Fixing the Payroll Tax and Improving Unemployment Insurance Reserves

Similar documents
The Material Well-Being of the Poor and the Middle Class since 1980

Income Progress across the American Income Distribution,

I S S U E B R I E F PUBLIC POLICY INSTITUTE PPI PRESIDENT BUSH S TAX PLAN: IMPACTS ON AGE AND INCOME GROUPS

Unemployment Insurance Oversight Hearing. Texas Legislature House Economic Development Committee. Testimony submitted by

The Distribution of Federal Taxes, Jeffrey Rohaly

Download the full paper»

Chapter 9: Unemployment and Inflation

The 2008 Statistics on Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION

If the Economy s so Bad, Why Is the Unemployment Rate so Low?

THE TAX POLICY. BRIEFING BOOK A Citizens' Guide for the 2008 Election and Beyond

At the end of Class 20, you will be able to answer the following:

The U.S. Economy: An Optimistic Outlook, But With Some Important Risks

Distributional Impact of Social Security Reforms: Summary

THE MIDDLE-CLASS SQUEEZE: DC s Tax System Falls Most Heavily on Moderate-Income Families

KEY THINGS TO KNOW ABOUT UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE by Hannah Shaw and Chad Stone

MINIMUM WAGE INCREASE COULD HELP CLOSE TO HALF A MILLION LOW-WAGE WORKERS Adults, Full-Time Workers Comprise Majority of Those Affected

TAXES ON MIDDLE-INCOME FAMILIES ARE DECLINING. by Iris J. Lav

The Beacon Hill Institute

Republican Leaders Tax Plan Would Deliver Large Tax Cuts to the Wealthiest Americans Even if It Doesn t Cut the Top Rate

OVERALL FEDERAL TAX BURDEN ON MOST FAMILIES AT LOWEST LEVELS SINCE AT LEAST Income Taxes for Median Family of Four at Lowest Level Since 1957

CAN EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT EXPLAIN THE RISE IN LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION AT OLDER AGES?

Proportion of income 1 Hispanics may be of any race.

Who Pays? The Unfairness of Connecticut s State and Local Tax System

The Massachusetts Joint Committee on Revenue Using a State Employer-Side Payroll Tax to Offset the Limit on the SALT Deduction

8.6% Unemployment Is a Myth

Chapter 2 Executive Summary: More work past age 60 and later claims for Social Security benefits

REPORT #02-04 O L A OFFICE OF THE LEGISLATIVE AUDITOR STATE OF MINNESOTA PROGRAM EVALUATION REPORT. Financing Unemployment Insurance

2007 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

2009 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

The Effects of State Revenue Options on Alaska Households

Taxation of Social Security Benefits Under the New Income Tax Provisions: Distributional Estimates for 1994 by David Pattison*

FINANCE COMMITTEE MAKES FLAWED EMPLOYER REQUIREMENT IN HEALTH REFORM BILL STILL MORE PROBLEMATIC

SENATE PROPOSAL TO ADD UNEMPLOYMENT INSURANCE BENEFITS IMPROVES EFFECTIVENESS OF STIMULUS BILL by Chad Stone, Sharon Parrott, and Martha Coven

Social Security and Medicare Lifetime Benefits and Taxes

TAX AND REVENUE ISSUES IN THE FY 2010 BUDGET

Putting Capital Back to Work for America

* Next, that you introduce yourself to one another

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

Notes Numbers in the text and tables may not add up to totals because of rounding. Unless otherwise indicated, years referred to in describing the bud

The Path to Responsible Financing of California s Unemployment Insurance System By Maurice Emsellem, Mike Evangelist, Claire McKenna

Quiz #1 Week 03/01/2009 to 03/07/2009

Changes in the Japanese Pension System

Report Documentation Page Form Approved OMB No Public reporting burden for the collection of information is estimated to average 1 hour per re

Obamacare Tax Subsidies: Bigger Deficit, Fewer Taxpayers, Damaged Economy

The Affordable Care Act: Seven Years Later

WikiLeaks Document Release

MORE THAN HALF OF BLACK AND HISPANIC FAMILIES WOULD NOT BENEFIT FROM BUSH TAX PLAN. by Isaac Shapiro, Allen Dupree and James Sly

Fixing Social Security Conducted by the Program for Public Consultation, School of Public Policy, University of Maryland.

