ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

Similar documents
IGE: The State of the Literature

Education and social mobility: where next for research and policy?

Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth

Which Estimates of Metropolitan-Area Jobs Growth Should We Trust?

Extract from Income Inequality, Equality of Opportunity, and Intergenerational Mobility

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Labor s Declining Share of Income and Rising Inequality. Margaret Jacobson and Filippo Occhino

Understanding Inequality, Poverty and Intergenerational Mobility

Many studies have documented the long term trend of. Income Mobility in the United States: New Evidence from Income Tax Data. Forum on Income Mobility

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

Income Inequality, Mobility and Turnover at the Top in the U.S., Gerald Auten Geoffrey Gee And Nicholas Turner

Wealth and Welfare: Breaking the Generational Contract

America s Changing Tastes Income Growth and the Impact of Relative Price Changes on Age-based Consumption Patterns Income Growth

Real Median Family Income is Falling. Family incomes have stagnated since the mid-1980s. Income in 2012 ($51,017) is lower than in 1989 ($51,681).

INCOME MOBILITY IN THE U.S. FROM 1996 TO 2005 REPORT OF THE

The Evolution of Household Leverage During the Recovery

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. When Might the Federal Funds Rate Lift Off? Edward S. Knotek II and Saeed Zaman

Income Mobility: The Recent American Experience

Inequality and Social Mobility. Econ 101

Income and Wealth Inequality in OECD Countries

The Impact of Social Security Reform on Low-Income Workers

SPECIAL REPORT. Income Mobility and the Persistence Of Millionaires, 1999 to 2007 By Robert Carroll Senior Fellow Tax Foundation

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. An Unstable Okun s Law, Not the Best Rule of Thumb. Brent Meyer and Murat Tasci

o. "n August 5, the U.S. Senate cleared

Economic Mobility in the United States

Labor Market Tightness across the United States since the Great Recession

Wealth Distribution and Bequests

The intergenerational transmission of wealth

Income Dynamics & Mobility in Ireland: Evidence from Tax Records Microdata

Inequality in 3D: Income, Consumption, and Wealth

INCOME DISTRIBUTION WITHIN COUNTRIES: RISING INEQUALITY

CEPR CENTER FOR ECONOMIC AND POLICY RESEARCH

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Reassessing the Effects of Extending Unemployment Insurance Benefits Pedro Amaral and Jessica Ice

Productivity Growth and Real Interest Rates in the Long Run

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Americans Cut Their Debt Yuliya Demyanyk and Matthew Koepke

EBRD 2016 Transition report presentation. Some additional lessons from the EU

Social Determinants of Health: evidence for action. Professor Sir Michael Marmot 12 th Sept th anniversary of the Faculty of Medicine, Oslo

Topic 11: Measuring Inequality and Poverty

Consumption Inequality in Canada, Sam Norris and Krishna Pendakur

Labour markets, social transfers and child poverty

Measuring the Trends in Inequality of Individuals and Families: Income and Consumption

Fiscal Fact. Reversal of the Trend: Income Inequality Now Lower than It Was under Clinton. Introduction. By William McBride

Living with austerity how is it affecting the better-off half of the 99%?

WHAT WOULD THE NEIGHBOURS SAY?

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND POVERTY IN THE OECD AREA: TRENDS AND DRIVING FORCES

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Unemployment after the Recession: A New Natural Rate? Murat Tasci and Saeed Zaman

Luxembourg Income Study Working Paper No On the Distribution of Income in Five Countries. Mariacristina De Nardi Liqian Ren Chao Wei

THIRD EDITION. ECONOMICS and. MICROECONOMICS Paul Krugman Robin Wells. Chapter 18. The Economics of the Welfare State

Out of the Shadows: Projected Levels for Future REO Inventory

Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. Updated Facts on the U.S. Distributions of Earnings, Income, and Wealth (p. 2) Summer 2002

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. Public University of Navarre Pamplona, Spain May 21 st 2018 J. E. Stiglitz

CIE Economics A-level

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Wage Growth after the Great Recession Roberto Pinheiro and Meifeng Yang

Law and Economic Justice

Graduate Public Economics Introduction and Road Map. Emmanuel Saez

Wealth - why do we care and what do we know?

