Trade off theory of capital structure choice and its relevance for emergent markets: the Romanian case

Similar documents
Dr. Syed Tahir Hijazi 1[1]

Comparative study of the companies return and risk in Romania

Keywords: Equity firms, capital structure, debt free firms, debt and stocks.

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW. Modigliani and Miller (1958) in their original work prove that under a restrictive set

CAPITAL STRUCTURE AND FINANCING SOURCES IN MELLI BANK AND WAYS TO OPTIMIZE IT

Capital Structure and Survival Dynamic of Business Organisation: The Earnning Approach

TRADE-OFF THEORY VS. PECKING ORDER THEORY EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM THE BALTIC COUNTRIES 3

Interrelationship between Profitability, Financial Leverage and Capital Structure of Textile Industry in India Dr. Ruchi Malhotra

Corporate Financial Management. Lecture 3: Other explanations of capital structure

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Analysis of Non Financial Firms Listed in Karachi Stock Exchange in Pakistan

Ownership Structure and Capital Structure Decision

The Determinants of Capital Structure of Stock Exchange-listed Non-financial Firms in Pakistan

Optimal financing structure of companies listed on stock market

AN ANALYSIS OF THE CAPITAL STRUCTURE FOR COMPANIES LISTED ON THE BUCHAREST STOCK EXCHANGE

THE SPEED OF ADJUSTMENT TO CAPITAL STRUCTURE TARGET BEFORE AND AFTER FINANCIAL CRISIS: EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIAN STATE OWNED ENTERPRISES

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Relationship Between Capital Structure and Firm Performance, Evidence From Growth Enterprise Market in China

THE DETERMINANTS OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE IN THE TEXTILE SECTOR OF PAKISTAN

Capital Structure Antecedents: A Case of Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan

Lecture 6: Non Normal Distributions

Capital Structure and Financial Performance: Analysis of Selected Business Companies in Bombay Stock Exchange

Chapter 4 Level of Volatility in the Indian Stock Market

CHAPTER II LITERATURE STUDY

Bank Concentration and Financing of Croatian Companies

Chapter 18 Interest rates / Transaction Costs Corporate Income Taxes (Cash Flow Effects) Example - Summary for Firm U Summary for Firm L

A Comparison of Capital Structure. in Market-based and Bank-based Systems. Name: Zhao Liang. Field: Finance. Supervisor: S.R.G.

Cash holdings determinants in the Portuguese economy 1

DETERMINANTS OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE: EVIDENCE FROM LISTED MANUFACTURING COMPANIES IN SRI LANKA

Volatility Clustering of Fine Wine Prices assuming Different Distributions

Financial Management Bachelors of Business Administration Study Notes & Tutorial Questions Chapter 3: Capital Structure

IMPACT OF CAPITAL STRUCTURE ON PROFITABILITY: EMPITRICAL EVIDENCE FROM CEMENT INDUSTRY IN INDIA

DETERMINANTS OF HERDING BEHAVIOR IN MALAYSIAN STOCK MARKET Abdollah Ah Mand 1, Hawati Janor 1, Ruzita Abdul Rahim 1, Tamat Sarmidi 1

Impact of credit risk (NPLs) and capital on liquidity risk of Malaysian banks

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

THE IMPACT OF FINANCIAL LEVERAGE ON FIRM PERFORMANCE: A CASE STUDY OF LISTED OIL AND GAS COMPANIES IN ENGLAND

Capital structure and its impact on firm performance: A study on Sri Lankan listed manufacturing companies

Impact of Capital Market Expansion on Company s Capital Structure

THE DETERMINANT OF A FIRM OPTIMUM CAPITAL STRUCTURE: CONCEPTUAL AND THEORETICAL OVERVIEW. Ajao, Mayowa Gabriel

CAPITAL STRUCTURE: Implications of the different sources of financing

Some Puzzles. Stock Splits

DO ROMANIAN COMPANIES FOLLOW PECKING ORDER FINANCING? Keywords: Capital structure, pecking order theory, profitability, non linear, taxation.

