Downloads from this web forum are for private, non-commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

Similar documents
Briefing on request for VAT exemption on sanitary towels

Reconsidering the effectiveness of zero-rating of value-added tax in South Africa

Contents VALUE ADDED TAX SOUTH AFRICA: /23/2011

Chapter 6 SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS

THE TARGETING OF ZERO-RATED BASIC FOODSTUFFS UNDER VALUE-ADDED TAX (VAT) IN SOUTH AFRICA

The VAT treatment of merit goods and services

Sebastian Beer Matthias Kasper. Who benefits from Zero-Ratings? A Brief Note on the South African VAT System

Indirect Taxation and Gender Equity: Evidence from South Africa

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non-commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

MODULE 7 TAXATION AND VALUE ADDED TAX (VAT)

Conference Theme: Global Challenges - Local Solutions.

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non-commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

Redistribution from a lifetime perspective: historical and hypothetical reforms

Inequality and Social Welfare

Revisiting the impact of direct taxes and transfers on poverty and inequality in South Africa

Inequality and Social Welfare

RESTRUCTURING VALUE-ADDED TAX IN SOUTH AFRICA A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS

CHAPTER 5. ALTERNATIVE ASSESSMENT OF POVERTY

Fiscal Incidence Analysis. B. Essama-Nssah World Bank Poverty Reduction Group Washinton D.C. June 03, 2008

Ramsey taxation and the (non?)optimality of uniform commodity taxation. Jason Lim and Sam Hinds

THE CHANCELLOR S CHOICES

The Tax System and Inclusive Growth in South Africa: A Discussion document FIRST INTERIM REPORT ON VALUE-ADDED TAX FOR THE MINISTER OF FINANCE

Benefit Incidence, Financing Incidence and Need of Healthcare Services in South Africa

INCOME, EXPENDITURE AND CONSUMPTION OF HOUSEHOLDS IN 2017

ON THE SCALES 7 OF 2018 NATIONAL BUDGET 2018

of budget measures James Browne Institute for Fiscal Studies

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

Value Added Tax in South Africa

G10 ACC - VAT. Grade 10 Accounting Notes SET 1: TAX VAT. Name: J. Cansfield Page 1 of 14

THIRD EDITION. ECONOMICS and. MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman Robin Wells. Chapter 18. The Economics of the Welfare State

Basic income as a policy option: Technical Background Note Illustrating costs and distributional implications for selected countries

Tax policy and inequality

The Impact of Austerity Measures on Households with Children

Redistribution via VAT and cash transfers: an assessment in four low and middle income countries

This report replaces the first report on VAT.

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non-commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

The impact of the Kenya CT-OVC Program on household spending. Kenya CT-OVC Evaluation Team Presented by Tia Palermo Naivasha, Kenya January 2011

PART II: ARMENIA HOUSEHOLD INCOME, EXPENDITURES, AND BASIC FOOD CONSUMPTION

The poor in Iraq are disproportionately dependent

INCOME, EXPENDITURE AND CONSUMPTION OF HOUSEHOLDS IN 2016

Minimum Wage as a Poverty Reducing Measure

Inflation Report 2009

POLICY AND PLANNING BRIEF SERIES NO.1

2018 Fiscal Framework and Revenue Proposals (2018 Budget)

Income Inequality and Poverty

AN ANALYSIS OF SOUTH AFRICA S VALUE ADDED TAX. Delfin S. Go, World Bank. Marna Kearney, South Africa National Treasury

NATIONAL BUDGET 2017/2018

Universal Basic Income

Analysis of poverty impact of Budget December 2008

The Links between Income Distribution and Poverty Reduction in Britain

Social impacts of the inflation

Distributional results for the impact of tax and welfare reforms between , modelled in the 2021/22 tax year

Poverty and Income Distribution

Distribution of the Commodity Tax Burden in Bihar

Changes in Economic Mobility

Income Inequality and Poverty (Chapter 20 in Mankiw & Taylor; reading Chapter 19 will also help)

Income and Wealth Inequality A Lack of Equity

Optimal Taxation : (c) Optimal Income Taxation

The global economic crisis and child well being in South Africa: summary results

A Comparative Analysis of Subsidy Reforms in the Middle East and North Africa Region

2017 budget. predictions

The Combat Poverty Agency/ESRI Report on Poverty and the Social Welfare. Measuring Poverty in Ireland: An Assessment of Recent Studies

A PHILANTHROPIC PARTNERSHIP FOR BLACK COMMUNITIES. Wealth and Asset Building BLACK FACTS

AQA Economics A-level

SESSION 8 Fiscal Incidence in South Africa

THE DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF THE VAT IN OECD COUNTRIES

CN Tower 301 Front St W. Toronto, ON Environics Analytics FoodSpend. Page 1

ASSIGNMENT 1 ST SEMESTER : MACROECONOMICS (MAC) ECONOMICS 1 (ECO101) STUDY UNITS COVERED : STUDY UNITS 1 AND 2. DUE DATE : 3:00 p.m.