Working paper series. The Decline in Lifetime Earnings Mobility in the U.S.: Evidence from Survey-Linked Administrative Data

NEW PERSPECTIVES ON INCOME MOBILITY AND INEQUALITY

Introduction to Taxes and Transfers: Income Distribution, Poverty, Taxes and Transfers (loosely follows Gruber Chapters 17-18)

EVIDENCE ON INEQUALITY AND THE NEED FOR A MORE PROGRESSIVE TAX SYSTEM

Distributive Impact of Low-Income Support Measures in Japan

Distributional Implications of the Welfare State

Poverty, Inequality and the Welfare State

Applying Generalized Pareto Curves to Inequality Analysis

THE NEED FOR MORE SOCIAL SECURITY AND SECURE PENSIONS

The intergenerational divide in Europe. Guntram Wolff

Tax Burden, Tax Mix and Economic Growth in OECD Countries

Table 13.1 shows the top 10 wealthiest people in the United States in 2006 and These names come from lists

Medicaid Insurance and Redistribution in Old Age

Redistribution from a Lifetime Perspective

GLOBAL INEQUALITY AND AUSTRALIA S ROLE

Social Perspective: The Missing Element in Mental Health Practice. Richard U Ren

Rising inequality? A stocktake of the evidence

STUDY OF HEALTH, RETIREMENT AND AGING

Usable Productivity Growth in the United States

Sarah K. Burns James P. Ziliak. November 2013

Diverting The Old Age Crisis:

Economics 448: Lecture 14 Measures of Inequality

BANKWEST CURTIN ECONOMICS CENTRE INEQUALITY IN LATER LIFE. The superannuation effect. Helen Hodgson, Alan Tapper and Ha Nguyen

Social Determinants of Health: employment and working conditions

A Graphical Analysis of Causality in the Reinhart-Rogoff Dataset

Geneva Locke MBA World Summit 2018 Cape Town, South Africa. How Our Generation Can Solve Inequality

From Communism to Capitalism: Private vs. Public Property and Rising. Inequality in China and Russia

Social Situation Monitor - Glossary

FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER

Inequality, Recessions and Recoveries. Fabrizio Perri. February 2014

INCOME INEQUALITY AND OTHER FORMS OF INEQUALITY. Sandip Sarkar & Balwant Singh Mehta. Institute for Human Development New Delhi

between Income and Life Expectancy

Household Income and Asset Distribution in Korea

Appendix A. Additional Results

METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES IN POVERTY RESEARCH

Household Heterogeneity in Macroeconomics

Intergenerational Dependence in Education and Income

20 Years of School Funding Post-DeRolph Ohio Education Policy Institute August 2018

S U M M A R Y B R I E F. The Nordic countries are leaders on gender equality

Do Bank Branches Matter Anymore?

1 Income Inequality in the US

INCOME DISTRIBUTION AND INEQUALITY IN LUXEMBOURG AND THE NEIGHBOURING COUNTRIES,

Economic Inequality in Portugal: A Picture in the Beginnings of the 21st century

High Idiosyncratic Volatility and Low Returns. Andrew Ang Columbia University and NBER. Q Group October 2007, Scottsdale AZ

Transcription:

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY Number 2016-06 June 20, 2016 Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen Concerns about rising income inequality are based on comparing income distributions over time. It is important to remember that such distributions are snapshots of a single year, and that the same households do not necessarily appear year after year in the same quintile of the distribution. Paying attention to mobility, as well as inequality, gives us a richer picture of the income possibilities for households over time. We document changes in a measure of income mobility over the past 40 years, a period in which income inequality has increased. We fi nd a modest level of movement through the distribution, particularly across generations. Nevertheless, the income quintile of one s parents still has a sizeable effect on just how high one is likely to rise or how low one may fall. The distribution of income has received considerable attention in recent years. This is not surprising given the high and rising levels of income inequality; but of equal importance is how frequently households change places within the distribution. What is the likelihood, for instance, of a household in the bottom 20 percent of the income distribution rising into the top 20 percent over a given period of time? What about the likelihood that a person s children will grow up to belong in the top quintile? Questions of this nature are focused on income mobility, which is different than income inequality. Income inequality compares the position of one household to another household at the same point in time. In contrast, income mobility compares the position of one household to itself at different points in time. Having a sense of the amount of income mobility in a society is critical because it affects how we interpret inequality. The distribution of income could be very unequal, but if people move throughout that distribution over their lifetime, perhaps because they start out relatively poor and then become richer as they age, then income inequality may be more tolerable. On the other hand, a highly unequal distribution of income could be associated with low mobility, meaning that the poor today will remain poor in the future, which implies large lifetime differences in income. In addition, if mobility is also low between generations, then the children of poor households have little prospect for improvement, and so the same families tend to remain poor over time. In this Commentary, we document changes in a measure of income mobility over the past 40 years, a period in which income inequality has increased. We find a modest level of movement through the distribution, particularly across generations. Nevertheless, the income quintile of one s parents still has a sizeable effect on just how high one is likely to rise or how low one may fall. The Rise in Income Inequality That income inequality has been rising is well documented. Work by Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez has highlighted that since the early 1980s an increasing share of the total income in the US is held within the top 1 percent of the income distribution. Heathcote, Perri, and Violante (2010) report that the Gini coefficient on income (a broad measure of inequality based over the entire distribution) has increased by roughly 25 percent from 1967 to 2005 (figure 1). ISSN 0428-1276

