Chapter 12 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Similar documents
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM. Wanna Download D. Salvatore, International Economics for free? Gr8, visit now jblogger2016.wordpress.com

2. Equlibrium and Efficiency

Review of Production Theory: Chapter 2 1

Chapter 11: General Competitive Equilibrium

GE in production economies

Theoretical Tools of Public Finance. 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Chapter 2 Equilibrium and Efficiency

PAPER NO.1 : MICROECONOMICS ANALYSIS MODULE NO.6 : INDIFFERENCE CURVES

The Robinson Crusoe model; the Edgeworth Box in Consumption and Factor allocation

ECON Micro Foundations

Tools of normative analysis

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Chapter 3: Model of Consumer Behavior

Math: Deriving supply and demand curves

Topic 3: The Standard Theory of Trade. Increasing opportunity costs. Community indifference curves.

3 General Equilibrium in a Competitive Market

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

Chapter 3. A Consumer s Constrained Choice

Trade on Markets. Both consumers' initial endowments are represented bythesamepointintheedgeworthbox,since

Chapter 3 Introduction to the General Equilibrium and to Welfare Economics

Understand general-equilibrium relationships, such as the relationship between barriers to trade, and the domestic distribution of income.

Chapter Thirty. Production

Lecture 15 - General Equilibrium with Production

Utility Maximization and Choice

Chapter 2 Commodity Trade

A Closed Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Intro to Economic analysis

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Consumption, Investment and the Fisher Separation Principle

General Equilibrium and Economic Welfare

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 2

MODULE No. : 9 : Ordinal Utility Approach

Chapter 31: Exchange

Chapter 8 COST FUNCTIONS. Copyright 2005 by South-western, a division of Thomson learning. All rights reserved.

1. Suppose a production process is described by a Cobb-Douglas production function f(v 1, v 2 ) = v 1 1/2 v 2 3/2.

Demand Side: Community Indifference Curve (CIC) Shows various combinations of two goods with equivalent welfare

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

Taxation and Efficiency : (a) : The Expenditure Function

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

Marginal Utility, Utils Total Utility, Utils

The objectives of the producer

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Exchange. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory. Boston College. M. Utku Ünver Micro Theory (BC) Exchange 1 / 23

Chapter 10 THE PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM COMPETITIVE MODEL. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Graphs Details Math Examples Using data Tax example. Decision. Intermediate Micro. Lecture 5. Chapter 5 of Varian

If Tom's utility function is given by U(F, S) = FS, graph the indifference curves that correspond to 1, 2, 3, and 4 utils, respectively.

Microeconomics IV. First Semster, Course

Firm s demand for the input. Supply of the input = price of the input.

Transport Costs and North-South Trade

Preferences and Utility

Chapter 2: Gains from Trade. August 14, 2008

Faculty: Sunil Kumar

File: Ch03; Chapter 3: The Standard Theory of International Trade

Gains from Trade. Rahul Giri

ECON 340/ Zenginobuz Fall 2011 STUDY QUESTIONS FOR THE FINAL. x y z w u A u B

Microeconomics Review in a Two Good World

Chapter 3 PREFERENCES AND UTILITY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Economics 370 Microeconomic Theory Problem Set 5 Answer Key

Chapter 6 DEMAND RELATIONSHIPS AMONG GOODS. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY FALL 2006 ECONOMICS 300/012 Midterm II November 9, 2006

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

Consumer Theory. The consumer s problem: budget set, interior and corner solutions.

Lecture 4 - Utility Maximization

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

PRODUCTION COSTS. Econ 311 Microeconomics 1 Lecture Material Prepared by Dr. Emmanuel Codjoe

ECON 301: General Equilibrium V (Public Goods) 1. Intermediate Microeconomics II, ECON 301. General Equilibrium V: Public Goods

Problem Set 5 Answers. A grocery shop is owned by Mr. Moore and has the following statement of revenues and costs:

This appendix discusses two extensions of the cost concepts developed in Chapter 10.

Problem Set 1 Answer Key. I. Short Problems 1. Check whether the following three functions represent the same underlying preferences

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Introductory to Microeconomic Theory [08/29/12] Karen Tsai

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October Q1. Find the equation of the production possibility curve in the following 2 good, 2 input

Cost Functions. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Final Term Papers. Fall 2009 (Session 03a) ECO401. (Group is not responsible for any solved content) Subscribe to VU SMS Alert Service

Intermediate microeconomics. Lecture 1: Introduction and Consumer Theory Varian, chapters 1-5

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Economics 4315/7315: Public Economics

The Standard Theory of International Trade

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Assignment 1. Multiple-Choice Questions. To answer each question correctly, you have to choose the best answer from the given four choices.

