FIN FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008

Similar documents
Lecture 9: Practicalities in Using Black-Scholes. Sunday, September 23, 12

The Black-Scholes Model

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

TEACHING NOTE 98-04: EXCHANGE OPTION PRICING

Mathematics of Finance Final Preparation December 19. To be thoroughly prepared for the final exam, you should

Math 181 Lecture 15 Hedging and the Greeks (Chap. 14, Hull)

Derivative Securities

Naked & Covered Positions

The Greek Letters Based on Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives, 8th Edition, Copyright John C. Hull 2012

Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Chapter 9 - Mechanics of Options Markets

Asset-or-nothing digitals

Chapter 15: Jump Processes and Incomplete Markets. 1 Jumps as One Explanation of Incomplete Markets

A Brief Review of Derivatives Pricing & Hedging

The Black-Scholes Model

2 f. f t S 2. Delta measures the sensitivityof the portfolio value to changes in the price of the underlying

The Black-Scholes PDE from Scratch

( ) since this is the benefit of buying the asset at the strike price rather

The Black-Scholes Model

Financial Markets & Risk

MATH 476/567 ACTUARIAL RISK THEORY FALL 2016 PROFESSOR WANG. Homework 3 Solution

Hedging with Options

OPTIONS & GREEKS. Study notes. An option results in the right (but not the obligation) to buy or sell an asset, at a predetermined

Forwards, Futures, Options and Swaps

Completeness and Hedging. Tomas Björk

Definition Pricing Risk management Second generation barrier options. Barrier Options. Arfima Financial Solutions

Chapter 14 Exotic Options: I

Advanced Topics in Derivative Pricing Models. Topic 4 - Variance products and volatility derivatives

Evaluating the Black-Scholes option pricing model using hedging simulations

Lecture Note 8 of Bus 41202, Spring 2017: Stochastic Diffusion Equation & Option Pricing

Solutions of Exercises on Black Scholes model and pricing financial derivatives MQF: ACTU. 468 S you can also use d 2 = d 1 σ T

K = 1 = -1. = 0 C P = 0 0 K Asset Price (S) 0 K Asset Price (S) Out of $ In the $ - In the $ Out of the $

P&L Attribution and Risk Management

A Brief Analysis of Option Implied Volatility and Strategies. Zhou Heng. University of Adelaide, Adelaide, Australia

Pricing and Hedging of European Plain Vanilla Options under Jump Uncertainty

Pricing theory of financial derivatives

In this lecture we will solve the final-value problem derived in the previous lecture 4, V (1) + rs = rv (t < T )

FINANCIAL OPTION ANALYSIS HANDOUTS

Simple Formulas to Option Pricing and Hedging in the Black-Scholes Model

Chapter 14. Exotic Options: I. Question Question Question Question The geometric averages for stocks will always be lower.

MASM006 UNIVERSITY OF EXETER SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING, COMPUTER SCIENCE AND MATHEMATICS MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES FINANCIAL MATHEMATICS.

Lecture 6: Option Pricing Using a One-step Binomial Tree. Thursday, September 12, 13

Fin 4200 Project. Jessi Sagner 11/15/11

European call option with inflation-linked strike

Hedging. MATH 472 Financial Mathematics. J. Robert Buchanan

UCLA Anderson School of Management Daniel Andrei, Derivative Markets MGMTMFE 406, Winter MFE Final Exam. March Date:

Financial Derivatives Section 5

last problem outlines how the Black Scholes PDE (and its derivation) may be modified to account for the payment of stock dividends.

Valuing Put Options with Put-Call Parity S + P C = [X/(1+r f ) t ] + [D P /(1+r f ) t ] CFA Examination DERIVATIVES OPTIONS Page 1 of 6

Practical Hedging: From Theory to Practice. OSU Financial Mathematics Seminar May 5, 2008

Notes for Lecture 5 (February 28)

International Mathematical Forum, Vol. 6, 2011, no. 5, Option on a CPPI. Marcos Escobar

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Spring 2018 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

4. Black-Scholes Models and PDEs. Math6911 S08, HM Zhu

Stochastic Differential Equations in Finance and Monte Carlo Simulations

Hedging the Smirk. David S. Bates. University of Iowa and the National Bureau of Economic Research. October 31, 2005

Advanced Corporate Finance. 5. Options (a refresher)

IEOR E4602: Quantitative Risk Management

Lecture Quantitative Finance Spring Term 2015

Queens College, CUNY, Department of Computer Science Computational Finance CSCI 365 / 765 Fall 2017 Instructor: Dr. Sateesh Mane.