Facts like those above often give rise to the statement that the rich are getting richer and the poor are getting poorer. In one sense this is true. It requires more income than in the past (even in real dollar terms) to belong to a top percentile group; but rising income inequality does not necessarily imply that the same rich individuals are getting richer and the same poor are getting poorer. It is possible for the distribution to spread out, becoming more unequal, while households within the distribution churn through it more rapidly as long as mobility is high. In this article, we consider two types of mobility: intragenerational and intergenerational. The first type asks how likely it is that a household in one income quintile will still be in that quintile after a fixed number of years; the second asks how likely is it that the child of a household will grow up to belong in the same quintile that his or her parents did. Mobility within a Generation The mobility of a household through the income distribution is affected by many factors. First, there is the level of education and career choice of those in the household. And there is the accumulation of job experience, resulting in different earnings as people age. Then there is the formation and dissolution of households. When individuals pair with or separate from one another, total household income can change considerably. All of these factors take effect over a household s lifetime. Using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) between 1968 and 2013 we construct a transition matrix that indicates the frequency with which households in one quintile were located in another quintile after a period of years. Because of large changes over the sample period in the female labor supply as well as social norms concerning head-of-household status, we restrict our sample to maleheaded households. Additionally, to avoid large swings in income from retirees, we limit age to between 18 and 65. Table 1 shows an example of a 10-year transition matrix calculated from 2003 to 2013. The rows are associated with the quintile where a household was in 2003. Reading across the row, each cell indicates the fraction of households from that row s quintile that are observed in that column s income quintile in 2013. In this case, about 64 percent of households that were in the bottom quintile in 2003 were there in 2013. Meanwhile, 1 percent of them had moved up to the top quintile. In order to get a sense of how much mobility has changed over time, we compare mobility matrices across different time periods using the Shorrocks index (Shorrocks, 1978). The Shorrocks index captures the stickiness of the income quintiles using the diagonal elements of the matrix (bolded in table 1), which denote the probability that households observed in a particular quintile will be observed again in that same quintile later. A Shorrocks index of 1 means that there is complete mobility. At this extreme, every household, regardless of its current position in the income distribution, has a 20 percent chance of being in any other position at the end of the measured period. In the other extreme, under complete immobility, every household has a 100 percent chance of remaining in its original quintile. In this case, the Shorrocks index would be 0. The matrix in table 1 has a Shorrocks index of 0.55, suggesting mobility is far from complete. This lack of mobility is especially pronounced at the bottom and top quintiles, which maintain approximately 70 percent of their occupants even after ten years. Figure 1. Gini Coefficient Figure 2. Shorrocks Index 0.44 Index 0.65 0.42 0.40 Pretax income 0.60 0.38 0.36 Disposable income 0.55 10 year 20 year 0.34 0.50 0.32 0.30 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 0.45 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Source of fi gure: Heathcote, Jonathan, Fabrizio Perri, and Giovanni L. Violante, 2010. Unequal We Stand: An Empirical Analysis of Economic Inequality in the United States, 1967 2006. Review of Economic Dynamics, 13:1, p. 32, fi gure 12. Source: Authors calculations based on Shorrocks 1978 and data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968 2013.