Capital Structure Determinants: An Inter-industry analysis For Dutch Firms

DETERMINANTS OF CORPORATE DEBT RATIOS: EVIDENCE FROM MANUFACTURING COMPANIES LISTED ON THE BUCHAREST STOCK EXCHANGE

PAPER No.: 8 Financial Management MODULE No. : 25 Capital Structure Theories IV: MM Hypothesis with Taxes, Merton Miller Argument

DETERMINANTS OF FINANCIAL STRUCTURE OF GREEK COMPANIES

THE CAPITAL STRUCTURE S DETERMINANT IN FIRM LOCATED IN INDONESIA

CAN AGENCY COSTS OF DEBT BE REDUCED WITHOUT EXPLICIT PROTECTIVE COVENANTS? THE CASE OF RESTRICTION ON THE SALE AND LEASE-BACK ARRANGEMENT

Chapter 13 Capital Structure and Distribution Policy

Testing the static trade-off theory and the pecking order theory of capital structure: Evidence from Dutch listed firms

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Economics and Finance 6 ( 2013 )

Analysis of the determinants of Capital Structure in sugar and allied industry

Capital structure decisions

Capital structure and profitability of firms in the corporate sector of Pakistan

The Applicability of Pecking Order Theory in Kenyan Listed Firms

What is the effect of the financial crisis on the determinants of the capital structure choice of SMEs?

Investment and Financing Policies of Nepalese Enterprises

The Month-of-the-year Effect in the Australian Stock Market: A Short Technical Note on the Market, Industry and Firm Size Impacts

Modelling Inflation Uncertainty Using EGARCH: An Application to Turkey

A literature review of the trade off theory of capital structure

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

Masooma Abbas Determinants of Capital Structure: Empirical evidence from listed firms in Norway

FACULTY OF ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF LJUBLJANA MASTER S THESIS TANJA GORENC

The long- and short-term determinants of the capital structure of Polish companies 3.

FINANCE 402 Capital Budgeting and Corporate Objectives. Syllabus

CHAPTER 14. Capital Structure in a Perfect Market. Chapter Synopsis

Jeffrey F. Jaffe Spring Semester 2011 Corporate Finance FNCE 100 Syllabus, page 1 of 8

UNOBSERVABLE EFFECTS AND SPEED OF ADJUSTMENT TO TARGET CAPITAL STRUCTURE

Financial Crisis Effects on the Firms Debt Level: Evidence from G-7 Countries

The Debt-Equity Choice of Japanese Firms

Analysis of the Influence of the Annualized Rate of Rentability on the Unit Value of the Net Assets of the Private Administered Pension Fund NN

Deviations from Optimal Corporate Cash Holdings and the Valuation from a Shareholder s Perspective

An Empirical Research on Chinese Stock Market Volatility Based. on Garch

The Determinants of Capital Structure: Evidence from Turkish Panel Data

Asian Economic and Financial Review THE CAPITAL INVESTMENT INCREASES AND STOCK RETURNS

The Existence of Inter-Industry Convergence in Financial Ratios: Evidence From Turkey

CORPORATE CASH HOLDING AND FIRM VALUE

Effect of Profitability and Financial Leverage on Capita Structure in Pakistan Textile Firms

13034, Liberal Arts Building, PO Box 3323, Kuwait b School of Economics, Finance and Marketing, RMIT, 239 Bourke Street, Melbourne, Victoria

Local Government Spending and Economic Growth in Guangdong: The Key Role of Financial Development. Chi-Chuan LEE

The Debt-Equity Choice of Japanese Firms

The distribution of the Return on Capital Employed (ROCE)

The influence of capital structure on the value of the firm. A study of European firms. Aleksandr Klimenok Spring 2014

Economic downturn, leverage and corporate performance

The Relationship between Capital Structure and Profitability of the Limited Liability Companies

Debt and Taxes: Evidence from a Bank based system

Example 1 of econometric analysis: the Market Model

Prerequisites for modeling price and return data series for the Bucharest Stock Exchange

Jeffrey F. Jaffe Spring Semester 2015 Corporate Finance FNCE 100 Syllabus, page 1. Spring 2015 Corporate Finance FNCE 100 Wharton School of Business

Does Calendar Time Portfolio Approach Really Lack Power?

An Empirical Investigation of the Trade-Off Theory: Evidence from Jordan

International Journal of Multidisciplinary Consortium

Christina 1 ; Johan Halim 2 ABSTRACT

There are four major theories in explaining the capital structure of a firm, namely Modigliani-Miller theorem, the pecking order theory, the trade-off

An Empirical Study on the Capital Structure Decisions of Select Pharmaceutical Companies in India

Determinants of Capital Structure: A comparison between small and large firms

Revista Economică 69:3 (2017) CAPITAL STRUCTURE ON ROMANIAN LISTED COMPANIES A POST CRISIS INSIGHT

Sources of Financing in Different Forms of Corporate Liquidity and the Performance of M&As

Composition of Foreign Capital Inflows and Growth in India: An Empirical Analysis.

