Brazil s public finances appeared to have been in a shambles prior to the election. A Brazilian-Type Debt Crisis: Simple Analytics

Similar documents
NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES A BRAZILIAN DEBT-CRISIS MODEL. Assaf Razin Efraim Sadka. Working Paper

COUNTRY RISK AND CAPITAL FLOW REVERSALS by: Assaf Razin 1 and Efraim Sadka 2

Do high interest rates stem capital outflows?

Financial vs physical capital

TheDeclineoftheWelfareState: Demography and Globalization

A Two-sector Ramsey Model

International Tax Reforms with Flexible Prices

TEACHING OPEN-ECONOMY MACROECONOMICS WITH IMPLICIT AGGREGATE SUPPLY ON A SINGLE DIAGRAM *

What Governance for the Eurozone? Paul De Grauwe London School of Economics

ECO 403 L0301 Developmental Macroeconomics. Lecture 8 Balance-of-Payment Crises

004: Macroeconomic Theory

Chapter 9 The IS LM FE Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Macroeconomics: Policy, 31E23000, Spring 2018

Discussion of A Pigovian Approach to Liquidity Regulation

Chapter 6 Firms: Labor Demand, Investment Demand, and Aggregate Supply

Gains from Trade. Rahul Giri

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

19.2 Exchange Rates in the Long Run Introduction 1/24/2013. Exchange Rates and International Finance. The Nominal Exchange Rate

A Baseline Model: Diamond and Dybvig (1983)

macro macroeconomics Aggregate Demand in the Open Economy N. Gregory Mankiw CHAPTER TWELVE PowerPoint Slides by Ron Cronovich fifth edition

VII. Short-Run Economic Fluctuations

Problem Set #2. Intermediate Macroeconomics 101 Due 20/8/12

Volatility of FDI and Portfolio Investments: The Role of Information, Liquidation Shocks and Transparency

QUEEN S UNIVERSITY FACULTY OF ARTS AND SCIENCE DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 222 A&B Macroeconomic Theory I. Final Examination 20 April 2009

202: Dynamic Macroeconomics

Real Estate Crashes and Bank Lending. March 2004

A Note on Ramsey, Harrod-Domar, Solow, and a Closed Form

Chapter 13 The Open Economy Revisited: the Mundell-Fleming Model and the Exchange-Rate Regime

Chapter 24 CRISES IN EMERGING MARKETS

HONG KONG INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY RESEARCH

14.05 Intermediate Applied Macroeconomics Problem Set 5

General Examination in Macroeconomic Theory. Fall 2010

Problem Set 2: Answer Key

Macroeconomics and finance

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Economics 2010c: -theory

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Chapter 8 A Short Run Keynesian Model of Interdependent Economies

Global Imbalances and Latin America: A Comment on Eichengreen and Park

On the Determination of Interest Rates in General and Partial Equilibrium Analysis

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Credible Threats, Reputation and Private Monitoring.

Modeling the Estate Tax Proposals of 2016

Enrique Martínez-García. University of Texas at Austin and Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

2. Aggregate Demand and Output in the Short Run: The Model of the Keynesian Cross

Part 1: Short answer, 60 points possible Part 2: Analytical problems, 40 points possible

Dynamic Scoring of Tax Plans

Comment on: Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy by J. Scott Davis and Ignacio Presno

This paper is part of a series that uses the authors' Keynes+Schumpeter

Problem Set 1. Debraj Ray Economic Development, Fall 2002

ECO 209Y MACROECONOMIC THEORY AND POLICY

AGGREGATE SUPPLY, AGGREGATE DEMAND, AND INFLATION: PUTTING IT ALL TOGETHER Macroeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.)

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ON QUALITY BIAS AND INFLATION TARGETS. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe Martin Uribe

A Decentralized Learning Equilibrium

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Unraveling versus Unraveling: A Memo on Competitive Equilibriums and Trade in Insurance Markets

The Open Economy Revisited: the Exchange-Rate Regime

Business 33001: Microeconomics

Understanding Krugman s Third-Generation Model of Currency and Financial Crises

CHAPTER 3 National Income: Where It Comes From and Where It Goes

CAPITAL FLOWS: EMERGING ISSUES Guillermo A. Calvo University of Maryland Bogota, October 1, 1997

Generalized Taylor Rule and Determinacy of Growth Equilibrium. Abstract

6 The Open Economy. This chapter:

Lectures 13 and 14: Fixed Exchange Rates

Paul Ormerod Volterra Partners LLP, London and Centre for the Study of Decision-Making Uncertainty, UCL

Monetary Economics: Macro Aspects, 19/ Henrik Jensen Department of Economics University of Copenhagen