ASHORTCOURSEIN INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS WITH CALCULUS. allan

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

Lecture 2: Marginal Functions, Average Functions, Elasticity, the Marginal Principle, and

Chapter 9 THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

A PRODUCER OPTIMUM. Lecture 7 Producer Behavior

ECON 311 Winter Quarter, 2010 NAME: KEY Prof. Hamilton

False_ The average revenue of a firm can be increasing in the firm s output.

Introduction to the Gains from Trade 1

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

FINANCE THEORY: Intertemporal. and Optimal Firm Investment Decisions. Eric Zivot Econ 422 Summer R.W.Parks/E. Zivot ECON 422:Fisher 1.

Transcription:

Chapter 12 GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM AND WELFARE Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved. 1

Perfectly Competitive Price System We will assume that all markets are perfectly competitive there is some large number of homogeneous goods in the economy both consumption goods and factors of production each good has an equilibrium price there are no transaction or transportation costs individuals and firms have perfect information 2

Law of One Price A homogeneous good trades at the same price no matter who buys it or who sells it if one good traded at two different prices, demanders would rush to buy the good where it was cheaper and firms would try to sell their output where the price was higher these actions would tend to equalize the price of the good 3

Assumptions of Perfect Competition There are a large number of people buying any one good each person takes all prices as given and seeks to maximize utility given his budget constraint There are a large number of firms producing each good each firm takes all prices as given and attempts to maximize profits 4

General Equilibrium Assume that there are only two goods, x and y All individuals are assumed to have identical preferences represented by an indifference map The production possibility curve can be used to show how outputs and inputs are related 5

Edgeworth Box Diagram Construction of the production possibility curve for x and y starts with the assumption that the amounts of k and l are fixed An Edgeworth box shows every possible way the existing k and l might be used to produce x and y any point in the box represents a fully employed allocation of the available resources to x and y 6

Edgeworth Box Diagram Labor in y production Labor for x Labor for y O y Capital in y production Total Capital Capital in x production O x Labor in x production Total Labor A Capital for y Capital for x 7

Edgeworth Box Diagram Many of the allocations in the Edgeworth box are technically inefficient it is possible to produce more x and more y by shifting capital and labor around We will assume that competitive markets will not exhibit inefficient input choices We want to find the efficient allocations they illustrate the actual production outcomes 8

Edgeworth Box Diagram We will use isoquant maps for the two goods the isoquant map for good x uses O x as the origin the isoquant map for good y uses O y as the origin The efficient allocations will occur where the isoquants are tangent to one another 9

Edgeworth Box Diagram Point A is inefficient because, by moving along y 1, we can increase x from x 1 to x 2 while holding y constant O y y 1 Total Capital y 2 A x 1 x 2 O x Total Labor 10

Edgeworth Box Diagram We could also increase y from y 1 to y 2 while holding x constant by moving along x 1 O y y 1 Total Capital y 2 A x 1 x 2 O x Total Labor 11

Edgeworth Box Diagram At each efficient point, the RTS (of k for l) is equal in both x and y production O y y 1 p 4 Total Capital y 3 y 2 p 2 p 3 x 4 y 4 p 1 x 3 x 2 x 1 O x Total Labor 12

Production Possibility Frontier The locus of efficient points shows the maximum output of y that can be produced for any level of x we can use this information to construct a production possibility frontier shows the alternative outputs of x and y that can be produced with the fixed capital and labor inputs that are employed efficiently 13

Production Possibility Frontier Quantity of y O x p 1 Each efficient point of production becomes a point on the production possibility frontier y 4 y 3 y 2 p 2 p 3 The negative of the slope of the production possibility frontier is the rate of product transformation (RPT) y 1 p 4 x 1 x 2 x 3 x 4 O y Quantity of x 14

Rate of Product Transformation The rate of product transformation (RPT) between two outputs is the negative of the slope of the production possibility frontier RPT (of x for y) = slope of production possibility frontier RPT (of x for y ) = dy dx (along O O x y ) 15

Rate of Product Transformation The rate of product transformation shows how x can be technically traded for y while continuing to keep the available productive inputs efficiently employed 16