The Minimum Wage Ain t What It Used to Be

J. V. Bruni and Company 1528 North Tejon Street Colorado Springs, CO (719) or (800)

How Much Should Americans Be Saving for Retirement?

Economists Expect Big Jump In 2Q GDP - We'll See May 16, 2017 by Gary Halbert of Halbert Wealth Management

DR. FRIEDMAN FINANCIAL STUDY EXECUTIVE SUMMARY DECEMBER 2017

Florida Economic Outlook State Gross Domestic Product

2011 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

shortfalls in perpetuity. 3 The 2003 Trustees report, for example, pushes the insolvency date back by assuming that older

Would the Senate Democrats proposed excise tax on highcost employer-paid health insurance benefits be progressive?

Improving Social Security s Progressivity and Solvency with Hybrid Indexing

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THE GROWTH IN SOCIAL SECURITY BENEFITS AMONG THE RETIREMENT AGE POPULATION FROM INCREASES IN THE CAP ON COVERED EARNINGS

Pacific Northwest Economic Development Council Conference Mt. Hood, Oregon June 20, 2005

The Economy: Growth Has Been Weak But Long-Lasting

Health Care: Obama Officials Look Back at the ACA and the Path Forward

AUGUST 2012 An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 2012 to 2022 Provided as a convenience, this screen-friendly version is identic

Testimony on Maryland s Tax Climate before the Maryland Economic Development and Business Climate Commission

Receipt of Unemployment Insurance by Higher- Income Unemployed Workers ( Millionaires )

THE BEST CHOICE FOR A PROSPEROUS TEXAS: A TEXAS-STYLE PERSONAL INCOME TAX

Social Security and Medicare Lifetime Benefits and Taxes

New Analysis Finds GOP Tax Plan would Give Richest One Percent of CT Residents $125,380 More Per Year on Average than Obama s Approach

Historical Effective Tax Rates, Preliminary Edition

There are several types of tax-favored retirement

Options to Limit the Benefit of Tax Expenditures for High-Income Households

These are tough times, especially for low- and

Unemployment Insurance Primer: Understanding What s At Stake as Congress Reopens Stimulus Package Debate. Wayne Vroman January 2002

Revised November 21, 2008

Notes and Definitions Numbers in the text, tables, and figures may not add up to totals because of rounding. Dollar amounts are generally rounded to t

Tax Foundation s Average Far More Than What Most Americans Pay in Federal Taxes FIGURE 1: April 2, 2012

Additional Analysis: Impacts of House Bill 463 Including the Pass-Through Deduction (199A) Provision February 20, 2018

Another Strong Jobs Report, But Economy Remains Weak

Ch In other countries the replacement rate is often higher. In the Netherlands it is over 90%. This means that after taxes Dutch workers receive

MISCONCEPTIONS AND REALITIES ABOUT WHO PAYS TAXES By Chuck Marr and Chye-Ching Huang

ISSUE. Evaluate several options for expanding eligibility for North Carolina s Earned Income

ARE TAXES TOO CONCENTRATED AT THE TOP? Rapidly Rising Incomes at the Top Lie Behind Increase in Share of Taxes Paid By High-Income Taxpayers

by sheldon danziger and rucker c. johnson

Summary of Findings for FY 2013 January 2015

2013 Minnesota Tax Incidence Study

Productivity and Wages

Poverty and Income Inequality in Scotland: 2013/14 A National Statistics publication for Scotland

STATE INCOME TAX BURDENS ON LOW-INCOME FAMILIES IN By Bob Zahradnik and Joseph Llobrera 1

Credit Where Credit is (Over) Due

STATES CAN RETAIN THEIR ESTATE TAXES EVEN AS THE FEDERAL ESTATE TAX IS PHASED OUT. By Elizabeth C. McNichol, Iris J. Lav and Joseph Llobrera

Designing Federal Budget Policy to Spur Economic Growth

State Minimum Wages and Employment in Small Businesses

The Trustees Report for the Old-Age, Survivors, and Disability

CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH

What Does the Unemployment Rate Indicate About the Weak Labor Market?