Comment on Beetsma, Debrun and Klaassen: Is fiscal policy coordination in EMU desirable? Marco Buti *

Comparing Different Regulatory Measures to Control Stock Market Volatility: A General Equilibrium Analysis

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

MACROECONOMICS. The Open Economy Revisited: the Mundell-Fleming Model and the Exchange-Rate Regime MANKIW N. GREGORY

This short article examines the

Real Business Cycle Model

Exercise 3 Short Run Determination of Output, the Interest Rate, the Exchange Rate and the Current Account in a Mundell Fleming Model

Chapter 10 (part 2) Exchange Rates, Business Cycles, and Macroeconomic Policy in the Open Economy. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Government Debt, the Real Interest Rate, Growth and External Balance in a Small Open Economy

1 Modern Macroeconomics

Notes VI - Models of Economic Fluctuations

Corporate Finance - Yossi Spiegel

Economia Finanziaria e Monetaria

Fiscal Consolidation Strategy: An Update for the Budget Reform Proposal of March 2013

Appendix: Common Currencies vs. Monetary Independence

Module 19 Equilibrium in the Aggregate Demand Aggregate Supply Model

A Note on Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities

International Macroeconomics

2. A DIAGRAMMATIC APPROACH TO THE OPTIMAL LEVEL OF PUBLIC INPUTS

Automatic Fiscal Stabilizers

Operationalizing the Selection and Application of Macroprudential Instruments

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Dynamic Inconsistency and Non-preferential Taxation of Foreign Capital

Public budget accounting and seigniorage. 1. Public budget accounting, inflation and debt. 2. Equilibrium seigniorage

Supplement to the lecture on the Diamond-Dybvig model

Interest on Reserves, Interbank Lending, and Monetary Policy: Work in Progress

Final Exam Solutions

Mankiw Chapter 10. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations. Introduction to Economic Fluctuations CHAPTER 10

University of Toronto June 8, 2012 ECO 209Y L0101 MACROECONOMIC THEORY. Term Test #1

Chapter 4. Determination of Income and Employment 4.1 AGGREGATE DEMAND AND ITS COMPONENTS

1 Answers to the Sept 08 macro prelim - Long Questions

Transcription:

IMF Staff Papers Vol. 51, No. 1 2004 International Monetary Fund A Brazilian-Type Debt Crisis: Simple Analytics ASSAF RAZIN and EFRAIM SADKA * This paper develops a model that captures important features of debt crises of the Brazilian type. Its applicability to Brazil lies in the facts that (1) macroeconomic fundamentals were relatively sound in the wake of the crisis (e.g., a nonnegligible primary surplus, a relatively low debt-gdp ratio, and low inflation); and (2) the trigger for the crisis forthcoming elections with an expected regime change appears to be extraneous. We rationalize the sort of circularity involved in a country s credit rating. In particular, we show how country credit ratings could bring about unstable macroeconomic behavior, and explore the implications of such behavior for fiscal policy. [JEL F21, F34, G15] Brazil s public finances appeared to have been in a shambles prior to the election in October 2002. The September 2002 stand-by credit gave Brazil a critical boost, providing the central bank with an additional $16 billion in international reserves to defend its weak currency and thereby to contain the explosion of dollarlinked public debt service. 1 The package also included a promise to increase the available funds to $30 billion, if the primary surplus had increased. Because threefourths of Brazil s debt is in domestic currency, and about one-third of this debt is * Assaf Razin is the Mario Henrique Simonsen Professor of Public Finance, Tel-Aviv University, a Research Associate at the National Bureau for Economic Research, Research Fellow at the Center for Economic Policy Research, and Research Fellow, CESifo. Efraim Sadka is the Henry Kaufman Professor of International Capital Markets, Tel-Aviv University and Research Fellow, CESifo. This paper was written while the two authors visited the Economic Policy Research Unit (EPRU) at the University of Copenhagen. We wish to thank Martin Uribe for an illuminating discussion. 1 Although only $6 billion of the new arrangement with the IMF was available in 2002, Brazil s central bank was also given more flexibility under the program, which cut to $5 billion (from $15 billion) the minimum level of reserves the central bank promises to hold. Thus, in effect, the central bank had an additional $16 billion to defend its currency. 148