Ind AS 102 Share-based Payments

Chapter 18 Volatility Smiles

NEWCASTLE UNIVERSITY SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICS, STATISTICS & PHYSICS SEMESTER 1 SPECIMEN 2 MAS3904. Stochastic Financial Modelling. Time allowed: 2 hours

FINANCE 2011 TITLE: 2013 RISK AND SUSTAINABLE MANAGEMENT GROUP WORKING PAPER SERIES

Lecture 18. More on option pricing. Lecture 18 1 / 21

The Black-Scholes Model

CHAPTER 9. Solutions. Exercise The payoff diagrams will look as in the figure below.

Implied Volatility Surface

Department of Mathematics. Mathematics of Financial Derivatives

Lecture 8: The Black-Scholes theory

Merton s Jump Diffusion Model. David Bonnemort, Yunhye Chu, Cory Steffen, Carl Tams

Mixing Di usion and Jump Processes

Derivative Securities Fall 2012 Final Exam Guidance Extended version includes full semester

Corporate Finance, Module 21: Option Valuation. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 7, 2005

Option Pricing in Continuous-Time: The Black Scholes Merton Theory and Its Extensions

This chapter discusses the valuation of European currency options. A European

FE610 Stochastic Calculus for Financial Engineers. Stevens Institute of Technology

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Forwards and Futures. Chapter Basics of forwards and futures Forwards

Z. Wahab ENMG 625 Financial Eng g II 04/26/12. Volatility Smiles

Derivatives Analysis & Valuation (Futures)

7.1 Volatility Simile and Defects in the Black-Scholes Model

INTEREST RATES AND FX MODELS

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

Evaluating Options Price Sensitivities

OPTION POSITIONING AND TRADING TUTORIAL

Subject CT8 Financial Economics Core Technical Syllabus

CHAPTER 10 OPTION PRICING - II. Derivatives and Risk Management By Rajiv Srivastava. Copyright Oxford University Press

Valuation of Equity Derivatives

Implied Volatility Surface

Approximation Methods in Derivatives Pricing

LECTURE 2: MULTIPERIOD MODELS AND TREES

Hedging Errors for Static Hedging Strategies

Volatility Smiles and Yield Frowns

ECO OPTIONS AND FUTURES SPRING Options

Problems; the Smile. Options written on the same underlying asset usually do not produce the same implied volatility.

MFE/3F Questions Answer Key

Finance 527: Lecture 31, Options V3

Transcription:

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS SPRING 2008 The Greeks Introduction We have studied how to price an option using the Black-Scholes formula. Now we wish to consider how the option price changes, either over time or as the parameters in the formula are changed. As the price of an option changes the risk of the option changes too. Therefore knowing how the option prices changes enables the trader to hedge the risks of holding the option. These notes will consider the various measures of how the option price changes. These measures are known as the Greeks as each of them is given a Greek letter. 1 We shall consider what these Greek letters measure and how they relate to each other. We shall also consider implied volatility and volatility smiles. We shall make use of the put-call parity condition for European options. Keywords: Delta, Gamma, Rho, Vega, Theta, Hedging, Volatility smiles. Reading: Hull Chapters 15 and 16. The Greeks We have from the Black-Scholes formula that the price of a call option depends on on the price of the underlying asset, S, the strike price K, the time to maturity, T, the interest rate, r and the volatility, σ. 2 Write this as 1 Well one of them is not a Greek letter at all. 2 The strike price K is a parameter but cannot change over the life of an option and therefore won t be of primarily interest. S and T do change through the life of an option and although the Black-Scholes formula assumes r and σ are constant, they could in fact change through the life of an an option. 1