Systematic risks for the financial and for the non-financial Romanian companies

Examining RADR as a Valuation Method in Capital Budgeting

Transcription:

Trade off theory of capital structure choice and its relevance for emergent markets: the Romanian case MARILEN PIRTEA, BOGDAN DIMA, CLAUDIU BOłOC Finance Department West University of Timisoara, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration 16 J. H. Pestalozzi Street, 300115, Timisoara Romania marilen.pirtea@feea.uvt.ro; bogdan.dima@feaa.uvt.ro; claudiu.botoc@feaa.uvt.ro Abstract: - Standard corporate finance theory supposes that a company chooses a capital structure that maximizes company value. The capital structure of a company is basically described by the two main elements that characterize its debt: financial leverage and maturity. Optimal leverage represents a compromise between the nominal stream of tax benefits generated by debt, and the probability of this stream being received. This paper briefly tries to determine a relation between financial leverage and Price Earnings Ratio (PER). The main hypothesis is that such a relation reflecting in fact the linkage between the choice of capital level and structure and the market value of the company. For this purpose, we conduct an empirical research that covers 46 selected companies traded at the Bucharest Stock Exchange within the time period 2005-2009. Our main results reveal a negative relation between the ratios mentioned. Such output suggests that the earnings effect of changes in financial leverage prevails on price adjustments effects. Key-Words: - capital structure, financial leverage, value of company, PER, GMM-System estimators, Romanian capital market 1 Introduction The capital structure of a company is basically described by the two main elements that characterize its debt: financial leverage and maturity. Optimal leverage represents a compromise between the nominal stream of tax benefits that debt generates, and the probability of this stream being received. As the company increases its leverage, interest payments are higher, and also higher the tax deductions associated to these payments. This would induce the company to choose a leverage rate equal to 100 percent. However, there are two reasons why a company will never do this: First, higher leverage means higher default probability, with the costs associated to this event. Second, and more importantly, tax deductions only apply if the company has a taxable income, that is, if the company is getting positive profits, and these are less likely to happen with such level of interest payments. It is standard in literature to estimate it s capital structure by financial leverage. As for the definition of leverage, the ratio of total liabilities to total assets is the broadest one and used in many empirical studies. However, Rajan and Zingales (1995) point out that this definition is inappropriate for financial leverage since total liabilities includes items used for transaction purposes (e.g. account payable) rather than financing [1]. Also, Rajan and Zingales (1995) suggest that total debt to capital probably best represents the effects of past financing decisions. Therefore it could be define leverage as the ratio of total debt (short-term and longterm borrowing plus bond) to capital (total debt plus equity) in addition to total liabilities to total assets. The paper is organized as follows. The next section highlights theoretical considerations regarding the relation between capital structure, financial leverage and value of the company. The third section briefly describes the methodological framework, where for an empirical research we try in section four to search for a relation between financial leverage and value of the company expressed by PER. The data characteristics and the results are reported in this section, whilst the last section summarizes the conclusions of the paper. 2 Literature Review The roots of the modern capital structure theory can be assumed to be grown up on the seminal paper of Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller (1958) commonly known as the MM theory, dating back to 1958 as one of the most influential papers in the economics literature [2]. It states that based on the assumption of no brokerage, tax and bankruptcy costs, investors can borrow at the same rate as corporations and they would tend to have the same information as management about the company s future investment opportunities. The MM theory proves that under some restrictions a company s value would be unaffected by its capital structure and thus assumes that earnings before income tax ISSN: 1792-5983 750 ISBN: 978-960-474-241-7