WEEK 7 INCOME DISTRIBUTION & QUALITY OF LIFE

Report :: Upside Down & Backwards: Taxes in New Jersey by Jon Shure. January 2003

Tax and fairness. Background Paper for Session 2 of the Tax Working Group

THREE WORLDS THEORY G L O B A L S T R A T I F I C A T I O N

CIE Economics A-level

INTRODUCTION TAXES: EQUITY VS. EFFICIENCY WEALTH PERSONAL INCOME THE LORENZ CURVE THE SIZE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME

Training COTE TAX PRACTIONER EXAMS

On Tax-Transfer Integration: Let Us Return to the Ability-To-Pay Principle

THE NATURE OF VALUE ADDED restructuring. In view of burgeoning revenue needs of

Understanding the Consumer Price Index (CPI)

THE RICH AND THE POOR: CHANGES IN INCOMES OF DEVELOPING COUNTRIES SINCE 1960

John Hills The distribution of welfare. Book section (Accepted version)

Inflation in a time of inequality: Assessing the relevance of cost of living measures for the poor

Using the Relation between GINI Coefficient and Social Benefits as a Measure of the Optimality of Tax Policy

The effect of UK welfare reforms on the distribution of income and work incentives

NET FISCAL INCIDENCE AT THE REGIONAL LEVEL : A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL WITH VOTING. Saloua Sehili

Consumer Price Inflation across the Income Distribution in South Africa

Indirect Taxation and Gender Equity: Evidence from South Africa

A weakly relative poverty line for South Africa

Analysing tax and social security policy: examples from Mexico and the UK David Phillips, Senior Research Economist, IFS

N. Surendran, Research Scholar B. Mathavan, Professor of Economics Annamalai University =============================================================

Indian Taxation System for Banking & SSC - GK Notes in PDF

TAX TREATMENT OF DEVELOPMENT PROJECTS

Fiscal sustainability and the South African transformation challenge

INSURANCE: Ali Ghufron Mukti. Master in Health Financing Policy and Health Insurance management Gadjah Mada University

Value Added Tax-Theoretical Aspects and Empirical Evidence for Pakistan Qamruz Zaman, Okasha, Muhammad Iqbal

Stellenbosch Economic Working Papers: 24/13

The problem with the current VAT treatment of immovable property. Christine Peacock, Graduate School of Business and Law, RMIT University

A simple model of risk-sharing

ESTIMATION OF URBAN-RURAL EXPENDITURE AND SIZE ELASTICITIES OF FOOD ITEMS IN PAKISTAN: EVIDENCE FROM PSLM DATA

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

Transcription:

Econ 3x3 www.econ3x3.org A web forum for accessible policy-relevant research and expert commentaries on unemployment and employment, income distribution and inclusive growth in South Africa Downloads from this web forum are for private, non-commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on www.econ3x3.org How effective is VAT zero rating as a pro-poor policy? July 2015 Ada Jansen and Estian Calitz, University of Stellenbosch In most countries with VAT, certain goods and services are zero rated to alleviate the tax burden on the poor. However, this may not be the most cost-effective way of helping the poor. We investigate the appropriateness of the products currently zero rated and the impact of this on the poor, the implications for tax revenue were it to be removed, and the contribution to poverty relief of zero rating compared to targeted social transfers. Introduction South Africa introduced a broad-based value-added tax (VAT) on 30 September 1991. This was in line with the widely held view (at the time) that a broad-based consumption tax would produce a more efficient tax system and improve revenue collection. Since the poor generally spend a greater proportion of their income on consumption goods than people who are more affluent, such a tax places a relatively greater burden on the former (i.e. it is a regressive tax). To counter this, some goods have been zero rated, which means that a zero VAT rate applies to certain basic products. This reduces the burden of the tax on low-income consumers and improves tax equity. In ensuing years a few additional items have been added to the zero-rated list. 1 With the basic VAT structure having been in place for more than twenty years, an assessment of the VAT structure is in order. First, it is likely that the consumption patterns of the poor (and others) have changed. Secondly, many government programmes aimed at poverty reduction and income redistribution have been introduced. (Most operate via the expenditure side of the government budget rather than the revenue side.) Notably, various social transfers targeted relief to vulnerable groups were introduced or extended. 1 The basic food items comprise fruit, vegetables, brown bread milk, maize meal, eggs, canned pilchards, samp, mealie rice, dried beans, vegetable oil, cultured milk, brown wheaten meal, edible legumes and pulses of leguminous plants, milk powder, and dairy powder blend. Paraffin is also zero-rated. 1

