Introduction Theory Equilibrium Data and Methodology Results conclusion. Toxic Arbitrage. Wing Wah Tham. Erasmus University Rotterdam

Similar documents
Toxic Arbitrage * Thierry Foucault Roman Kozhan Wing Wah Tham. March, Abstract

Toxic Arbitrage * Thierry Foucault Roman Kozhan Wing Wah Tham. November, 2014 (First draft: September 2012) Abstract

Tick Size Constraints, High Frequency Trading and Liquidity

Equilibrium Fast Trading

Toxic Arbitrage * Thierry Foucault Roman Kozhan Wing Wah Tham. March, Abstract

Toxic Arbitrage * Thierry Foucault Roman Kozhan Wing Wah Tham. March, Abstract

High-Frequency Trading and Market Stability

Corporate Strategy, Conformism, and the Stock Market

News Trading and Speed

Every cloud has a silver lining Fast trading, microwave connectivity and trading costs

Illiquidity Contagion and Liquidity Crashes

Tick Size Constraints, Market Structure and Liquidity

REGULATING HFT GLOBAL PERSPECTIVE

Kiril Alampieski and Andrew Lepone 1

Do retail traders suffer from high frequency traders?

Liquidity Supply across Multiple Trading Venues

Tick Size Constraints, High Frequency Trading and Liquidity

Market Transparency Jens Dick-Nielsen

A Blessing or a Curse? The Impact of High Frequency Trading on Institutional Investors

High Frequency Trading and Welfare. Paul Milgrom and Xiaowei Yu

Intro A very stylized model that helps to think about HFT Dynamic Limit Order Market Traders choose endogenously between MO and LO Private gains from

Rise of the Machines: Algorithmic Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market. Alain Chaboud, Benjamin Chiquoine, Erik Hjalmarsson, and Clara Vega

Microstructure: Theory and Empirics

Market Microstructure Invariants

Response to ESMA s Call for Evidence: Periodic Auctions for Equity Instruments (ESMA )

High Frequency Market Making. The Evolving Structure of the U.S. Treasury Market Federal Reserve Bank of New York October 20-21, 2015

Potential Pilot Problems. Charles M. Jones Columbia Business School December 2014

Discrete or continuous trading?

Arbitrage Opportunities: a Blessing or a Curse?

Subsidizing Liquidity: The Impact of Make/Take Fees on Market Quality

High-Frequency Trade and Market Performance

Rise of the Machines: Algorithmic Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market

Toxic Arbitrage and Price Discovery

High-Frequency Trading in the Foreign Exchange Market: New Evil or Technological Progress? Ryan Perrin

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

Computer-based trading in the cross-section

Center for the Study of Financial Regulation

Foreign Exchange Markets with Last Look

Information and Inventories in High-Frequency Trading

MPhil F510 Topics in International Finance Petra M. Geraats Lent Course Overview

State Dependency of Monetary Policy: The Refinancing Channel

Market Liquidity. Theory, Evidence, and Policy OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS THIERRY FOUCAULT MARCO PAGANO AILSA ROELL

Who makes the market during stressed periods? HFTs vs. Dealers

Fast Aggressive Trading

Liquidity Creation as Volatility Risk

FINRA/CFP Conference on Market Fragmentation, Fragility and Fees September 17, 2014

Comments on SEBI s Discussion Paper Strengthening of the Regulatory framework for Algorithmic Trading & Co-location

Fast trading & prop trading

Algos gone wild: Are order cancellations in financial markets excessive?

High-Frequency Quoting: Measurement, Detection and Interpretation. Joel Hasbrouck

By George Jiang, Ingrid Lo, and Giorgio Valente

Liquidity Provision and Market Making by HFTs

Do High Frequency Traders Need to be Regulated? Evidence from Trading on Macroeconomic Announcements

A Theory of Endogenous Liquidity Cycles

High Frequency Trading in the US Treasury Market. Evidence around Macroeconomic News Announcements

High-Frequency Trading in the U.S. Treasury Market: Liquidity and Price. Efficiency around Macroeconomic News Announcements

Arbitrage is a trading strategy that exploits any profit opportunities arising from price differences.