Shape of the Production Possibility Frontier The production possibility frontier shown earlier exhibited an increasing RPT this concave shape will characterize most production situations RPT is equal to the ratio of MC x to MC y 17

Shape of the Production Possibility Frontier Suppose that the costs of any output combination are C(x,y) along the production possibility frontier, C(x,y) is constant We can write the total differential of the cost function as C C dc = dx + dy x y = 0 18

Shape of the Production Possibility Frontier Rewriting, we get RPT dy C / x = (along OxOy ) = dx C / y = MC MC x y The RPT is a measure of the relative marginal costs of the two goods 19

Shape of the Production Possibility Frontier As production of x rises and production of y falls, the ratio of MC x to MC y rises this occurs if both goods are produced under diminishing returns increasing the production of x raises MC x, while reducing the production of y lowers MC y this could also occur if some inputs were more suited for x production than for y production 20

Shape of the Production Possibility Frontier But we have assumed that inputs are homogeneous We need an explanation that allows homogeneous inputs and constant returns to scale The production possibility frontier will be concave if goods x and y use inputs in different proportions 21

Opportunity Cost The production possibility frontier demonstrates that there are many possible efficient combinations of two goods Producing more of one good necessitates lowering the production of the other good this is what economists mean by opportunity cost 22

Opportunity Cost The opportunity cost of one more unit of x is the reduction in y that this entails Thus, the opportunity cost is best measured as the RPT (of x for y) at the prevailing point on the production possibility frontier this opportunity cost rises as more x is produced 23

Concavity of the Production Possibility Frontier Suppose that the production of x and y depends only on labor and the production functions are x = f l = l 0.5 ( x ) x y = f 0.5 ( l y ) = ly If labor supply is fixed at 100, then l x + l y = 100 The production possibility frontier is x 2 + y 2 = 100 for x,y 0 24

Concavity of the Production Possibility Frontier The RPT can be calculated by taking the total differential: dy ( 2x) 2xdx + 2ydy = 0 or RPT = = = dx 2y The slope of the production possibility frontier increases as x output increases the frontier is concave x y 25

Determination of Equilibrium Prices We can use the production possibility frontier along with a set of indifference curves to show how equilibrium prices are determined the indifference curves represent individuals preferences for the two goods 26

Determination of Equilibrium Prices Quantity of y If the prices of x and y are p x and p y, society s budget constraint is C C Output will be x 1, y 1 y 1 Individuals will demand x 1, y 1 y 1 U 2 U 3 C U 1 slope = p p y x x 1 x 1 Quantity of x 27

Determination of Equilibrium Prices Quantity of y There is excess demand for x and excess supply of y y 1 C The price of x will rise and the price of y will fall excess supply y 1 U 2 U 3 C U 1 slope = p p y x x x 1 Quantity of x 28 1 excess demand

Determination of Equilibrium Prices Quantity of y y 1 y 1 * y 1 C C* The equilibrium prices will be p x * and p y * The equilibrium output will be x 1 * and y 1 * U 2 U 3 C x 1 x 1 * U 1 C* x 1 p* x slope = p* y p slope = p Quantity of x y x 29

Comparative Statics Analysis The equilibrium price ratio will tend to persist until either preferences or production technologies change If preferences were to shift toward good x, p x /p y would rise and more x and less y would be produced we would move in a clockwise direction along the production possibility frontier 30

Comparative Statics Analysis Technical progress in the production of good x will shift the production possibility curve outward this will lower the relative price of x more x will be consumed if x is a normal good the effect on y is ambiguous 31

Technical Progress in the Production of x Quantity of y Technical progress in the production of x will shift the production possibility curve out The relative price of x will fall More x will be consumed U 2 U 3 U 1 x 1 * x 2 * Quantity of x 32

General Equilibrium Pricing Suppose that the production possibility frontier can be represented by x 2 + y 2 = 100 Suppose also that the community s preferences can be represented by U(x,y) = x 0.5 y 0.5 33

General Equilibrium Pricing Profit-maximizing firms will equate RPT and the ratio of p x /p y x RPT = = y p p x y Utility maximization requires that y MRS = = x p p x y 34

General Equilibrium Pricing Equilibrium requires that firms and individuals face the same price ratio RPT = x y = p p y y x x = = MRS or x* = y* 35