2 THE GREEKS a function C = C(S, K, T, r, σ). Then using a first-order approximation we have C(S + δs, K, T + δt, r + δr, σ + δσ) = C(S, K, T, r, σ) + δs C S + δt C T + δr C r + δσ C σ. This show the effect of varying each of the parameters, S, T, r, σ by small amounts δs, δt, δr and δσ but with K fixed. The same will be true for any option or portfolio of options. Thus if Π = C(S, T, r, σ) is the value of the option or portfolio of options then the value of the portfolio after a small change in the parameters is given by 3 Π(S + δs, K, T + δt, r + δr, σ + δσ) = Π(S, K, T, r, σ) + δs Π S Each of the partial effects is given a Greek letter. + δt Π T + δr Π r + δσ Π σ. Delta = Π/ S. measures how the option price changes when the price of the underlying asset changes. Theta Θ = Π/ T. Θ measures how the option price changes as the time to maturity decreases. Rho ρ = Π/ r. ρ measures how the option price changes as the interest rate changes. Vega υ = Π/ σ. υ measures how the option price changes as the volatility changes. There is also another Greek that measures how changes as S changes. This is known as Gamma. 3 Here K is a vector since there might be many different strike prices to be considered in the portfolio.

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS 3 Gamma Γ = / S = 2 Π/ S 2. Γ measures the rate of change of the option s as the price of the underlying changes. We shall discuss each of these a little further. Delta We have shown in the binomial model that holding a position that is units long in the stock and short one call option we have a portfolio that is risk free. The price of this portfolio is Π(S, K, T, r, σ) = S C(S, K, T, r, σ). The Delta of the portfolio is therefore Π = Π S = C S = C where C is the Delta of the call option. If the portfolio is risk-free it will not depend on S and hence Π = 0. Such a portfolio is said to be delta neutral. It therefore follows that C =. That is the we calculate in replicating the option or creating a risk neutral portfolio is the Delta of the option itself. This gives a convenient method for finding from the Black-Scholes formula. Let s take the Black-Scholes formula where C(S, K, T, r, σ) = SN(d 1 ) e rt KN(d 2 ) d 1 = ln( S K ) + (r + 1 2 σ2 )T σ T d 2 = d 1 σ T = ln( S K ) + (r 1 2 σ2 )T σ T We wish to find C/ S where we have to remember that both d 1 and d 2 depend on S. To find we first note that the call price has the property

4 THE GREEKS that if we double the strike K and double the price of the underlying S, the call price doubles. This is exactly what we should expect. If we change the currency denomination of the asset from pounds to dollars and there are two dollars per pound then the strike price and the price of the underlying should double and the call price should also be double. A function with this property is said to be linearly homogeneous in S and K. More generally this means that λc(s, K, T, r, σ) = C(λS, λk, T, r, σ) for any λ > 0. It therefore follows from Euler s Theorem that 4 C(S, K, T, r, σ) = S C S + K C K. Since the Black-Scholes formula has the form C(S, K, T, r, σ) = Sx Ky where x = N(d 1 ) and y = e rt N(d 2 ). This therefore implies that C/ S = N(d 1 ) and ( C/ K = e rt N(d 2 )) and therefore that = N(d 1 ). Question: Give an interpretation for C/ K [Hint: Consider the effect of a one unit increase in the strike price on the profitability of holding the option.] Notice that since = N(d 1 ), 0 1 as N(d 1 ) is a cumulative probability. This is again what we should expect. The tell us how much of the underlying asset to buy to replicate the option. Only if we know for sure that the option will be exercised will we replicate it by buying the underlying asset. If there is some possibility that the option will not be exercised then we only need to buy a fraction of the underlying asset (whilst partly borrowing in order to pay for the asset). Question: What is the of a forward contract? [Hint: The forward contract has a value of S Ke rt.] It is important to remember that changes (with S and T ) and therefore a portfolio that replicates the call will change over time and as the time to 4 This is obtained by differentiating the above equation with respect to λ and setting λ = 1 in the resulting equation.

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS 5 maturity gets closer. The appropriate replicating portfolio or hedge thus changes over time. This is known as rebalancing and the the the strategy of keeping a delta-neutral portfolio is known as dynamic delta-hedging. The of a put option can easily be calculated from the put-call parity conditions for European options: C = P + (S Ke rt ). Differentiating the above equation with respect to S C = P + 1 where C = C/ S and P = P / S. Thus P = C 1 = N(d 1 ) 1. The of the put option is negative ( 1 P 0) indicating that to replicate the put option we mush short sell the underlying asset or to hedge a long position in the option we buy the underlying asset. Question: How would you hedge a long position in the forward contract? What is the of a forward contract? Theta Theta measures how the option price changes as the time to maturity approaches. 5 With some differentiation and manipulation it can be shown that Θ C = C T = SN (d 1 )σ 2 rke rt N(d 2 ). T This shows that Θ C < 0. That is the price of the option declines as maturity approaches or that longer dated options are more valuable. We know that 5 Notice that by convention Θ is measured with a negative sign. That is it is how the the option price changes as we approach maturity and T decreases.