(henceforth EBIT) would not have been related to the use of debt, that leads to the inference that capital structure may be considered irrelevant. Despite the fact that some of the fundamental assumptions of the theory can be assumed unrealistic in the eyes of investors and other economic agents, the MM relevance theory was generally accepted and subsequent research focused on relaxing some of its assumptions in order to develop a more realistic approach. In this sense, MM published another paper considering some of the criticisms or deficiencies of their theory and relaxed the assumption that there were no corporate taxes [3]. The underlying rationale for the MM theory is that the value of the company is determined solely by the left hand side of the balance sheet which reflects the company s investment policy [4]. So their theory suggests that the value of the company tends to be independent from the debt balance of the company, and instead, it is mainly affected by the presence of a number of projects handled with positive net present value (NPV). In line with these theoretical fundamentals, several arguments lead to the development of trade off theory which suggests that a company s target leverage is determined by taxes and costs of financial distress. Based on the trade off theory that the interest payments tend to be tax deductible, market debts appears to be less expensive than the use of equity financing. In effect, the government pays some portion of the interest incurred, or in other words, debt provides tax shelter benefits. As a result, debt increases the EBIT that provides more inflow to investors. Adding debt to a company s capital structure lowers its (corporate) tax liability and increases the after-tax cash flow available to the providers of capital. This leads us to assume that there would be a positive relationship between the (corporate) tax shield and the value of the company. However in practice, the companies rarely use 100% debt financing. When a company raises excessive debt to finance its operations, it may default on this debt and thus can be exposed to bankruptcy costs. For these reasons, trade off theory claims that tax shield benefits of debt financing need to be adjusted for financial distress costs that rise with increasing debt levels, creating an optimal capital structure that balances both forces [5]. Although the MM theory assumes that investors have the same financial information about a company with that of the managers, which can be referred to as symmetric information, in practice, it is more convenient to assume that managers are likely to have insider information (asymmetric information). Myers and Majluf (1984) accept that company managers have superior information about the actual value of the company [6]. Managers will enable to adjust themselves for the just-timing of the new equity issues if they observe that market price seems to be exceeding their own assessment of the stock value, that is, if the stocks tend to be overvalued by the market. Since investors are aware of the existence of the information asymmetry they will interpret the announcement of an equity issue as a signal of that the listed stocks are overvalued, which subsequently will cause a negative price reaction. If companies are required to finance new projects by issuing equity, under pricing may be so severe that new investors capture more than the net present value of the new project, which would result in a net loss to current shareholders. Even a positive net present value project will be rejected, leading to yet another underinvestment problem. The information costs associated with debt and equity issues have makes Myers (1984) to argue that a company s capital structure reflects the accumulation of past financial requirements. According to the pecking order theory of Myers (1984), companies prioritize their sources of financing - from internal financing to equity issues- according to the law of least effort, or of least resistance, preferring to raise equity as a financing means of last resort. Hence, internal funds are likely to be used first, and only when they are depleted will the companies apply to the new debt issues. Also when it is not sensible to issue any more debt, they would be obliged to realize new equity issues. This theory maintains that companies adhere to a hierarchy of financing sources and prefer internal financing when available, and debt is preferred over equity if external financing is required. The theory suggests that the companies apply to external finance if and only if internal finance has not been sufficient. In case of using external financing, the companies issue the cheapest security first so they start with debt, and then possibly apply to hybrid securities such as convertible bonds, and the issue equity only as a last resort. In contrast to the trade-off theory, there is no well-defined target leverage ratio in the pecking order theory. Debt is considered the first source of external finance on the pecking order. Equity is issued only as a last resort, when the debt capacity is fully exhausted. Tax benefits of debt are assumed to have a second-order effect. The debt ratio varies when there is an imbalance between internal funds and real investment opportunities. Standard corporate finance theory supposes that a company chooses a capital structure that maximizes company value. Based on this convention, there have been an important amount of researches concerning a company s capital structure decisions. Beginning with the paper of Modigliani and Miller (1958), it develops from models such as tax shelter vs. bankruptcy cost models to agency models, signaling models, and the model based on asymmetric information (pecking-order theory). Also, it is notable that intensive empirical researches followed theoretical development, especially in the U.S. Several studies presented the evidence that ISSN: 1792-5983 751 ISBN: 978-960-474-241-7