This article reports on a recent assessment of VAT zero rating in South Africa (Jansen & Calitz 2015). We analyse the appropriateness of the items currently being zero rated and whether or not more (or different) items should be considered for zero rating. We measure the potential impact on the poor if zero rating were to be removed, as well as the tax revenue implications of such a change. Finally, we explore the net fiscal result of possibly replacing VAT zero rating with a targeted income support programme for the poor. Considerations when contemplating VAT zero rating The economic literature provides some theoretical guidelines on the properties of a good tax system. One dimension is that the tax should be efficient, i.e. it should not cause too many distortions in the economy. For VAT, better efficiency may be achieved if higher rates are levied on goods where consumption is unlikely to respond much to price rises due to the VAT (i.e. goods for which the demand is relatively less responsive to the VAT-inclusive price); likewise, this calls for lower VAT rates on goods that consumers readily can choose to consume less of in response to higher VAT-inclusive prices. 2 However, since the poor consume relatively more of the first type of goods (compared to high-income households), this may place a greater tax burden on poor households. The more efficient tax will be a more regressive tax. Thus policymakers should also give consideration to tax equity, i.e. how equitably the VAT burden is distributed amongst consumers. Since the differentiated rates suggested by theory will have regressive distributional effects and increase administrative complexity a single rate has been preferred as a second-best, pragmatic option. A single rate system still allows the option of zero rating. While the zero rating of some goods produces a more equitable VAT thus reducing inequality it may also be seen as being important as an effective instrument to combat poverty. However, this is not so. Goods that are zero rated are consumed across the board by all consumers (poor and rich). This implies that rich taxpayers receive a greater monetary benefit (since they spend more on these goods in absolute rand terms). 3 Thus zero rating is not a very effective way of improving the position of the poor it costs too much in terms of benefits that accrue to the rich. 2 Formally: the tax rate must be inversely proportional to the price elasticity of the demand for a product or service. This is said to minimise welfare losses associated with the imposition of the tax (Rosen & Gayer 2014). 3 Redistribution using differential rates is limited as there is an insufficient variation between the proportion of income spent on these goods by poor and rich households (Keen, 2012: 7). 2

This raises the question of whether there are more effective ways of alleviating the plight of lower-income groups, for example, by using income transfers rather than continuing with a measure (VAT zero rating) that is less cost effective. Do transfers provide more equity bang for the buck than VAT zero rating? Implications of the spending patterns on zero-rated items We consider the spending patterns of households across the income distribution using recent data from Statistics SA. 4 This gives an indication of the distributional implications of the consumption of zero-rated items by poor and rich households. Knowledge of the spending on zero-rated goods will also aid us to determine the cost of zero rating to the Treasury in terms of the lost taxes not paid by the richer households). Our analysis reveals that spending on zero-rated items as a proportion of total consumption declines as the total consumption of households increases. Figure 1 shows these proportions for selected items (such as rice, brown bread and maize meal) for lower to higher total-consumption groups i.e. from the 10% of households with the lowest consumption (i.e. decile group 1) to the 10% of households with the highest consumption (decile group 10). This is roughly equivalent to the spectrum from the poorest to the richest households. Figure 1: Total household spending on selected zero-rated items as a proportion of total consumption Source: Own calculations from IES 2010/11. 4 We use the Income and Expenditure Surveys (IES) of SA, released by Statistics South Africa (2008, 2012). 3

The poorest households clearly spend relatively more on zero-rated goods. In Figure 1 the poorest ten per cent of households spent 4.70% of their total consumption on maize meal, compared to only 0.03% for the richest ten per cent of households (where households are ranked according to their household consumption). These numbers seem to support the argument for zero rating as this gives a greater benefit to poor households (relative to their total consumption or income) compared to the rich. However, high-income households spend a much larger absolute rand amount on these goods than lower-income households and thus receive a higher benefit in rand terms. The Treasury loses VAT on all the money spent on these items by high-income households. In 2010/11, for example, the total revenue loss to the Treasury due to zero rating was R8 661 million (in 2012 prices). Of this, the poorest forty per cent of households together received a benefit of R3 396 million. The richer households (the top sixty per cent of households together) received tax relief of R5 265 million. These amounts reveal that zero rating as an anti-poverty instrument is not very effective: the cost (as lost tax revenue on zero-rated items consumed by the richest sixty per cent of households) is higher than the monetary benefit to the poorest forty per cent of households. Should the list of VAT zero-rated items be amended? Given that the rich gain more than the poor in absolute terms in the current VAT system, an important question is whether VAT zero rating should be retained. Alternatively, should we consider reducing, or changing, the list of zero-rated items? To answer this question we use a method first applied by Fourie & Owen (1993), namely selection according to the weighted net-equity gain ratio (WEGR). The weighted equity-gain ratio (for a product) is calculated as the square of the proportional share of consumption by the poorest ten per cent of households, divided by the proportional share of consumption by the richest ten per cent of households. (The benefit to the poor is squared to give it more weight in selecting goods for zero rating.) Items with the largest ratios make the biggest contribution to VAT equity when zero rated. Table 1 shows the food items with the highest weighted equity-gain ratios (WEGR) as well as their current zero-rating status. Maize meal, brown bread and sorghum beer have extraordinarily high values, indicating their importance for poor households. 4