High Frequency Trading Not covered on final exam, Spring 2018

Speed and Trading Behavior in an Order-Driven. Market: An Analysis on a High Quality Dataset

LECTURE 12: FRICTIONAL FINANCE

The High-Frequency Trading Arms Race: Frequent Batch Auctions as a Market Design Response

Contract Pricing and Market Efficiency: Can Peer-to-Peer Internet Credit Markets Improve Allocative Efficiency?

Index Arbitrage and Refresh Time Bias in Covariance Estimation

Belief Dispersion and Order Submission Strategies in the Foreign Exchange Market

Retrospective. Christopher G. Lamoureux. November 7, Experimental Microstructure: A. Retrospective. Introduction. Experimental.

Portfolio Management and Optimal Execution via Convex Optimization

Market Microstructure Invariants

Institutional Finance Financial Crises, Risk Management and Liquidity

Limited Attention and News Arrival in Limit Order Markets

News Trading and Speed

HIGH FREQUENCY TRADING AND ITS IMPACT ON MARKET QUALITY

Discussion of Corporate Bond Liquidity Before and After the Onset of the Subprime Crisis by J. Dick-Nielsen, P. Feldhütter, D.

Why Do Stock Exchanges Compete on Speed, and How?

Q7. Do you have additional comments on the draft guidelines on organisational requirements for investment firms electronic trading systems?

News Trading and Speed

FIN11. Trading and Market Microstructure. Autumn 2017

Speculative Betas. Harrison Hong and David Sraer Princeton University. September 30, 2012

Dynamic Market Making and Asset Pricing

How Fast Can You Trade? High Frequency Trading in Dynamic Limit Order Markets

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness

1 The Structure of the Market

High Frequency Trading What does it mean for Plan Sponsors? Zeno Consulting Group, LLC May 11-14, 2015

Capital Constraints, Counterparty Risk and Deviations from Covered Interest Rate Parity *

Price Impact, Funding Shock and Stock Ownership Structure

News Trading and Speed

Algorithmic and High-Frequency Trading

Algorithmic Trading under the Effects of Volume Order Imbalance

Can Financial Frictions Explain China s Current Account Puzzle: A Firm Level Analysis (Preliminary)

Data Abundance and Asset Price Informativeness

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Speed and Trading Behavior in an Order-Driven. Market: An Analysis on a High Quality Dataset

Lecture notes on risk management, public policy, and the financial system Credit risk models

Do regulatory hurdles on algorithmic trading work?

Large tick assets: implicit spread and optimal tick value

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

How Do Exchange Rate Regimes A ect the Corporate Sector s Incentives to Hedge Exchange Rate Risk? Herman Kamil. International Monetary Fund

The impact of arbitrage on market liquidity

The Real Business Cycle Model

Transcription:

Toxic Arbitrage Thierry Foucault Roman Kozhan HEC University of Warwick Wing Wah Tham Erasmus University Rotterdam National Bank of Belgium May 27-28, 2015

Arbitrage ˆ Arbitrage is a cornerstone of finance...

Arbitrage ˆ Arbitrage is a cornerstone of finance... ˆ To make a parrot into a learned financial economist, he only needs to learn the single word: arbitrage (Ross (1987, American Economic Review)

Arbitrage ˆ Arbitrage is a cornerstone of finance... ˆ To make a parrot into a learned financial economist, he only needs to learn the single word: arbitrage (Ross (1987, American Economic Review) ˆ Is arbitrage a good thing? What is the social value of arbitrage?

High frequency arbitrageurs: Heroes or Villains? ˆ SEC (2010): U.S. concept release on equity market structure. The Commission requests comment on arbitrage strategies and whether they benefit or harm the interests of long-term investors and market quality in general.[...] (Securities Exchange Commission, 2010)

High frequency arbitrageurs: Heroes or Villains? ˆ SEC (2010): U.S. concept release on equity market structure. The Commission requests comment on arbitrage strategies and whether they benefit or harm the interests of long-term investors and market quality in general.[...] (Securities Exchange Commission, 2010) ˆ High frequency arbitrageurs: those taking advantage of very short lived arbitrage opportunities, lasting fractions of seconds

High frequency arbitrageurs: Heroes or Villains? ˆ SEC (2010): U.S. concept release on equity market structure. The Commission requests comment on arbitrage strategies and whether they benefit or harm the interests of long-term investors and market quality in general.[...] (Securities Exchange Commission, 2010) ˆ High frequency arbitrageurs: those taking advantage of very short lived arbitrage opportunities, lasting fractions of seconds ˆ Is high frequency arbitrage a good thing?