companies behave as if they had target debt-equity ratios and that capital structure models seem to explain actual financing decisions of companies. From these studies, we know that six important factors seem to affect the determination of financial leverage ratio [7]: 1. Taxes - Because of the deductibility of interest payments, using debt rather than equity reduces tax paid by the company. This gain should be large when the company does not have lots of tax shields other than interest payments (non-debt tax shie1ds). Thus, a company with fewer non-debt tax shields issues more debt. 2. Types of Assets - The costs of financial distress depend on types of assets. If a company has a large investment in fixed assets (land, buildings, other tangible assets), it will have smaller costs of financial distress than a company with a large investment in research and development (R&D) or advertising. The reason is that fixed assets have relatively high resale value whereas most of R&D or advertising value disappears in financial distress. Therefore, a company with larger fixed assets tends to increase debt, and a company with large expenditures to R&D or advertising prefers to have low leverage to reduce the probability of default. 3. Investment Opportunities - Companies having good investment opportunities should use a greater amount of equity finance because highly levered companies are more likely to pass up profitable investment. Also the costs of financial distress are large for the company with good investment opportunities. Thus, the better investment opportunities a company has, the lower leverage should be. 4. Uncertainty of Operating Income - Companies with uncertain operating income have a high probability of falling into financial distress, other factors being equal. Thus, these companies tend to issue equity rather than debt to reduce the possibility of financial crisis. In other words, uncertainty of operating income is negatively related to target leverage ratio. 5. Profitability - As Myers and Majulf pointed out, under asymmetric information, companies prefer internal funds (internal equity) to external financing (pecking-order-theory). Because profitable companies must have more retained earnings than unprofitable ones, they can finance with plenty of internal funds rather than debt. Thus, we predict the effects of profitability on leverage are negative. 6. Size - Large companies in general tend to be more diversified and less likely to be in financial distress. If so, size should have a positive impact on leverage. However, empirical evidence on the relation between financial leverage and expected stock returns is scarce and contradictory. Bhandari identifies leverage measured in market values as a separate risk factor [8]. Fama-French find that leverage based on book values has a negative risk premium, which contradicts Bhandari s result [9]. They conclude that these results are explained and absorbed by the book-to-market effect. However, Modigliani- Miller s proposition 2 (MM2) does not imply that leverage should be a separate risk factor. Hamada have shown that if the CAPM holds, betas should increase in financial leverage by an arbitrage mechanism [10]. This logic can be extended to show that all factor loadings in a multifactor model should increase in financial leverage. Base on these previous results, we argued that an increase in financial leverage will exercise at least two sets of distinctive effects on PER dynamic: Income effects since an increase in the return of borrowed financial resources is expected to improve the overall results of company activities and thus will leads to a decrease in PER level; Price adjustments effects linked to a greater interest of investors in stocks with lower levels of PER and implicitly with greater potential to growth after the inclusion in their portfolios. Thus, if the prices are elastic, an increase in financial leverage can end by contributing to an increase in PER level. Of course, these two effects are linked in a multiperiodical sequence and are amplified / inhibit by the global market conditions. More explicitly, if market displays at least a certain degree of informational efficiency, the income effects will be the first to be manifested followed by prices adjustments in a time span depending on prices elasticity. 3 Methodological framework Overall, the null hypothesis of the present study can be resumed as follows: H: The financial leverage growth will tend to reduce the level of PER since the income effects will prevail on prices adjustments effects in an emergent market with reduced liquidity and imperfect transaction mechanisms. Thus, the formal model describing the analytical background will be: ISSN: 1792-5983 752 ISBN: 978-960-474-241-7