The Corn Laws Debate High tariffs on grain imports were imposed by the British government after the Napoleonic wars Economists debated the effects of these corn laws between 1829 and 1845 what effect would the elimination of these tariffs have on factor prices? 36

The Corn Laws Debate Quantity of manufactured goods (y) If the corn laws completely prevented trade, output would be x 0 and y 0 The equilibrium prices will be p x * and p y * y 0 x 0 U 1 U 2 p* x slope = p* y Quantity of Grain (x) 37

The Corn Laws Debate Quantity of manufactured goods (y) y 1 Removal of the corn laws will change the prices to p x and p y Output will be x 1 and y 1 Individuals will demand x 1 and y 1 y 0 y 1 U 1 U 2 slope = px ' p ' y x 1 x 0 x 1 Quantity of Grain (x) 38

The Corn Laws Debate Quantity of manufactured goods (y) exports of goods y 1 y 0 Grain imports will be x 1 x 1 These imports will be financed by the export of manufactured goods equal to y 1 y 1 y 1 U 1 U 2 slope = px ' p ' y x 1 x 0 x 1 Quantity of Grain (x) imports of grain 39

The Corn Laws Debate We can use an Edgeworth box diagram to see the effects of tariff reduction on the use of labor and capital If the corn laws were repealed, there would be an increase in the production of manufactured goods and a decline in the production of grain 40

The Corn Laws Debate A repeal of the corn laws would result in a movement from p 3 to p 1 where more y and less x is produced O y y 1 p 4 Total Capital y 3 y 2 p 2 p 3 x 4 y 4 p 1 x 3 x 2 x 1 O x Total Labor 41

The Corn Laws Debate If we assume that grain production is relatively capital intensive, the movement from p 3 to p 1 causes the ratio of k to l to rise in both industries the relative price of capital will fall the relative price of labor will rise The repeal of the corn laws will be harmful to capital owners and helpful to laborers 42

Political Support for Trade Policies Trade policies may affect the relative incomes of various factors of production In the United States, exports tend to be intensive in their use of skilled labor whereas imports tend to be intensive in their use of unskilled labor free trade policies will result in rising relative wages for skilled workers and in falling relative wages for unskilled workers 43

Existence of General Equilibrium Prices Beginning with 19th century investigations by Leon Walras, economists have examined whether there exists a set of prices that equilibrates all markets simultaneously if this set of prices exists, how can it be found? 44

Existence of General Equilibrium Prices Suppose that there are n goods in fixed supply in this economy let S i (i =1,,n) be the total supply of good i available let p i (i =1, n) be the price of good i The total demand for good i depends on all prices D i (p 1,,p n ) for i =1,,n 45

Existence of General Equilibrium Prices We will write this demand function as dependent on the whole set of prices (P) D i (P) Walras problem: Does there exist an equilibrium set of prices such that D i (P*) = S i for all values of i? 46

Excess Demand ( 超额需求 ) Functions The excess demand function for any good i at any set of prices (P) is defined to be ED i (P) = D i (P) S i This means that the equilibrium condition can be rewritten as ED i (P*) = D i (P*) S i = 0 47

Excess Demand Functions Demand functions are homogeneous of degree zero this implies that we can only establish equilibrium relative prices in a Walrasiantype model Walras also assumed that demand functions are continuous small changes in price lead to small changes in quantity demanded 48

Walras Law A final observation that Walras made was that the n excess demand equations are not independent of one another Walras law shows that the total value of excess demand is zero at any set of prices n i = 1 P i ED i ( P) = 0 49

Walras Law Walras law holds for any set of prices (not just equilibrium prices) There can be neither excess demand for all goods together nor excess supply 50

Walras Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices The market equilibrium conditions provide (n-1) independent equations in (n-1) unknown relative prices can we solve the system for an equilibrium condition? the equations are not necessarily linear all prices must be nonnegative To attack these difficulties, Walras set up a complicated proof 51

Walras Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices Start with an arbitrary set of prices Holding the other n-1 prices constant, find the equilibrium price for good 1 (p 1 ) Holding p 1 and the other n-2 prices constant, solve for the equilibrium price of good 2 (p 2 ) in changing p 2 from its initial position to p 2, the price calculated for good 1 does not need to remain an equilibrium price 52

Walras Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices Using the provisional prices p 1 and p 2, solve for p 3 proceed in this way until an entire set of provisional relative prices has been found In the 2 nd iteration of Walras proof, p 2,,p n are held constant while a new equilibrium price is calculated for good 1 proceed in this way until an entire new set of prices is found 53