6 THE GREEKS this is true for American options because the longer dated options give all the opportunities for profit as the earlier dated options and more besides. The same applies for European options (on non-dividend paying stocks) because the early exercise of an American call option is never optimal and therefore European and American call options are equivalent. To see that early exercise is not optimal consider again the put-call parity condition C = P + (S Ke rt ). Since the put option is a limited liability asset its price must be non-negative. Hence P 0 and therefore C S Ke rt. Thus a lower bound for the call price is C max{0, S Ke rt }. Now if r > 0 this means C > S K. Since the American option cannot be worth less than the equivalent European option we therefore also have C A > S K 6 and hence it will always be better to sell the option rather than exercise it early. Thus American and European options on non-dividend paying stock are equivalent. The situation is slightly different for European put options. From differentiating the put-call parity condition with respect to T we get Θ C = Θ P + rke rt. Hence Θ P = C T = SN (d 1 )σ 2 rke rt N(d 2 ) + rke rt T which may be of either sign. The same argument applies as for a call option. The longer dated option will in general be more valuable. However for an American put option early exercise may be optimal. This is because by exercising early the investor gets the strike price earlier. In the extreme case where the option is deep-in-the money and the stock price is close to zero then there is little chance of falling lower. As there may be some chance of it increasing, it may be optimal to exercise early and get the maximum gain at an earlier point in time. 7 Thus an American put option will be worth more 6 Where C A is the price of the equivalent American call option. 7 This is more likely if the option is deep in the money and N(d 2 ) = 0.

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS 7 than a European option. Thus although Θ for an American put option will be negative the Θ of a European put option may in some cases be positive. 8 It should be remembered that Θ should not really be considered a hedge parameter in the way is a hedge parameter for S. There is no uncertainty about the approach of the expiration date and hence no risk against which to hedge. Nevertheless Θ is related to another hedge parameter Gamma and therefore it is information that is normally tracked by traders. Gamma Gamma measures how much changes as the price of the underlying asset S changes and thus provides information about the appropriate dynamic hedging strategy and how should be changed as S changes. If Γ is large then it will be necessary to change by a large amount as S changes. In this case it will be risky to leave unchanging even over shorter periods. On the other hand if Γ is small then the costs of leaving unchanged will be relatively small. Often traders wish to create a portfolio which is gammaneutral as well as delta-neutral. The reason for this is that it may not be feasible or desirable to change continuously to keep a completely deltaneutral portfolio and hence a gamma-neutral portfolio will mean that the costs of not keeping the portfolio completely delta-neutral will be minimised. It is important to realise however, that a gamma-neutral portfolio cannot be achieved by using only the underlying asset (or a forward contract) since the Gamma of the underlying asset is zero. Thus suppose that the delta-neutral portfolio has a Gamma of Γ x and that there is another traded option that has a gamma of Γ y. Then selling Γ x /Γ y of the traded options will create a new portfolio that is gamma-neutral. 8 In practice these cases seem quite rare.

8 THE GREEKS Given that for a call option = N(d 1 ) and Γ = / S it is easy to calculate that the Gamma for a call option is Γ C = N (d 1 ) Sσ T where d 1 is as given above and N (d) = (e d2 /2 )/ 2π. Since N (d) > 0 we have that Γ C > 0 which shows that the call price is a convex function of the price of the underlying asset. Since P = C 1 from the put-call parity condition, we have by differentiating that Γ P = Γ C so that the Gamma of a put and an equivalent call are the same. We can see the relationship between, Θ and Γ from the Black-Scholes- Merton Partial Differential Equation. This states that the price C of any option or portfolio of options satisfy C = 1 {( C C + rs r T S + 1 )} 2 σ2 S 2 2 C S which can be re-written as C = 1 r {( ( Θ + rs + 1 )} 2 σ2 Γ. This equation can be used for calculating one of Θ, Γ and if the other two are known. Also it follows directly from this equation that any portfolio which is delta-neutral and gamma-neutral is also theta-neutral. Vega Vega measures how the option price changes as volatility changes. The Vega of a call option is given by υ C = S T N (d 1 ).

