth rates normally distributed about zero with standard deviation 15%, equation 5 states that the expectation of return r is ½ (0.15) 2 ; which is to say, 0.01125, or 1.125%. With investment in a sufficiently large number of assets each with mean growth rate, µ, and idiosyncratic volatility about such rate, σ, all growth rates may be assumed to occur in proportion to their probability of occurrence; in which case, the return generated by the idiosyncratic volatility, ½ σ 2, becomes a certain outcome. If the risk captured by the volatility σ is systematic across assets in the portfolio, the expectation of return generated by the volatility remains as ½ σ 2, but may, of course, exceed or fall short of such expectation. The organic model of appreciation is consistent with the observation that the potential wealth outcome of an investment is, on the upside, theoretically unbounded, while on the downside it cannot be less than zero (since exp( ) =, while exp(- ) = 0). The model predicts that when volatility acts idiosyncratically to increase the number of unusually high returns, and simultaneously the number of unusually low returns in a portfolio, the overall outcome is an increase in the portfolio s overall rate of return. 4. Idiosyncratic Risk and the Empirical Evidence Given that idiosyncratic risk is effectively diversified away in a portfolio that comprises a sufficient number of uncorrelated stocks, we might expect that, in equilibrium, the return generated by idiosyncratic volatility, ½ σ 2, should be eliminated by upward adjustments in the prices of stocks. It is likely, however, that such equilibrium did not dominate observed returns over the period of the above studies. Firstly, as Malkiel and Xu have observed, the idiosyncratic volatility of small firm stocks had been increasing over the period of their study in a manner that remained essentially unrecognized at the time. Secondly, in so far as prices over the period of the study might have been adjusted upward in response to the return generated by idiosyncratic risk, such upward adjustment by virtue of being captured by the data would have had the effect of actually increasing - rather than decreasing - the measured returns on these stocks. The measured average annual return for the portfolios as a function of the portfolio s idiosyncratic volatility displays an unambiguously increasing relationship (both those of Malkiel and Xu for the US stock markets, and our own for the Australian markets). It is possible to impose the curve r = µ + ½ σ 2 on these findings. Their findings appear to be consistent with the prediction that the increasing return of their portfolios should be as a quadratic function of idiosyncratic volatility. In our model, an idiosyncratic volatility of 5% per month contributes ½ σ 2 = 0.125% to the monthly return (1.50% annualized); an idiosyncratic volatility of 13% per cent per month contributes ½ σ 2 = 0.845 % to the monthly return (10.14% annualized); while an idiosyncratic volatility of 15.5% per cent per month contributes ½ σ 2 = 1.20 % to the monthly return (14.42% annualized). In Figure 1.0, we have 7

displayed our model predictions against the empirical observations for the US and Australian markets. 5. Conclusion and implications The central prediction of the Capital Asset Pricing Model of Sharpe (1964) is that expected returns on securities are a positive linear function of their market betas. The CAPM also implies that there is a reward for bearing systematic risk which, is measured by the market risk premium. The CAPM also implies that idiosyncratic risk can be eliminated in a diversified portfolio and hence investors will not be rewarded for bearing idiosyncratic risks. However, Malkiel and Xu (1997 and 2000) contradict the CAPM by observing that idiosyncratic volatility is priced in the market and hence related to stock returns. Our findings are: (a) portfolio with high idiosyncratic risks generates high returns, (b) small stocks high idiosyncratic risks and therefore generate high returns. Malkiel and Xu (1997) are of the view that the relationship between idiosyncratic risks and stocks returns contradict the tenets of the CAPM which are the foundation of our understanding of how rational markets are expected to function. In response, we have advanced a model of stock market growth in terms of exponential rather than discrete one-period growth as advanced by the traditional CAPM. Whereas the one-period model implies that growth rates of x% and x% on equallyweighted investments effectively cancel, the organic growth model generates the growth factor [exp(x) + exp(-x)]/2, which is always greater than unity. Thus the organic model of capital appreciation predicts that given two well-diversified portfolios with the same mean exponential growth rate, µ, the one whose assets have the higher idiosyncratic volatility will have the higher return. The prediction is consistent with the empirical findings for both US and Australian stock markets as reported in this paper. As observed by Malkiel and Xu, the volatility of their stocks is correlated closely with the inverse of their firm size. Our findings therefore suggest a satisfying theoretical explanation for the findings of Fama and French to the effect that returns on stocks appear to be correlated closely with the inverse of their firm size. In addition, our findings challenge the portfolio theory of Markowitz (1952) and the CAPM of Sharpe (1964) which advances the notion that it is rational for a utility maximizing investor to hold a well-diversified portfolio of investments to eliminate idiosyncratic risks. In our view, a fascinating area of future research is to conduct additional empirical tests on the role of idiosyncratic risk in asset pricing. This is an issue we explore in our next paper. References Campbell, John Y., Martin Lettau, Burton G. Malkiel and Yexiao Xu, 2001, Have individual stocks become more volatile? An empirical exploration of idiosyncratic risk, Journal of Finance 56, 1-43. Dempsey, Mike, 2001, On Market, Risk and Return, Financial Analysts Journal forthcoming. Fama, Eugene F., 1976, Foundations of Finance, Basic Books, New York. 8

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1992, The cross-section of expected stock returns, Journal of Finance 47, 427-465. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1995, Size and Book-to-Market factors in earnings and returns, Journal of Finance 50, 131-155. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1996, Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies, Journal of Finance 51, 55-84. Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1998, Value versus growth: The international evidence, Journal of Finance 53, 1975-1999. Jones, Charles P., and Jack W. Wilson, 1999, Expectations about real returns, Journal of Portfolio Management 25, 45-52. Malkiel, Burton G., and Yexiao Xu, 1997, Risk and return revisited, Journal of Portfolio Management 23, 9-14. Malkiel, Burton G., and Yexiao Xu, 2000, Idiosyncratic risk and security returns, working paper, Department of Economics, Princeton University. Markowitz, Harry M., 1952, Portfolio Selection, Journal of Finance 7, 77-91. Sharpe, William F., 1964, Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk, Journal of Finance 19, 425-442. 9