Walras Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices The importance of Walras proof is its ability to demonstrate the simultaneous nature of the problem of finding equilibrium prices Because it is cumbersome, it is not generally used today More recent work uses some relatively simple tools from advanced mathematics 54

Brouwer s Fixed-Point Theorem Any continuous mapping [F(X)] of a closed, bounded, convex set into itself has at least one fixed point (X*) such that F(X*) = X* 55

Brouwer s Fixed-Point Theorem f (X) 1 Suppose that f(x) is a continuous function defined on the interval [0,1] and that f(x) takes on the values also on the interval [0,1] Any continuous function must cross the 45 line f (X*) This point of crossing is a fixed point because f maps this point (X*) into itself 45 0 X* 1 x 56

Brouwer s Fixed-Point Theorem A mapping is a rule that associates the points in one set with points in another set let X be a point for which a mapping (F) is defined the mapping associates X with some point Y = F(X) if a mapping is defined over a subset of n- dimensional space (S), and if every point in S is associated (by the rule F) with some other point in S, the mapping is said to map S into itself 57

Brouwer s Fixed-Point Theorem A mapping is continuous if points that are close to each other are mapped into other points that are close to each other The Brouwer fixed-point theorem considers mappings defined on certain kinds of sets closed (they contain their boundaries) bounded (none of their dimensions is infinitely large) convex (they have no holes in them) 58

Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices Because only relative prices matter, it is convenient to assume that prices have been defined so that the sum of all prices is equal to 1 Thus, for any arbitrary set of prices (p 1,,p n ), we can use normalized prices of the form p i ' = n p i = 1 i p i 59

Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices These new prices will retain their original relative values and will sum to 1 p i = p j ' ' p p i j These new prices will sum to 1 n i = 1 p i ' = 1 60

Proof of the Existence of Equilibrium Prices We will assume that the feasible set of prices (S) is composed of all nonnegative numbers that sum to 1 S is the set to which we will apply Brouwer s theorem S is closed, bounded, and convex we will need to define a continuous mapping of S into itself 61

Free Goods Equilibrium does not really require that excess demand be zero for every market Goods may exist for which the markets are in equilibrium where supply exceeds demand (negative excess demand) it is necessary for the prices of these goods to be equal to zero free goods 62

Free Goods The equilibrium conditions are ED i (P*) = 0 for p i * > 0 ED i (P*) 0 for p i * = 0 Note that this set of equilibrium prices continues to obey Walras law 63

Mapping the Set of Prices Into Itself In order to achieve equilibrium, prices of goods in excess demand should be raised, whereas those in excess supply should have their prices lowered 64

Mapping the Set of Prices Into Itself We define the mapping F(P) for any normalized set of prices (P), such that the ith component of F(P) is given by F i (P) = p i + ED i (P) The mapping performs the necessary task of appropriately raising or lowering prices 65

Mapping the Set of Prices Into Itself Two problems exist with this mapping First, nothing ensures that the prices will be nonnegative the mapping must be redefined to be F i (P) = Max [p i + ED i (P),0] the new prices defined by the mapping must be positive or zero 66

Mapping the Set of Prices Into Itself Second, the recalculated prices are not necessarily normalized they will not sum to 1 it will be simple to normalize such that n i = 1 F i ( P) = 1 we will assume that this normalization has been done 67

Application of Brouwer s Theorem Thus, F satisfies the conditions of the Brouwer fixed-point theorem it is a continuous mapping of the set S into itself There exists a point (P*) that is mapped into itself For this point, p i * = Max [p i * + ED i (P*),0] for all i 68

Application of Brouwer s Theorem This says that P* is an equilibrium set of prices for p i * > 0, p i * = p i * + ED i (P*) ED i (P*) = 0 For p i * = 0, p i * + ED i (P*) 0 ED i (P*) 0 69

A General Equilibrium with Three Goods The economy of Oz is composed only of three precious metals: (1) silver, (2) gold, and (3) platinum there are 10 (thousand) ounces of each metal available The demands for gold and platinum are p2 p3 p2 p3 D2 = 2 + + 11 D3 = 2 + 18 p p p p 1 1 1 1 70

A General Equilibrium with Three Goods Equilibrium in the gold and platinum markets requires that demand equal supply in both markets simultaneously 2 p2 p3 + + 11= p p 1 1 10 p2 p3 2 + 18 = p p 1 1 10 71