For high frequency arbitrageurs...yes.. ˆ Budish et al.(2015, fthcoming QJE): estimate annual profits from cross-arbitrage in the ES-SPY ETFs to be $75 million. ˆ This is just one of hundredth of high frequency cross market arbitrage opportunities (see Table B.2 in Budish et al.(2015)).

For high frequency arbitrageurs...yes.. ˆ Budish et al.(2015, fthcoming QJE): estimate annual profits from cross-arbitrage in the ES-SPY ETFs to be $75 million. ˆ This is just one of hundredth of high frequency cross market arbitrage opportunities (see Table B.2 in Budish et al.(2015)). For others?

Social Value of Arbitrage? ˆ Arbitrage has benefits: 1. Arbitrageurs increase pricing efficiency: they quickly correct mispricings due to noise/liquidity traders. 2. Arbitrageurs provides liquidity (literature on limits to arbitrage). In correcting mispricing, they provide liquidity to noise/liquidity traders = Relaxing constraints should be desirable because arbitrageurs provide liquidity (Gromb and Vayanos (2012))

Social Value of Arbitrage? ˆ Arbitrage has benefits: 1. Arbitrageurs increase pricing efficiency: they quickly correct mispricings due to noise/liquidity traders. 2. Arbitrageurs provides liquidity (literature on limits to arbitrage). In correcting mispricing, they provide liquidity to noise/liquidity traders = Relaxing constraints should be desirable because arbitrageurs provide liquidity (Gromb and Vayanos (2012)) ˆ Our paper: Arbitrage has also costs: Some arbitrage opportunities (not all) raise adverse selection costs they make markets less liquid. ˆ Why?

Arbitrage 1: Stale Quotes.

Arbitrage 2: Transient Price Pressures.

Toxic Arbitrage Opportunities ˆ Arbitrage opportunities due to stale quotes are a source of adverse selection (picking off risk; cf Copeland and Galai (1983)) for liquidity suppliers They are toxic.

Toxic Arbitrage Opportunities ˆ Arbitrage opportunities due to stale quotes are a source of adverse selection (picking off risk; cf Copeland and Galai (1983)) for liquidity suppliers They are toxic. ˆ They make the market less liquid. ˆ They do not generate gains from trade: the arbitrageurs gains are his/her counterparties losses.

Predictions ˆ Composition effect: This is not the number of arbitrage opportunities that matters but the nature of these opportunities. Illiquidity is higher 1. On days in which toxic arbitrage opportunities are more frequent; 2. In pairs of related assets (ETFs/Underlying basket) in which toxic opportunities are more frequent.

Predictions ˆ Composition effect: This is not the number of arbitrage opportunities that matters but the nature of these opportunities. Illiquidity is higher 1. On days in which toxic arbitrage opportunities are more frequent; 2. In pairs of related assets (ETFs/Underlying basket) in which toxic opportunities are more frequent.

Predictions ˆ Composition effect: This is not the number of arbitrage opportunities that matters but the nature of these opportunities. Illiquidity is higher 1. On days in which toxic arbitrage opportunities are more frequent; 2. In pairs of related assets (ETFs/Underlying basket) in which toxic opportunities are more frequent. ˆ Speed effect : Illiquidity is higher when arbitrageurs become relatively faster in reacting to toxic arbitrage opportunities.

Contribution to the Policy Debate ˆ Budish, Cramton, and Shim (2014) s batch auctions proposal (see CFTC, Comments Letter): market correlations completely break down at high-frequency [...], which creates technical arbitrage opportunities available to whomever is fastest [...] the arms race [...] is socially wasteful, and it harms liquidity. The arms race and these negative effects are thus a consequence of flawed market design. As an alternative, we recommend frequent batch auctions [...] at frequent but discrete time intervals, such as once per second.