PER = f ( Financial Leverage ) f Financial Leverage > 0 + ε i, t (1) This study estimates the dynamic panel data model using GMM-System estimator. The system GMM estimator (GMM-SYS) was proposed by Arellano & Bover (1995), Blundell & Bond (1998, 2000), and Windmeijer (2005) [11, 12, 13, 14]. A small panel sample may produce downward bias of the estimated asymptotic standard errors in the two-step procedure (Baltagi 2008) and thus we are using the Windmeijer correction for the estimated standard errors [15]. There are several advantages of the GMM-SYS over other static or dynamic panel estimation methods. Among them, at least two are relevant for this methodological framework: 1) Static panel estimates, as the OLS models, are subject of the problem of dynamic panel bias (Bond, 2002); 2) In our database there are 46 companies (N) that are analyzed over a period of 5 years (T) and there are several arguments in the literature that that the dynamic panel model is specially designed for a situation where T is smaller than N in order to control for dynamic panel bias [16]. 4 Results and comments 4.1 Data Data represents annual values of PER and financial leverage covering a time span of 2005-2009. PER is computed as the ratio between the last price of reference year and net income per share. The financial leverage is estimated according to: Total Debt Financial Leverage = ( ROIA eir) Total Equity ROIA eir Net operating income = Total Assets (Net) Interest expenditure = Financial debts 100 100 (2) Where ROIA represent the return on operational income to total assets and eir reflect the effective interest rate. The data are provided by Bucharest Stock Exchange (www.bvb.ro). The data are grouped in two conventional sectors: A (or primary and secondary industries- extraction and manufacture or refined of petroleum, including support services, manufacture of industrial machinery including manufacture of air and spacecraft and related machinery, private and industrial constructions, raw materials extraction and manufacture.) and, respectively, B (pharmaceutical products, equipments, telecommunications, transports, manufacture of agriculture products, tourism, and services). The main statistic characteristics of the data are reported in Table 1. It can be observed that the data are non-normal for both sectors with significant long-tails effects and peaked (leptokurtic) distributions. Table 1: Main statistic characteristic of the data Leverage "A" Leverage "B" PER "A" PER "B" Mean 0.0541 0.0071 16.7361 20.3473 Median 0.0116 0.0015 5.6550 11.3650 Maximum 3.9092 0.4529 258.4900 269.1000 Minimum -1.1774-0.1844 0.0000 0.0000 Std. Dev. 0.3866 0.0786 36.0623 32.3537 Skewness 8.0956 2.4026 3.9214 4.7850 Kurtosis 84.7655 17.1767 21.5346 34.1707 Jarque-Bera 34738.7400 1026.9810 2025.1960 4872.9790 Probability 0 0 0 0 Sum 6.493105 0.778735 2008.33 2238.2 Sum Sq. Dev. 17.79 0.67 154758.30 114096.90 Observations 120 110 120 110 4. 2 Results Table 2 reports the estimations using the GMMsystem (GMM-SYS) estimator. In order to check for the robustness of these estimations, along with the Sargan test, are reported also the residuals characteristics. The dynamic panel data can be considered valid if the estimator is consistent and the instruments itself are valid. Due to the small data sample, we are involving the Windmeijer (2005) correction for errors in small samples. Table 2: GMM-System estimation for the impact of financial leverage on PER indicator Dependent Variable: PER Method: Panel Generalized Method of Moments (period dummy variables included) Transformation: Orthogonal Deviations Sample (adjusted): 2007 2009 Periods included: 3 Cross-sections included: 24 for sector A and 22 for sector B Total panel (balanced) observations: 72 / 66 White period instrument weighting matrix White period standard errors & covariance (no degree of freedom correction) ISSN: 1792-5983 753 ISBN: 978-960-474-241-7

Constant added to instrument list Variable A B PER it 1 0.27*** -0.13*** (0.03) (0.02) [10.06] [-6.19] FinancialLeverage it 1-7.18*** -46.46** (0.71) (9.55) [-10.06] [-4.86] Expected sign + J-statistic 7.74 9.48 Sargan test 0.65 0.49 *, **, *** significance level at 10%, 5%, 1% Standard errors in () and t-statistic in [] Graphic 1: The histogram of standardized residuals 24 20 16 12 8 4 0-60 -40-20 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 25 20 15 10 5 0 Standardized Residuals -120-80 -40 0 40 80 120 Standardized Residuals - Series: Standardized Residuals Sample 2007 2009 Observations 66 Mean -1.261540 Median -3.386341 Maximum 173.2654 Minimum -58.28626 Std. Dev. 29.11026 Skewness 3.395877 Kurtosis 21.58680 Jarque-Bera 1076.891 Probability 0.000000 Series: Standardized Residuals Sample 2007 2009 Observations 72 Mean -2.559783 Median -1.569969 Maximum 113.6537 Minimum -135.0062 Std. Dev. 34.14899 Skewness -0.041752 Kurtosis 9.609501 Jarque-Bera 131.0774 Probability 0.000000 Overall, the results from Table 2 are indicating a statistical significant negative impact of lagged financial leverage on current dynamic of PER. In the mean time, such impact seems to have non-uniform amplitude in each of these sectors being larger for sector B and also displaying different levels of significance. Supplementary, the autoregressive pattern of PER is distinctive, positive for sector A and negative for sector B. It can be noticed the fact that the values of the Sargan tests for the over-identifying restrictions suggests that their formulation can be seen as satisfactory. However, the values of the distributional parameters for the estimation residuals display some differences between sectors in terms of estimation quality. While for sector A the values of skewness and kurtosis indicates a long left tail effect and a peaked (leptokurtic) distribution relative to the normal one, for sector B the distribution of residual appears to be more symmetric but still peaked. Still, despite the non-normality of residuals, it can be considered that the estimations are robust enough. Overall, the empirical evidences tend to support the H hypothesis. But the differences in specific results for the two considered sectors raise an important caveat. In greater details, these results seem to highlight some particularities in sectors prices mechanisms in terms of their adjustment speed under the impact of financial information. More exactly, since the spillover effects of financial leverage are larger in sector B it can be argued that for the financial instruments with issuers in tertiary sectors the prices are adjusting themselves stronger than for the financial instruments originated in primary and secondary sectors. Here, it should be noticed that the sector B is defined by the inclusion of the five financial investments societies SIF as well as of three larger credit institutions which are providing together an important fraction of the total market liquidity. Thus the prices adjustments effects are specially enhanced in this sector by the existence of a liquidity premium. 4 Conclusion The purpose of this study was to provides some empirical evidences on the connection between company s capital structure, as it is this reflected by the financial leverage, and market value described by PER. In GMM-System estimator, we found that a statistical significant negative correlation between these two variables holds even in the case of an emergent capital market as the Romanian one. In our view such output can be analyzed based on the assumptions of trade off theory. More exactly, one can argue that for an emergent market, with severe restrictions on financial resources supply side, the choice of the capital structure imply a tradeoff between external sources represented mainly by banking credit and limited appeal to the financing opportunities through the capital market. Of course this study have several limits both on conceptual as well as on empirical level. Among this: 1. The use of return of operating income to total assets ratio instead of EBIT on total sales ratio. The main reason for such substitution is connected to the real sectors prices rigidities and slow adjustments mechanism in an inflationary environment. Thus, we had ISSN: 1792-5983 754 ISBN: 978-960-474-241-7