Economic Outlook, January 2016 Jeffrey M. Lacker President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

District Economic. Structurally Deficient Bridges, 2001 (Percent)

Chapter 12 Government and Fiscal Policy

Chart Book: Deficit Reduction, the Economy, And the Budget Negotiations By Sharon Parrott, Richard Kogan, Krista Ruffini, and William Chen

Transcription:

Fixing the Payroll Tax and Improving Unemployment Insurance Reserves by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION January 27, 2011

National Academy of Social Insurance Conference Washington, DC / January 27, 2011 Strengthening Unemployment Insurance Promising Solutions to Systemic Problems: Fixing the Payroll Tax and Improving State Unemployment Insurance Reserves by Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION I want to talk about an unusual feature of the U.S. financing system for unemployment benefits a uniquely bad feature: The extreme regressivity of the unemployment insurance (UI) payroll tax. Most of you know that employers must pay a statutory UI tax for each of their employees. They pay this tax on each worker s wages below an annual ceiling called the taxable wage base. Many of you probably know, too, that the federal minimum wage is currently $7.25 / hour. A simple calculation shows that a minimum-wage worker who works full time 2,000 hours a year earns $14,500 a year. What you may not know is the relationship between the taxable wage base in unemployment insurance and the annual earnings of a minimum-wage worker. The earnings subject to taxes for unemployment insurance are usually below the annual earnings of a minimum-wage worker! How many states have a taxable wage base lower than minimum-wage earnings? If we count the District of Columbia as a state, the correct answer is: 33. In other words, in two-thirds of the states, employers pay exactly the same UI tax for a minimum-wage worker as they do for their Chief Executive Officer. [SEE SECOND SLIDE] This chart shows states taxable wage bases in relation to the annual earnings of a minimum-wage worker. In three states, employers pay the maximum UI tax for minimum-wage workers who are on half-

time schedules. Employers in those states pay the maximum UI tax for a minimum-wage worker who is employed just 20 hours a week. In another 19 states, employers pay the maximum UI tax for minimum-wage workers who work between 20 and 30 hours a week, all of whom would be classified as part-time workers. Interestingly, in some these states if the part-time minimum-wage workers have the misfortune to get laid off, they will not even qualify for UI benefits. (At least they would not qualify if they honestly told a UI in-take worker they re looking for a part-time job.) These unlucky souls would not qualify for UI benefits, even though their previous employer paid the maximum UI tax on their wages. Note also that if a minimum-wage worker holds two part-time jobs with two different employers, each employer pays the maximum UI tax in his or her behalf. Thus, a minimum-wage worker holding down two part-time jobs may pay twice the UI tax paid on a CEO s wages. Let s think about what this means for workers in a couple of states. [SEE THIRD SLIDE] Start with California, where the UI wage base is just $7,000. According to DOL, the minimum statutory UI tax in California is 1.5%; the maximum is 6.2%. This chart shows the tax employers pay on workers with three wage levels ½ the minimum wage; exactly the minimum wage; and 4 times the minimum wage. The red bars show the UI tax liability of an employer facing the minimum statutory UI tax rate; the blue bars show the tax of a company facing the maximum rate. As it happens, the Californian minimum wage last year was $0.75 / hour higher than the federal minimum. But that makes no difference. Using either the federal minimum wage or the California minimum wage, employers paid exactly the same UI payroll tax for someone who earned one-half the minimum wage, exactly the minimum wage, or four times the minimum wage. For an - 2 -

employer facing the lowest statutory rate, that tax was $105 / year; for a company facing the maximum rate, the annual tax was $434, regardless of the worker s wage. California is one of the states with the lowest wage base. What about a state nearer the middle, like Massachusetts? [SEE FOURTH SLIDE] The Massachusetts wage base is $14,000. The state has a minimum statutory tax rate of 1.26% and a maximum UI tax rate of 12.27%. In Massachusetts, an employer pays a higher UI tax for full-time minimum-wage workers than for half-time minimum-wage workers. Notice, however, that the tax is not twice as high, even though under my assumption the higher-paid worker earns twice as much. That s because in Massachusetts and many other states, employers are liable to pay the maximum UI tax for minimum-wage workers who work just 35 hours a week. The employer pays the same UI tax for a 35-hour-a-week minimum-wage worker as it pays for workers earning the median wage or earning 10 times the median wage, for that matter. The state with the highest UI wage base is Washington state. Its wage base last year was $37,300. [SEE FIFTH SLIDE] That s a little more than twice the annual earnings of a minimum-wage worker in Washington who is employed on a full-time schedule. (Washington s minimum wage is $8.67 / hour.) As you can see on the right side of this chart, employers pay higher UI taxes for workers earning four times the minimum wage compared with workers who only earn the minimum wage. Still, the UI tax rate is effectively higher as a percentage of earnings for workers earning the minimum wage compared with workers earning four times the minimum wage. Some of you may think a tax that is the same for a minimum-wage worker as it is for a highly paid CEO is a regressive tax. I agree. More than a decade ago - 3 -