Contribution to the Policy Debate ˆ Budish, Cramton, and Shim (2014) s batch auctions proposal (see CFTC, Comments Letter): market correlations completely break down at high-frequency [...], which creates technical arbitrage opportunities available to whomever is fastest [...] the arms race [...] is socially wasteful, and it harms liquidity. The arms race and these negative effects are thus a consequence of flawed market design. As an alternative, we recommend frequent batch auctions [...] at frequent but discrete time intervals, such as once per second. ˆ Randomized execution of market orders: 10 milliseconds delay would encourage the liquidity providers to do so because [...]they will have time to adjust their quotes following sudden events (in Interactive Brokers Group Proposal to address High Frequency Trading ),

Contribution to the Policy Debate ˆ However, no empirical analysis of the effect of high speed arbitrage on liquidity : 1. We are not sure the problem exists: Our analysis shows that it does but suggests that it could be time and pair specific because the composition of arbitrage opportunities varies over time and across pairs. 2. We have no idea of the counterfactual: By how much would liquidity increase if (a) one could suppress all toxic arbitrage opportunities or (b) one could reduce the likelihood that an arbitrageur is able to exploit a toxic arbitrage opportunity by x%?

Theory ˆ Similar to Foucault, Röell and Sandas (2003, RFS) with two assets X and Y. ˆ Payoffs θ X = σ θ Y at t=2. (1 share of X = σ shares of Y ) ˆ 3 types of participants 1. Two risk neutral market makers: One specialized in asset X and one specialized in asset Y. They set bid-ask quotes in each asset. 2. One risk neutral arbitrageur 3. Liquidity traders who buy or sell asset X or Y with equal probabilities.

Market Makers Quotes ˆ Market makers: at t = 1, they simultaneously choose their bid-ask spreads: S X and S Y and post quotes for the asset: Ask Price in asset j : a j = m j + S j 2 Bid Price in asset j : b j = m j S j 2 ˆ m j = Midquote for asset j = market maker j s valuation for the asset. ˆ m X = E (θ X ) = Unconditional expected payoff of the asset.

Market-Maker Y s Valuation

Case 1: Stale Quotes.

Case 2: Transient Price Pressures.

Arbitrageur s Payoff ˆ The arbitrage portfolio is: (a) Short σ shares of Y -Long one share of X or (b) Long σ shares of Y -Short one share of X. 1. Cost of (a): a X σb Y = m X σm Y + (S X + σs Y )/2 = σjump + (S X + σs Y )/2 ˆ 2. Cost of (b): σa Y b X = σm Y m X + S X /2 + σs Y /2 = +σjump + (S X + σs Y )/2 If σjump > (S X + σs Y )/2, the arbitrageur s optimal arbitrage strategy is: Portfolio (a) if Jump > 0 and Portfolio (b) If Jump < 0. ˆ Here Jump = 1/2

Traders payoffs Termination Liq. trader arrives (with prob 1 α) Traders Payoffs A toxic arbitrage happens (with prob αϕ) A non toxic arbitrage happens (with prob α(1 ϕ)) Liq. trader trades Arb. trades (with prob π) X cancels (with prob 1 π) Arb. trades (with prob 1) X cancels (with prob 0) Arb s expected payoff 0 X s expected payoff Y s expected payoff Aggregate expected payoff (Arbs + Market Makers) σ S X σs Y 2 0 S X4 (σ S X 2 ) 0 σs Y 4 σs Y 2 0 σ S X σs Y 2 0 S X2 0 σs Y 2 0 S X +σs Y 4 0 0 σ 2 0

The Arbitrage Race ˆ Traders choose their average speed of reaction ( latency ) to arbitrage opportunities (i.e., λ 1 or γ 1 ) but being faster is costly: an increase in speed by one unit cost c j to trader j {X, Arb}. ˆ π = γ γ+λ = A measure of arbitrageurs relative speed. ˆ Expected duration of an arbitrage opportunity: E (D) = ϕ(e (Min{D a, D X })) + (1 ϕ)e (D a ) = ϕ λ + γ (1 ϕ) +. γ

Equilibrium ˆ We solve for equilibrium spreads, speeds, duration of arbitrage opporunities and π in two steps: 1. For given bid-ask spreads, Nash equilibrium in speeds: traders choose the speed that maximizes their expected profit: 1.1 In equilibrium traders speed decrease with bid-ask spreads Arbitrage opportunities last longer when spreads are larger. 2. Then, we solve for zero profit spreads.