A BRAZILIAN-TYPE DEBT CRISIS indexed to the dollar, the policy challenge was not only to defend the strength of Brazil s currency, but also to reduce the level and volatility of domestic interest rates. However, because most of Brazil s local currency debt is short term, and thus effectively indexed to the rate of interest, Brazil seems to have been vulnerable to self-fulfilling-expectations reversals in capital flows, with the country-risk ratings at the center of the expectations-coordination failure. But, since the presidential elections in October 2002 that brought to power the leftist Workers Party, which had a history of anti-market sloganeering, the new government has worked to reassure the markets that Brazil would pay its debts, curb its budget deficits, and reduce inflation. By March 2003, Brazil s currency had appreciated and the risk premium that investors demand for holding Brazilian debt had dropped significantly (from more than 20 percentage points in October 2002 to 10 percentage points by March 2003). Did credit rating institutions contribute to an overreaction by the markets in the run-up for Brazil s 2002 election? The Economist (2003), though in a domestic regulation context, describes the potential circularity associated with ratings as follows: As ratings have been more widely used in regulation, they have begun to affect the market, in a version of Goodhart s law (that any variable chosen as a monetary-policy target immediately starts to behave differently). Because regulators and banks use ratings to assess credit risk, a rating downgrade can itself become a trigger requiring higher interest payments from a borrower or even driving it into bankruptcy. Similarly, rather as teachers often teach to the test, financial instruments are increasingly designed solely to carry a particular rating, not the other way round. In this paper we rationalize the sort of circularity involved in country credit ratings. Our main purpose is to develop a simple, textbook-like exposition of how country credit ratings could bring about unstable macroeconomic behavior, and to explore its implications for fiscal policy. We have previously dealt with this subject in Razin and Sadka (2001). The main differences between this paper and our earlier paper are as follows. (1) Investment behavior in this paper is neoclassical, to assure the reader that no other credit frictions are crucial to the argument. In contrast, in our earlier paper investors are subject to a costly state verification to accommodate for potential defaults (as in Townsend, 1979). (2) This paper deals with fiscal policy implications, while in the earlier work we glossed over such implications. (3) The main insight to be obtained from this paper comes from a simple diagrammatic analysis. Thus, our main argument is not clouded by algebra. This paper is also related to Velasco (1996). That paper s model, however, deals with a different macroeconomic mechanism that could lead to coordination failure. Consequently, the fiscal policy implications are also quite different. I. Textbook Model Consider a small open economy that borrows in the world capital markets at a rate r, which includes a country-specific risk premium. Suppose that the initial stock of capital of a representative firm is (1 δ)k 0, where δ is the rate of depreciation and 149

Assaf Razin and Efraim Sadka K 0 is previous period capital. With this stock at hand, the firm invests at present so as to adjust its capital stock to K to maximize its value. This gives rise to a Bellman equation as follows: { } 1 t V K r FK K K 1 [( 1 δ) 0] = Max ( ) K 1 0 V 1 K 1 + [ ( δ ) ] + α [ 1 + r ( δ ) ], where F(.) is a production function, V(.) is a value function, t is a current (distortionary) tax, and α is a parameter that captures expected future corporate taxes. Naturally, higher future taxes should reduce α. Thus, the derivative of the function V (.) must always be equal to one. 2 The first-order condition is given by (1) ( 1 tf ) ( K) = r+ δ + ( 1 α) ( 1 δ ). (2) Because investment is irreversible no new investment occurs when ( 1 tf ) (( 1 δ) K) < r+ δ + ( 1 α) ( 1 δ ). 0 (3) Naturally, the country s credit rating is external to our (identical) competitive firms, and depends on some aggregate (macro) economic variables that characterize the macroeconomic state of the country. Suppose that these macro variables are two. The first variable is the growth prospect of the economy as measured by the private stock of capital (K); the second variable denotes the fiscal stance of the government, as measured by the primary surplus of the government. The higher the surplus, the less likely that the government will have to increase taxes in the future (that is, the higher also is α). Accordingly, we assume that the country-specific interest rate is a decreasing function of both (K) and α: r = r( K, α). (4) Equation (4) captures plausibly country risk rating based on aggregate macroeconomic variables, which yields a macroeconomic externality. It is admittedly ad hoc. But this reduced-form relationship is of a more general validity. It seems that this macroeconomic externality can also be rationalized in a more micro-founded relationship of this sort. Given the current fiscal stance of the government, and the implied future taxation as captured by α; equations (2) (or condition (3)) and (4) equations (1) and 2 Why should V (.) = 1, as implied by equation (2)? The derivative of the maximand in equation (1) with respect to K yields ( 1 t) ( 1 ) ( ) 1 + [( 1 ) ] = 0 ( 1 + r F K δ α V δ K. ) ( 1 + r) Differentiating equation (1) totally, using the first-order condition (the Envelope Theorem) yields 1 1 ( 1 ) [( 1 ) 0] 0 = t ( δ) δ V δ K dk ( ) 1 + α [( 1 δ ) ] + ( 1 δ ) 0 [( 1 δ ) 0] = 1 l + r F K V K dk dk V K. ( l + r) 150