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS 9 Also from the put-call parity condition we have that υ C = υ P. It is important to understand why Vega is studied. In the Black-Scholes model volatility is assumed to be constant. Thus it makes much less sense to consider how the Black-Scholes formula changes in response to a change in volatility than to a change in the underlying price. However, the relevant volatility for calculating the option price is the volatility of the underlying asset over the lifetime of the option. This is a future volatility, which is not observable. It can be seen that the Vega of a call or put option is positive 9 and so 10 it is possible to use the known market price of the option to impute the volatility. This is known as the implied volatility. It is therefore possible to use market prices to calculate implied volatility. More on this later. Rho Rho measures the sensitivity of the option price with respect to the interest rate. As with the volatility an assumption of the Black-Scholes model is that interest rates are constant over the life of the option. For a call option it can be shown that ρ C = KT e rt N(d 2 ) which is non-negative. This is because a rise in the interest rate reduces the present value of the strike price to be paid out if the option is exercised and this will raise the option price. From the put-call parity condition C = P + (S Ke rt ) we get ρ C = ρ P + KT e rt so that ρ P = KT e rt (N(d 2 ) 1) = KT e rt N( d 2 ) 9 Here we are considering plain vanilla options. If we consider digital puts and call then the Vega of the put and the call must add to zero from the put-call parity condition for digital options and hence the Vega of either the put or the call will be negative. 10 because the relationship between price and volatility is monotonic, it can be inverted.

10 THE GREEKS which is non-positive. This is because as the interest rate rises the present value of the strike price received at expiration, if the option is exercised, declines reducing the price of the put. Volatility Implied volatility and volatility smiles As we have discussed the volatility that is required to calculate the Black- Scholes formula is a future volatility which is in principle unknown. It may be calculated on the basis of historic volatility but this may not be an accurate reflection of future volatility. It is therefore common to take the market prices for options and calculate the volatility which if used in the Black- Scholes formula would give the market price. This can be done as Vega is positive so that no two different volatilities can imply the same price. If the Black-Scholes formula were correct then all similarly dated options on the same underlying should have the same implied volatility. If however, the implied volatility is calculated and plotted against the strike price then there is typically a u-shaped pattern with the bottom of the U near the atthe-money strike price. Such a pattern is known as a volatility smile. Given that Vega is positive one might imagine that this implies some arbitrage opportunity. Either the low volatility options are underpriced or the higher volatility options are overpriced and one can buy the low volatility options and sell the high volatility options to yield a profit. However, these smiles appear to persist so the arbitrage opportunity is probably more apparent than real. The smile is more an expression of the market s view of the imperfections of the Black-Scholes model itself. The two main imperfections are first the assumption that the underlying prices follow geometric Brownian motion and

FIN-40008 FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS 11 so are lognormally distributed and second that the dynamic hedging which requires continuous adjustment can be carried out without cost. Fat tails, jumps and stochastic volatility The assumption of geometric Brownian motion matches the data well but not perfectly. When one compares actual data to that expected one finds that actual data exhibits kurtosis. This means that the tails are fatter or thicker than expected and the distribution is more highly peaked at the centre. One way of modelling fat tails is to assume that volatility is itself stochastic and itself follows something like a geometric Brownian motion process. Another approach is to assume tat volatility is a function of changes in the stock price so that big changes increase volatility. Another approach is to consider processes that allow for jumps at some discrete points. The jumps themselves follow a Poisson process and this is added to the continuous Brownian motion process for the stock return. These mixed models are know as jump-diffusion processes. These alternatives for the Black-Scholes model are not universally better. Which model fits better will depend on the market being studied. Thus jumps in stock prices are quite common but are less common in foreign exchange markets. This leaves much open for analysis and future work and most trading banks will have teams of analysts working on exactly this. They will typically be using discrete and numerical methods as well as mathematical models. This of course also makes a topic for dissertation work.

12 THE GREEKS Conclusion We have discussed what is meant by the Delta, Theta, Gamma, Rho and Vega of an option. We have considered the relationship between Θ, and Γ for an option or portfolio of option. We have also discussed how to impute volatility from knowledge of market prices and the empirical phenomenon of volatility smiles and how these might be accounted for by stochastic modelling of volatility.