Equilibrium ˆ Let ρ = cx = Relative Cost of Speed: higher ρ means c Arb the cost of speed becomes relatively smaller for arbitrageurs. ˆ In equilibrium: Relative Speed : π = γ /(λ + γ ) = ρ 1 + ρ

Equilibrium ˆ Let ρ = cx = Relative Cost of Speed: higher ρ means c Arb the cost of speed becomes relatively smaller for arbitrageurs. ˆ In equilibrium: Relative Speed : π = γ /(λ + γ ) = ρ 1 + ρ Illiquidity : S X = ϕ π α(2 π )σ απ (2 π )σ + (1 α).

Equilibrium ˆ Let ρ = cx = Relative Cost of Speed: higher ρ means c Arb the cost of speed becomes relatively smaller for arbitrageurs. ˆ In equilibrium: Relative Speed : π = γ /(λ + γ ) = ρ 1 + ρ Illiquidity : S X = ϕ π α(2 π )σ απ (2 π )σ + (1 α). Duration: E (D) = (1 + ρ ϕ) γ (ϕ, ρ, SX )(1 + ρ) }{{} Arb s Speed

Testable implications ˆ Imp.1a (Composition effect): An increase in the fraction of arbitrage opportunities that are toxic (ϕ) causes an increase in illiquidity.

Testable implications ˆ Imp.1a (Composition effect): An increase in the fraction of arbitrage opportunities that are toxic (ϕ) causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.1b (Speed effect): An increase in arbitrageurs speed relative to dealers speed (π) causes an increase in illiquidity.

Testable implications ˆ Imp.1a (Composition effect): An increase in the fraction of arbitrage opportunities that are toxic (ϕ) causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.1b (Speed effect): An increase in arbitrageurs speed relative to dealers speed (π) causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.2: A decrease in arbitrageurs relative cost of speed (an increase in ρ) triggers an increase in arbitrageurs relative speed (π) and, through this channel, causes an increase in illiquidity.

Testable implications ˆ Imp.1a (Composition effect): An increase in the fraction of arbitrage opportunities that are toxic (ϕ) causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.1b (Speed effect): An increase in arbitrageurs speed relative to dealers speed (π) causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.2: A decrease in arbitrageurs relative cost of speed (an increase in ρ) triggers an increase in arbitrageurs relative speed (π) and, through this channel, causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.3: An increase in the fraction of arbitrage opportunities that are toxic (ϕ) causes a reduction in the duration of arbitrage opportunities.

Testable implications ˆ Imp.1a (Composition effect): An increase in the fraction of arbitrage opportunities that are toxic (ϕ) causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.1b (Speed effect): An increase in arbitrageurs speed relative to dealers speed (π) causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.2: A decrease in arbitrageurs relative cost of speed (an increase in ρ) triggers an increase in arbitrageurs relative speed (π) and, through this channel, causes an increase in illiquidity. ˆ Imp.3: An increase in the fraction of arbitrage opportunities that are toxic (ϕ) causes a reduction in the duration of arbitrage opportunities. ˆ Imp.4: A decrease in arbitrageurs relative cost of speed (an increase in ρ) reduces the duration of arbitrage opportunities. Faster arbitrageurs reactions to toxic arbitrage opportunities make the market less liquid but always more price efficient.