A General Equilibrium with Three Goods This system of simultaneous equations can be solved as p 2 /p 1 = 2 p 3 /p 1 = 3 In equilibrium: gold will have a price twice that of silver platinum will have a price three times that of silver the price of platinum will be 1.5 times that of gold 72

73 A General Equilibrium with Three Goods Because Walras law must hold, we know p 1 ED 1 = p 2 ED 2 p 3 ED 3 Substituting the excess demand functions for gold and silver and substituting, we get 3 1 2 3 1 3 2 2 1 3 2 1 2 2 1 1 8 2 2 p p p p p p p p p p p p ED p + + = 1 3 1 2 2 1 2 3 2 1 2 2 1 8 2 2 p p p p p p p p ED + =

Smith s Invisible Hand Hypothesis Adam Smith believed that the competitive market system provided a powerful invisible hand that ensured resources would find their way to where they were most valued Reliance on the economic self-interest of individuals and firms would result in a desirable social outcome 74

Smith s Invisible Hand Hypothesis Smith s insights gave rise to modern welfare economics The First Theorem of Welfare Economics suggests that there is an exact correspondence between the efficient allocation of resources and the competitive pricing of these resources 75

Pareto Efficiency An allocation of resources is Pareto efficient if it is not possible (through further reallocations) to make one person better off without making someone else worse off The Pareto definition identifies allocations as being inefficient if unambiguous improvements are possible 76

Efficiency in Production An allocation of resources is efficient in production (or technically efficient ) if no further reallocation would permit more of one good to be produced without necessarily reducing the output of some other good Technical efficiency is a precondition for Pareto efficiency but does not guarantee Pareto efficiency 77

Efficient Choice of Inputs for a Single Firm A single firm with fixed inputs of labor and capital will have allocated these resources efficiently if they are fully employed and if the RTS between capital and labor is the same for every output the firm produces 78

Efficient Choice of Inputs for a Single Firm Assume that the firm produces two goods (x and y) and that the available levels of capital and labor are k and l The production function for x is given by x = f (k x, l x ) If we assume full employment, the production function for y is y = g (k y, l y ) = g (k - k x, l - l x ) 79

Efficient Choice of Inputs for a Single Firm Technical efficiency requires that x output be as large as possible for any value of y (y ) Setting up the Lagrangian and solving for the first-order conditions: L = f (k x, l x ) + λ[y g (k - k x, l - l x )] L/ k x = f k + λg k = 0 L/ l x = f l + λg l = 0 L/ λ = y g (k - k x, l - l x ) = 0 80

Efficient Choice of Inputs for a Single Firm From the first two conditions, we can see that This implies that f f k = g k l g l RTS x (k for l) = RTS y (k for l) 81

Efficient Allocation of Resources among Firms Resources should be allocated to those firms where they can be most efficiently used the marginal physical product of any resource in the production of a particular good should be the same across all firms that produce the good 82

Efficient Allocation of Resources among Firms Suppose that there are two firms producing x and their production functions are f 1 (k 1, l 1 ) f 2 (k 2, l 2 ) Assume that the total supplies of capital and labor are k and l 83

Efficient Allocation of Resources among Firms The allocational problem is to maximize x = f 1 (k 1, l 1 ) + f 2 (k 2, l 2 ) subject to the constraints k 1 + k 2 = k l 1 + l 2 = l Substituting, the maximization problem becomes x = f 1 (k 1, l 1 ) + f 2 (k - k 1, l - l 1 ) 84

85 Efficient Allocation of Resources among Firms First-order conditions for a maximum are 0 2 2 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 = = + = k f k f k f k f k x 0 2 2 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 = = + = l l l l l f f f f x

Efficient Allocation of Resources among Firms These first-order conditions can be rewritten as f k 1 1 = f k 2 2 f1 f = l l 1 2 2 The marginal physical product of each input should be equal across the two firms 86

Efficient Choice of Output by Firms Suppose that there are two outputs (x and y) each produced by two firms The production possibility frontiers for these two firms are y i = f i (x i ) for i=1,2 The overall optimization problem is to produce the maximum amount of x for any given level of y (y*) 87

Efficient Choice of Output by Firms The Lagrangian for this problem is L = x 1 + x 2 + λ[y* - f 1 (x 1 ) - f 2 (x 2 )] and yields the first-order condition: f 1 / x 1 = f 2 / x 2 The rate of product transformation (RPT) should be the same for all firms producing these goods 88