Patricia Anderson and Bruce Meyer wrote a paper estimating the regressivity of the UI tax. 1 Let s assume for a minute that the full burden of the UI payroll tax is effectively paid by workers, even though technically the check is signed and mailed by their employers. The idea that workers bear the burden of the UI tax conforms with the way most economists see the payroll tax. They think workers essentially pay the tax, because their employers would pay them higher gross wages if the UI tax did not exist. Turning to Anderson and Meyer s findings: In 1994, workers in the bottom one-tenth of the American wage distribution paid about 2.8% of their wages to the UI system in UI taxes. Workers in the top one-tenth of the wage distribution paid about 0.4% of their wages in UI taxes. The tax-rate ratio is therefore 7-to-1: As a percent of wages, the bottom one-tenth of wage earners pays 7 times the UI tax paid by the top one-tenth of wage earners. The data in Anderson and Meyer s study are now 17 years old. In many states the taxable wage base hasn t increased very much in those 17 years. However, wages in the top one-tenth of the earnings distribution have increased much, much faster than wages in the middle and at the bottom of the distribution. Given these facts, it s a reasonable guess that the UI tax has become even more regressive since the year analyzed by these economists. Compared with the UI tax, both the Social Security payroll tax and the sales tax look like models of progressive taxation. The Social Security payroll tax is capped when wages reach about $107,000 a year. As I recall some old CBO analysis, the Social Security tax is actually a progressive tax up to family incomes 1 Anderson, Patricia M. and Bruce D. Meyer. 2006. Unemployment Insurance Tax Burdens and Benefits: Funding Family Leave and Reforming the Payroll Tax, National Tax Journal, pp. 77-95. - 4 -

of about $150,000 a year. That is, the Social Security tax represents a rising share of family income for families with incomes between $0 / year and $150,000 / year. (The reason for this is that families with very low and modest family incomes often receive unearned income, like Social Security benefits and food stamps, which are not subject to the Social Security payroll tax. The payroll tax is only owed on families labor income, and labor income tends to represent a rising percentage of family income as we move up the income ladder from, say, $2,000 to $150,000 a year in income.) In contrast, the UI payroll tax is lower for the middle income one-fifth than it is for the bottom one-fifth, and it is much lower for the top onefifth than it is for the middle one-fifth. To be sure, the UI tax does not look so bad if you consider it in relation to the distribution of UI benefits that it finances. In comparison to the income distribution of UI tax payers, the income distribution of UI recipients is much more comparable. At least that is what Anderson and Meyer found in their analysis of 1994 data. My suspicion, however, is that the balance of tax payments and UI benefits has gotten less favorable for people with low wages and incomes. The reason is that state UI benefit formulas more or less keep pace with the trend in wages. The average weekly UI benefit is roughly the same percentage of the average weekly wage today as it was 15 years ago, 30 years ago, or 45 years ago. The UI tax base, however, has not come remotely close to keeping up with average wages, except in a handful of states. As the taxable wage cap has continuously fallen in relation to the average wage, a larger and larger percentage of the tax is being imposed on the wages of the workers with the lowest annual earnings. The main factor that is generating increased regressivity in the UI tax is the very low cap on taxable wages. The low cap has two other pernicious effects: - 5 -