Numerical Example Bid Ask Spread bps 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Likelihoodtoxic arbitrage φ 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Arbitrageur's relative speed Bid Ask Spread bps 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 Ρ c m c a ArbitrageDuration sd 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Likelihoodtoxic arbitrage φ ArbitrageDuration sd 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.00 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.10 Arbitrageur's Cost of Speed

Data ˆ Tick-by-tick data (2003-2004) from Reuters D-3000: an interdealer limit order book in the FX market ˆ Three currency pairs: $/e, $/ and e/ ˆ All orders: limit, market, cancellations etc ˆ Time-stamped accuracy at the one-hundredth of a second

Triangular Arbitrage

Triangular arbitrage opportunities ˆ Two ways to buy euros with dollar: 1. Direct: Buy e1 at A $/e, the ask price in dollar for euros. Cost: A $/e 2. Indirect: Buy A /e units of pounds at A $/ and then e1 at A /e in the euro/sterling market. Cost: Â $/e =A /e A $/. ˆ Two ways to sell euros against dollar: 1. Direct: Sell e1 at B $/e, the bid price in dollar for euros. Revenue: B $/e 2. Indirect: Sell e1 at B /e in the euro/sterling market and then sell B /e units of pounds at B $/. Revenue: B$/e =B /e B $/.

Triangular Arbitrage Opportunities ˆ A triangular arbitrage opportunity exists if: A $/e < OR B $/e  $/e < B $/e ˆ Practically, we just focus on arbitrage opportunities that secure a profit before costs of at least 1bps. ˆ # triangular arbitrage opportunities in sample: 37,689 over two years.

Triangular Arbitrage Opportunities ˆ Similar in nature to those exploited by high speed arbitrageurs, i.e.: 1. Short-lived (last for about 1 second and sometimes much less) 2. Almost riskless 3. Deliver a very small profit per opportunity 4. Winner takes it all flavor ˆ All opportunities take place within the same trading platform: Synchronisation of time stamps across markets is not an issue (a major hurdle for empirical studies of high frequency arbitrage).

Toxic vs. Non-Toxic Arbitrage opportunities: Classification Panel A: Toxic arbitrage opportunities (permanent shifts in prices) Panel B: Non-toxic arbitrage opportunities (price reversals) ˆ # toxic triangular arbitrages in sample: 15,908.

Toxic and Non Toxic Arbitrage Opportunities: Time-Series

Arbitrage opportunities breakdown

Proxies for Dealers Exposure to Toxic Arbitrage Trades ˆϕ t = # Toxic arbitrage opportunities on day t. # Arbitrage opportunities on day t ˆ π t = # Toxic opportunities closed by a trade on day t # Toxic Arbitrage opportunities on day t

Toxic vs. Non-Toxic Arbitrage opportunities Toxic Non Toxic Daily measures Median SD Median SD Duration (msd) 890 0.30 510 0.2 Nbr Arb 32 20 45 38 ˆϕ(%) 41.5 10 59 11 Arb Size (bps) 3.53 0.75 3.53 0.84 Profit (bps) 1.42 0.27 1.61 0.57 π (%) 74 11 80 8.2 ˆ Profit per opportunity are small but the total daily profit on triangular arbitrages (about $5,000) is of the order of magnitude of that found for HFTs on Nasdaq (see Brogaard, Hendershott and Riordan (2012)). ˆ π for toxic and non toxic arbitrage opportunities have a zero correlation (0.08) = do not capture the same phenomenon.

Liquidity measures ˆ Note: Bid-ask spreads are expressed in pips: 1 pip = 1 bps. Minimum trade size = 1 million of the base currency in each pair.

Main Test ˆ We estimate the following regression for the three currencies in our sample: Ill it = α i + β t + b 1 πˆ t + b 2 ϕˆ t + b 3 Arbsize t + b 4 ˆα it + b 5 Vol it + + b 6 Trsize it + b 7 #Orders it + b 8 Illiq EBS it + ɛ it Predictions: b 1 > 0 and b 2 > 0. ˆ Control variables: daily average arbitrage size (σ in the model), daily ratio of the number of arbitrage opportunities to number of trades (α), daily realized volatility, daily average trade size in millions, daily number of orders, illiquidity on EBS platform

IV Approach ˆ Reverse Causality Problem: Illiquidity also affects π: Arbitrageurs have less incentive to be fast when trading costs are large. ˆ Instrument: the introduction of AutoQuote (API) by Reuters D-3000 in July 2003. ˆ AutoQuote API (Application Programming Interface): Enable traders using Reuters D-3000 to automate order entry onset of algo trading on Reuters. ˆ Increase in traders speed. Should affect π without directly affecting illiquidity.