Cars Efficient Choice of Output by Firms Firm A is relatively efficient at producing cars, while Firm B is relatively efficient at producing trucks Cars 1 2 RPT = RPT = 1 1 100 100 Firm A Trucks 50 50 Firm B Trucks 89

Cars Efficient Choice of Output by Firms If each firm was to specialize in its efficient product, total output could be increased Cars 1 2 RPT = RPT = 1 1 100 100 Firm A Trucks 50 50 Firm B Trucks 90

Theory of Comparative Advantage The theory of comparative advantage was first proposed by Ricardo countries should specialize in producing those goods of which they are relatively more efficient producers these countries should then trade with the rest of the world to obtain needed commodities if countries do specialize this way, total world production will be greater 91

Efficiency in Product Mix Technical efficiency is not a sufficient condition for Pareto efficiency demand must also be brought into the picture In order to ensure Pareto efficiency, we must be able to tie individual s preferences and production possibilities together 92

Efficiency in Product Mix The condition necessary to ensure that the right goods are produced is MRS = RPT the psychological rate of trade-off between the two goods in people s preferences must be equal to the rate at which they can be traded off in production 93

Efficiency in Product Mix Output of y P Suppose that we have a one-person (Robinson Crusoe) economy and PP represents the combinations of x and y that can be produced Any point on PP represents a point of technical efficiency P Output of x 94

Efficiency in Product Mix Output of y Only one point on PP will maximize Crusoe s utility P U 3 At the point of tangency, Crusoe s MRS will be equal to the technical RPT U 2 U 1 P Output of x 95

Efficiency in Product Mix Assume that there are only two goods (x and y) and one individual in society (Robinson Crusoe) Crusoe s utility function is U = U(x,y) The production possibility frontier is T(x,y) = 0 96

Efficiency in Product Mix Crusoe s problem is to maximize his utility subject to the production constraint Setting up the Lagrangian yields L = U(x,y) + λ[t(x,y)] 97

Efficiency in Product Mix First-order conditions for an interior maximum are L x = U x + λ T x = 0 L y = U y + λ T y = 0 L λ = T( x, y) = 0 98

Efficiency in Product Mix Combining the first two, we get U U / / x y = T T / x / y or dy MRS ( x for y ) = (along T ) = RPT ( x for y) dx 99

Competitive Prices and Efficiency Attaining a Pareto efficient allocation of resources requires that the rate of trade-off between any two goods be the same for all economic agents In a perfectly competitive economy, the ratio of the prices of the two goods provides the common rate of trade-off to which all agents will adjust 100

Competitive Prices and Efficiency Because all agents face the same prices, all trade-off rates will be equalized and an efficient allocation will be achieved This is the First Theorem of Welfare Economics 101

Efficiency in Production In minimizing costs, a firm will equate the RTS between any two inputs (k and l) to the ratio of their competitive prices (w/v) this is true for all outputs the firm produces RTS will be equal across all outputs 102

Efficiency in Production A profit-maximizing firm will hire additional units of an input (l) up to the point at which its marginal contribution to revenues is equal to the marginal cost of hiring the input (w) p x f l = w 103

Efficiency in Production If this is true for every firm, then with a competitive labor market p x f l1 = w = p x f l 2 f l1 = f l 2 Every firm that produces x has identical marginal productivities of every input in the production of x 104

Efficiency in Production Recall that the RPT (of x for y) is equal to MC x /MC y In perfect competition, each profitmaximizing firm will produce the output level for which marginal cost is equal to price Since p x = MC x and p y = MC y for every firm, RTS = MC x /MC y = p x /p y 105

Efficiency in Production Thus, the profit-maximizing decisions of many firms can achieve technical efficiency in production without any central direction Competitive market prices act as signals to unify the multitude of decisions that firms make into one coherent, efficient pattern 106

Efficiency in Product Mix The price ratios quoted to consumers are the same ratios the market presents to firms This implies that the MRS shared by all individuals will be equal to the RPT shared by all the firms An efficient mix of goods will therefore be produced 107

Efficiency in Product Mix Output of y x* and y* represent the efficient output mix P y* p* x slope = p* y Only with a price ratio of p x */p y * will supply and demand be in equilibrium U 0 x* P Output of x 108