considered that the total assets reflect better the output of the company s operational activities. 2. The short-time span considered, the limited numbers of traded companies included the absence of split by sectors, the absence of any references to the inter-correlation between stocks as well as between stocks and global market dynamic, some robustness of the estimated coefficient problems revealed by the existence of certain autocorrelations in estimation residuals etc. Despite the resulted caveats, we are arguing that there is a support for the trade off theory application to the Romanian case and further investigation are relevant for a better understanding of capital structure formation mechanisms. References: [1] Rajan, R., Zingales, L., What do we know about capital structure? Some evidence from International Data, Journal of Finance, 1995, 50(5), pp 1421-60. [2] Modigliani, F., & Miller, M., The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment, American Economic Review, 1958, 48(3), 261-97. [3] Modigliani, F., & Miller, M., Corporate Income Taxes and the Cost of Capital: A Correction, American Economic Review, 1963, 53(3), 433-443. [4] Drobez and Fix R., What are Determinants of Capital Structure? Some Evidence for Switzerland, WWZ working paper no.4/03, 2003. [5] Brounen, D., Eichholtz M., Capital Structure Theory Evidence from European Property Companies: Capital Offerings, Forthcoming in Real Estate Economics, 2001, 21(4). [6] Myers, S., Majluf, N., Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions when Firms have Information that Investors do not have, Journal of Financial Economics 13, 1984, 187-221. [7] Harris, M., Raviv, A., The theory of capital structure, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 46, No. 1, 1991, pp 297-355. [8] Bhandari, L. C., Debt/Equity Ratio and Expected Common Stock Returns: Empirical Evidence, Journal of Finance XLIII, 1988, pp 507-528. [9] Fama, E. F., French, K., The cross-section in expected stock returns, Journal of Finance 47, 1992, pp 427-466. [10] Hamada, R. S., The Effect of the Firm s Capital Structure on the Systematic Risk of Common Stocks, Journal of Finance 27(2), 1972, pp 435-452. [11] Arrelano, M., Bover, O., Another look at the instrumental variables estimation of error components models, Journal of Econometrics, 1995, 68, 29-51. [12] Blundell, R., Bond, S., Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models, Journal of Econometrics, Elsevier, 1998, 87(1), 115-143. [13] Blundell, R., Bond, S., GMM Estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions, Econometric Reviews, Taylor and Francis Journals, 2000, 19(3), 321-340. [14] Windmeijer, F., A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators, Journal of Econometrics, Elsevier, 2005, 126(1), 25-51. [15] Baltagi, B. H., Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, Chichester: John Wiley & Sons Ltd., 4 th edition, 2008. [16] Bond, S., Dynamic Panel Models: A Guide to Micro Data Methods and Practice, Institute for Fiscal Studies, Department of Economics, UCL, CEMMAP, Working Paper CWPO9/02, 2002. ISSN: 1792-5983 755 ISBN: 978-960-474-241-7