Table 1: Weighted equity gain ratio (WEGR) for selected food items Currently Items WEGR > 10 zero-rated? Rice 52.7 Yes White bread 17.4 No Brown bread 142.9 Yes Maize meal 677.6 Yes Cake flour 41.0 No Bread flour 62.5 No Samp 58.3 Yes Poultry 80.4 No Mopane worms 13.5 No Canned pilchards 22.5 Yes Cabbage 54.3 Yes Dried beans 97.9 Yes Potatoes 36.7 Yes Sour milk 47.1 Yes Edible oils 51.8 Yes White sugar 63.1 No Brown sugar 16.7 No Baby food (mainly milk) 20.5 No Tea leaves 15.6 No Sorghum beer traditional 113.0 No Source: Own calculations from IES 2010/11. Of the twenty items with relatively large ratio values, only half are currently zero rated. If VAT zero rating remains the preferred policy choice, there is reason to revisit the list of zerorated items: removing some, perhaps adding some (see Jansen & Calitz 2015 for more detailed proposals). Costs and benefits: comparing social assistance programmes and zero rating Alternatively, one can compare the benefit of VAT zero rating for poor households to other forms of targeted assistance. 5 Table 2 shows the benefits and costs of VAT zero rating compared to the current social assistance programme (specifically, old-age pensions and child support grants). 6 Using this information, a benefit-to-cost ratio can be determined, as shown in table 2. 5 We use government expenditure statistics from the National Treasury (2009, 2014). 6 The total number of social assistance beneficiaries for these two transfers reached 14 million in 2012/13. 5

Table 2: Comparing the costs and benefits of VAT zero rating with key social assistance programmes (R million, 2012 prices) 2005/6 2010/11 Social assistance programmes Total benefit* (old-age pension and child support grant) 49 990 72 115 Total cost** (administration of all social assistance) 4 948 5 824 Ratio: benefit to cost 10 12 VAT zero rating Total benefit (benefit of zero rating to the poorest forty per cent of households) 2 723 3 396 Total cost (benefit of zero rating to the richest sixty per cent of households) 4 011 5 265 Ratio: benefit to cost 0.68 0.65 Source: Own calculations from IES 2005/06, IES 2010/11 and National Treasury, 2009, 2014. Notes: * The sum of the value of the expenditure on old-age and child support grants per year. ** Total administrative cost of programme 5 of the National Department of Social Development for the South African Social Security Agency The results show a much higher benefit-to-cost ratio for social assistance than for VAT zero rating. Hence these programmes which were underdeveloped at the time of the introduction of VAT (with zero rating) have evolved to be much better targeted and arguably more effective, from a benefit-cost point of view, than zero rating. Conclusion and recommendations Our preliminary conclusion is that VAT zero rating may not be the optimal way in which to relieve poverty. If zero rating is removed and replaced with a targeted social assistance programme that improves the welfare of the poor, a substantial net fiscal gain might be achieved (see Jansen & Calitz 2015 for estimates). Such a change would improve the aftertax-and-grants distribution of income without sacrificing poverty alleviation. The fiscal gain justifies a serious search for such an alternative social assistance programme or amendments to existing ones. However difficult the political economy of altering the VAT might be, it seems justified from the point view of efficiency and equity. The removal of zero rating would reduce the distortions in the economy and could allow us to focus on those measures (such as targeted social transfers) where the equity gains are much higher. 6

References Fourie F C v N & Owen A. 1993. Value-added tax and regressivity in South Africa. South African Journal of Economics 61(4): 308 319. Jansen A & Calitz E. 2015. Reconsidering the effectiveness of zero-rating of value-added tax in South Africa. REDI3x3 Working Paper 9. www.redi3x3.org/papers Keen M. 2012. Targeting, Cascading, and Indirect Tax Design. National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi. National Treasury. 2009 & 2014. Estimates of national expenditure. Pretoria. Rosen HS & Gayer T. 2014. Public Finance. 10th edition. McGraw-Hill Irwin. Statistics South Africa. 2008. Income and expenditure survey 2005/2006. Pretoria. ----------. 2012. Income and Expenditure Survey 2010/2011. Pretoria. 7