First, it causes UI payroll tax revenues to climb more slowly than wages. This doesn t make any sense when weekly UI benefits are climbing roughly in line with wage growth. In the long run, the effect is to starve the UI system of revenues unless state legislatures increase the tax rate on earnings below the cap. But at least initially, the effect of the low cap is to push state UI systems toward very low trust fund balances, which I think is bad for insurance protection in recessions. Second, by maintaining low taxable caps, state UI systems tend to boost the tax rate applied to the low earnings amounts that are subject to the tax. The UI tax becomes the equivalent of a poll tax on new employment. Any jobs created in a year, except jobs paid the very lowest wage rates, will cause employers to pay the maximum UI tax for that job. Simple economic theory suggests the incentive created by a high tax rate imposed on a small taxable wage base is to discourage job creation while encouraging employers to add to the work hours of their current employees. In states with a low tax base, the UI tax becomes a tax penalty on job creation, at least in the short- and intermediate-runs. In sum, the UI tax is regressive and growing more regressive each passing decade. The regressivity seems unfair, whatever adverse incentives are created by the tax. Second, the regressivity is caused by the very low and very slowly rising tax cap. This feature of the tax causes two other problems for the system. It slows the growth of UI tax revenue in comparison to wages given the fact that nominal wages have been rising 2½% to 4% a year for the past few decades. This in turn hurts UI trust fund balances, which reduces the insurance protection offered by UI in recessions. And finally, it pushes state legislatures to impose higher taxes on a narrow tax base in order to finance benefits. This has undesirable incentive effects, because it discourages job creation in comparison with a tax that imposes lower tax rates on a larger tax base. My suggestion is simple. The federal government should raise its own UI taxable wage base to one-half the wage base of Social Security bringing it to $53,000 and it should raise the wage base every year at the same rate as it - 6 -

increases the Social Security wage. Moreover, it should require states to have a wage base that is no lower than the federal UI wage base. Of course, the tax rate on wages included in the higher tax base can and should be lowered. If a state has an ample UI trust fund and there is no reason for additional revenues, the current tax rate can be lowered quite significantly. However, if a state needs additional revenue to replenish its UI trust fund or pay down its debt to the federal Treasury, then it is better to obtain the additional revenues with increases in the taxable wage base than with an increase in the current tax rate. - Gary Burtless THE BROOKINGS INSTITUTION Washington, D.C. January 27, 2011-7 -

SLIDE 1: The UI payroll tax is imposed on a taxable wage base that is too small UI tax is too regressive Low wage base means Poorest wage earners face the maximum tax Wages subject to UI taxes increase more slowly than earnings that are insured by program Anemic growth in taxed earnings slows growth of UI revenues hurting state trust funds UI payroll tax is now a poll tax on jobs UI wage base should be increased to one-half the Social Security wage base (i.e., $53,000)

Slide 2: The taxable wage base in 50 states + D.C. Number of states 20 16 12 8 19 4 0 3 Less than 50% 50% to 75% 11 12 75% to 100% 100% to 200% 6 More than 200% Taxable wage base as a percent of annual earnings of full-time minimum-wage worker Source: American Payroll Association (2011).

Slide 3: Annual UI tax liability: Workers at selected wage levels UI tax liability: California (Taxable wage base = $7,000) 700 600 500 400 Employer pays minimum tax Employer pays maximum tax 300 200 100 0 $434 $434 $434 $105 $105 $105 One-half the minimum wage At the minimum wage Worker's annual earnings Four times the minumum wage Source: U.S. DOL/ETA and American Payroll Association (2011).

Slide 4: Annual UI tax liability: Workers at selected wage levels UI tax liability: Massachusetts (Taxable wage base = $14,000) 2,000 1,750 1,500 1,250 Employer pays minimum tax Employer pays maximum tax 1,000 750 500 250 0 $101 $982 One-half the minimum wage $1,718 $1,718 $176 $176 At the minimum wage Worker's annual earnings Four times the minumum wage Source: U.S. DOL/ETA and American Payroll Association (2011).

Slide 5: Annual UI tax liability: Workers at selected wage levels UI tax liability: Washington State (Taxable wage base = $37,300) 2,400 2,000 1,600 Employer pays minimum tax Employer pays maximum tax $2,264 1,200 $1,053 800 400 0 $85 $526 One-half the minimum wage $170 At the minimum wage $366 Four times the minumum wage Worker's annual earnings Source: U.S. DOL/ETA and American Payroll Association (2011).