Laissez-Faire Policies The correspondence between competitive equilibrium and Pareto efficiency provides some support for the laissez-faire position taken by many economists government intervention may only result in a loss of Pareto efficiency 109

Departing from the Competitive Assumptions The ability of competitive markets to achieve efficiency may be impaired because of imperfect competition externalities public goods imperfect information 110

Imperfect Competition Imperfect competition includes all situations in which economic agents exert some market power in determining market prices these agents will take these effects into account in their decisions Market prices no longer carry the informational content required to achieve Pareto efficiency 111

Externalities An externality occurs when there are interactions among firms and individuals that are not adequately reflected in market prices With externalities, market prices no longer reflect all of a good s costs of production there is a divergence between private and social marginal cost 112

Public Goods Public goods have two properties that make them unsuitable for production in markets they are nonrival additional people can consume the benefits of these goods at zero cost they are nonexclusive extra individuals cannot be precluded from consuming the good 113

Imperfect Information If economic actors are uncertain about prices or if markets cannot reach equilibrium, there is no reason to expect that the efficiency property of competitive pricing will be retained 114

Distribution Although the First Theorem of Welfare Economics ensures that competitive markets will achieve efficient allocations, there are no guarantees that these allocations will exhibit desirable distributions of welfare among individuals 115

Distribution Assume that there are only two people in society (Smith and Jones) The quantities of two goods (x and y) to be distributed among these two people are fixed in supply We can use an Edgeworth box diagram to show all possible allocations of these goods between Smith and Jones 116

Distribution O J U J 1 U J 2 U J 3 U S 4 Total Y U J 4 U S 3 U S 2 U S 1 O S Total X 117

Distribution Any point within the Edgeworth box in which the MRS for Smith is unequal to that for Jones offers an opportunity for Pareto improvements both can move to higher levels of utility through trade 118

Distribution O J U J 1 U J 2 U J 3 U S 4 U J 4 U S 3 U S 2 A U S 1 O S Any trade in this area is an improvement over A 119

Contract Curve In an exchange economy, all efficient allocations lie along a contract curve points off the curve are necessarily inefficient individuals can be made better off by moving to the curve Along the contract curve, individuals preferences are rivals one may be made better off only by making the other worse off 120

Contract Curve O J U J 1 U J 2 U J 3 U S 4 U J 4 U S 3 U S 2 Contract curve A U S 1 O S 121

Exchange with Initial Endowments Suppose that the two individuals possess different quantities of the two goods at the start it is possible that the two individuals could both benefit from trade if the initial allocations were inefficient 122

Exchange with Initial Endowments Neither person would engage in a trade that would leave him worse off Only a portion of the contract curve shows allocations that may result from voluntary exchange 123

Exchange with Initial Endowments O J Suppose that A represents the initial endowments U J A A U S A O S 124

Exchange with Initial Endowments Neither individual would be willing to accept a lower level of utility than A gives O J U J A A U S A O S 125

Exchange with Initial Endowments O J Only allocations between M 1 and M 2 will be acceptable to both U J A M 2 M 1 A U S A O S 126

The Distributional Dilemma If the initial endowments are skewed in favor of some economic actors, the Pareto efficient allocations promised by the competitive price system will also tend to favor those actors voluntary transactions cannot overcome large differences in initial endowments some sort of transfers will be needed to attain more equal results 127

The Distributional Dilemma These thoughts lead to the Second Theorem of Welfare Economics any desired distribution of welfare among individuals in an economy can be achieved in an efficient manner through competitive pricing if initial endowments are adjusted appropriately 128

Important Points to Note: Preferences and production technologies provide the building blocks upon which all general equilibrium models are based one particularly simple version of such a model uses individual preferences for two goods together with a concave production possibility frontier for those two goods 129

Important Points to Note: Competitive markets can establish equilibrium prices by making marginal adjustments in prices in response to information about the demand and supply for individual goods Walras law ties markets together so that such a solution is assured (in most cases) 130

Important Points to Note: Competitive prices will result in a Pareto-efficient allocation of resources this is the First Theorem of Welfare Economics 131

Important Points to Note: Factors that will interfere with competitive markets abilities to achieve efficiency include market power externalities existence of public goods imperfect information 132

Important Points to Note: Competitive markets need not yield equitable distributions of resources, especially when initial endowments are very skewed in theory any desired distribution can be attained through competitive markets accompanied by lump-sum transfers there are many practical problems in implementing such transfers 133