A BRAZILIAN-TYPE DEBT CRISIS (2) jointly determine r and K. This is illustrated in Figure 1. Equation (2) is depicted by the curve AB (recall that F is concave in K). Equation (4) is depicted by the curve E 1 E 2 E 3 H. There are potentially three equilibrium points at E 1, E 2, and E 3. We can ignore the equilibrium at E 2, as it is not Walras-stable: If the stock of private capital rises above K *, then r = r(k, α) falls, and each firm will tend to further increase its capital stock, moving further away from the equilibrium; a similar divergent out-of-equilibrium process occurs if K falls below K *. We refer to the equilibrium point at E 1 as the bad equilibrium. At this equilibrium the interest rate r[(1 δ)k 0, α] is high, above (1 t)f (K 0 ) δ (1 α)(1 δ), so that no firm will choose to invest at all, as indicated by condition (3). We refer to the equilibrium at the point E 3 as the good equilibrium, in which (1 t)f (K **, α) = r +δ+(1 α)(1 δ) and firms have incentives to increase their capital stock to K ** from (1 δ)k 0. II. Self-Fulfilling Credit Ratings Our textbook model can now be used to highlight the problem of self-fulfilling credit ratings. Suppose that the economy is initially at the good equilibrium: private domestic investment is relatively high and the country-specific risk premium is relatively low. However, triggered by extraneous shocks, the country may switch abruptly from this good equilibrium to the bad equilibrium. Such expectations-coordination failure may happen if some political factor serves to Figure 1. The Stock of Private Capital and the Country-Specific Interest Rate r E 1 A' A E 2 E' 1 ( 1 δ ) K 0 K* Investment-Productivity curve ( 1 t) F'( K) = r + δ + (1 α)(1 δ ) Credit-rating curve r = r(k, α) E 3 K** E'3 B B' H K 151

Assaf Razin and Efraim Sadka redirect market expectations and move the entire equilibrium point. An example of such a political factor is the emergence of a rookie candidate for presidency whose future policies are uncertain in the eyes of international investors. Creditors would then shift their beliefs about the country s creditworthiness, which in turn would shift the market. These beliefs (that the country is at high credit risk) then become self-fulfilling and, indeed, the country s investments dry out. 3 III. Corrective Policies A possible remedy is to raise the primary surplus. This would reduce future taxes, increase α, and shift the curve E 1 E 2 E 3 H downward to E 1 1E 1 3. The primary surplus increases by cutting spending, rather than by raising current taxes (in this case, t does not change). Therefore, the increase in α also shifts out the curve AB to A B. In this case, the bad equilibrium (and also the unstable equilibrium) may altogether disappear. Despite the initial decline in the country s credit rating that made the country land on the bad equilibrium point E 1, the country moves to a new good equilibrium with an even better credit rating and more investment. If, however, the primary surplus is raised by increasing current taxes and not by cutting spending (that is, by increasing t,) then the curve AB need not shift out at all. In this case, all three equilibria may remain, and the country is still vulnerable to selffulfilling credit-rating crunches. Thus, raising the primary surplus as such is not necessarily a cure for a Brazilian-type debt crisis. It is effective when the policy is a government spending cut, but not necessarily when taxes are raised. IV. Conclusion Our simple credit-rating model captures key features of the Brazil-type debt crisis. Its applicability to Brazil lies in two common features. (1) Both in the model and in the case of Brazil, macro fundamentals are not shaky (e.g., the primary surplus in Brazil in the wake of the crisis was about 2.25 percent of the GNP). (2) Both in the model and in the Brazilian case, the coordinator of market expectations that shift the market outcome is extraneous to the market economy. In Brazil the expectations coordinator appears to have been forthcoming elections with a possibility of regime change. Recently, to tackle the crisis Brazil raised its primary surplus target to 3.75 4.25 percent of GDP; as in our model, in the preceding section. Whether Brazil can return to robust growth seems to depend crucially on whether lower interest rates can be restored, as in our model. 3 See our earlier paper (Razin and Sadka, 2001) for a similar mechanism that creates boom-bust cycles. A related treatment is Calvo (1988), which is concerned about the debt-service issue. 152

A BRAZILIAN-TYPE DEBT CRISIS REFERENCES Calvo, Guillermo, 1988, Servicing the Public Debt: The Role of Expectations, American Economic Review, Vol. 78 (September), pp. 647 61. Economist, 2003, Let Go of Nanny, February 8. Razin, Assaf, and Efraim Sadka, 2001, Country Risk and Capital Flow Reversals, Economics Letters, Vol. 72 (July), pp. 73 7. Townsend, Robert M., 1979, Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly State Verification, Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 21 (October), pp. 265 93. Velasco, Andres, 1996, Animal Spirits, Investment, and International Capital Movements, Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 15 (April), pp. 221 37. 153