Findings spread espread slope 1 st stage 2 nd stage 1 st stage 2 nd stage 1 st stage 2 nd stage AD 0.040 (4.09) 0.042 (4.12) 0.040 (4.10) ˆπ 7.934 (3.91) 3.443 (3.70) 4.526 (3.96) ˆϕ -0.011 (-0.31) 0.691 (2.29) -0.011 (-0.31) 0.511 (3.68) -0.010 (-0.28) 0.445 (2.61) ˆσ -0.011 (-2.14) 0.238 (4.93) -0.012 (-2.17) 0.221 (9.94) -0.011 (-2.11) 0.120 (4.39) vol -0.009 (-0.75) 0.374 (3.72) -0.009 (-0.77) 0.401 (8.65) -0.009 (-0.76) 0.220 (3.87) trsize 0.002 (0.66) -0.128 (-0.30) 0.001 (0.84) -0.196 (-0.98) 0.001 (0.76) -0.265 (-1.09) nrorders 0.014 (0.27) -0.004 (-0.77) 0.012 (0.22) -0.006 (-2.62) 0.016 (0.30) -0.003 (-1.01) illiq EBS -0.003 (-3.88) 0.021 (0.79) -0.003 (-3.85) -0.002 (-0.43) -0.003 (-3.89) 0.001 (0.08) Adj.R 2 2.34% 34.40% 2.34% 62.18% 2.35% 25.56% Fstat 16.7 16.9 16.8 Currency pair FE Month dummies YES YES YES YES YES YES

Economic size of the effects ˆ A 1% increase in the likelihood that a toxic arbitrage terminates with an arbitrageur s trade ( ˆπ) raises bid-ask spread by about 4% (0.08bps) ˆ This effect translates in a quite large increase in trading costs given the trading volume for the currencies in our sample (average trade size of about 1.8 mio with about 2,500 trades per day). We estimate that the increase in trading costs due to a 1% increase in: ˆ ˆπ is $161,296 (about $40 mio per year) ˆ ˆϕ is $14,047 (the daily standard deviation of ˆϕ is 10%)

Arbitrage and Pricing Efficiency (Implications 3 and 4) Dep.Var: log(duration Arb.) Toxic AD -0.068 (-3.04) -0.057 (-2.93) vol -0.084 (-3.15) -0.105 (-4.53) ˆϕ -0.248 (-2.95) 0.050 (0.68) ˆσ 0.070 (6.59) 0.085 (9.22) trsize 0.022 (0.18) 0.015 (0.14) nrorders -0.012 (-7.29) -0.010 (-7.40) Adj.R 2 21.24% 33.33% All ˆ The introduction of Autoquote API ( AD ) reduces by about 6.8% the duration of toxic arbitrage opportunities (i.e., by about 62 milliseconds; the average duration is 890 milliseconds).

Conclusions 1/2 ˆ Arbitrage and liquidity: 1. The mix of arbitrage opportunities matters: more arbitrage opportunities due asynchronous price adjustments are associated with less liquidity. 2. Arbitrageurs speed of reaction matters: Faster arbitrageurs reaction to toxic opportunities lower liquidity. ˆ Future Work: Do benefits of high speed arbitrageurs offset adverse selection costs? 1. Faster price discovery? Do we care about prices being right 60 ms faster? Why? 2. Faster response to transient liquidity shocks? Maybe...needs to be modeled and quantified, however.

Conclusions 2/2 ˆ How to solve the problem? Lower arbitrageurs relative speed π: 1. Batch auctions 2. Random delay to the execution of market orders. ˆ Calibration of regulatory intervention: should depend on the composition of arbitrage opportunities. Unlikely to be the same across all asset pairs! ˆ Need to look more systematically at the composition of arbitrage opportunities across asset pairs (ETFs, options, futures etc.