Table 1. Transition Matrix of Household Income, 2003 2013 Original quintile Quintile 10 years later (poorest to richest) 1 2 3 4 5 1 0.64 0.24 0.08 0.03 0.01 2 0.23 0.45 0.24 0.07 0.02 3 0.08 0.20 0.46 0.23 0.04 4 0.04 0.07 0.19 0.54 0.18 5 0.03 0.04 0.06 0.16 0.72 Note: The sum of a row may not equal one due to rounding. Source: Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968 2013. We examine how mobility has changed in the past 40 years, measured over both 10-year and 20-year windows. The results for the 10-year and 20-year cases are displayed in figure 2. The dates are the end of each 10-year and 20-year window. Mobility decreased during the 1980s, rose throughout the 1990s, and then decreased somewhat over the last decade. This suggests that although households are more spread out in the income distribution, they are only somewhat less fixed in their positions within it. Curiously, changing the time window from 10 years to 20 years has only a very small effect on the Shorrocks measure, meaning that the probability of changing quintiles in the next 10 years depends upon whether you changed quintiles in the previous 10 years. If instead the probabilities were independent, then the Shorrocks index should increase with the time window. Our findings are consistent with a situation in which households are mobile when they are young, perhaps because of education or marriage, and then their position in the distribution becomes more solidified as they age. To check this, we divided households into two groups: those between the ages of 18 and 30 and those between the ages of 31 and 45. Figure 3 shows the Shorrocks indexes of both age groups for a 10-year window. The picture supports our suspicion that mobility declines after an early age. While the two mobility measures move together over time, the younger group has considerably more income mobility than its older cohort. In the analysis above, we have considered only how likely a household is to stay in its current income quintile. Another aspect of mobility that is of interest is how frequently a household moves up to a higher quintile. Figure 4 plots the fraction of households that move up after 10 years, conditional on their current quintile. While there has been a small increase in upward movement for the poorest groups over time, for most income quintiles the fraction is roughly flat. Mobility across Generations The second type of mobility we consider, intergenerational mobility, concerns how likely it is for a household s children to move out of their parents income quintile. Beyond just inheritable traits which affect income, intergenerational mobility embeds factors such as parents input to education (both pecuniary and nonpecuniary), residential choice (which affects public school quality and crime), social connections, and income from inherited wealth. It is not feasible to compare intergenerational mobility over time in the way Figure 3. Ten-Year Shorrock Index Figure 4. Percentage of Households Moving Up after Ten Years Index 0.60 0.55 0.50 Ages 18 30 Ages 31 45 Percent Percentiles 45 40 35 First (poorest) 30 Second 25 Third 0.45 20 Fourth 15 0.40 10 5 0.35 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 0 1980 1985 1990 1995 2001 2007 2013 Source: Authors calculations based on Shorrocks 1978 and data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968 2013. Note: The data is annual from 1978 to 1999 and biennial thereafter. Source: Authors calculations using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968 2013.

we have done for intragenerational mobility. Unfortunately, it requires far more reliable data than is available now. We can, however, look at a recent snapshot. Chetty, Hendren, Kline, and Saez (2014) estimate a matrix of parent income to child income for the years 1980 1985 using data on taxpayers in the Statistics of Income. The Shorrocks index for the matrix is 0.905, suggesting that intergenerational income mobility is quite high; however, while children are likely to belong to a different income quintile than their parents did, they are unlikely to move very far away. While distant movements are observed in the data, they are far less common. Figure 5 shows that for the children of parents in the first quintile of income, only about 25 percent end up in the fourth or fifth quintiles. Contrast that with children of fifth-quintile parents, where the same statistic is over 60 percent. Thus in the United States, children born into families with higher-than-average income have a sizeable advantage over their less fortunate peers. Against the backdrop of rising inequality, this suggests that intergenerational mobility could be reduced as advantage breeds further advantage over time. Evidence from international data supports this story. In a study of developed countries, Corak (2013) plots income inequality and a measure of intergenerational earnings mobility, the so-called Great Gatsby Curve (figure 6). While not a perfect relationship, the upward slope of the curve indicates a negative correlation between income inequality and mobility. Developed countries with low levels of income inequality tend to also have more mobility within the income distribution across generations. Conclusion Much attention is paid to changes in the distribution of income. It is important to remember that these are crosssections, snapshots of a single year. Any quintile of the distribution is not composed of exactly the same households year after year. Instead, households shuffle and sort as they age, marry, move up in the labor market, and encounter good and bad luck. Paying attention to mobility, as well as inequality, gives us a richer picture of the income possibilities for households over time. Data on mobility suggest a modest level of movement through the distribution, particularly across generations. Nevertheless, the income quintile of one s parents still has a sizeable effect on just how high one is likely to rise or how low one may fall. References Chetty, Raj, Nathaniel Hendren, Patrick Kline, and Emmanuel Saez, 2014. Where Is the Land of Opportunity? The Geography of Intergenerational Mobility in the United States, Quarterly Journal of Economics,129:1553-1623. Corak, Miles, 2013. Income Inequality, Equality of Opportunity, and Intergenerational Mobility, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27.3: 79-102. Heathcote, Jonathan, Fabrizio Perri, and Giovanni L. Violante, 2010. Unequal We Stand: An Empirical Analysis of Economic Inequality in the United States, 1967 2006, Review of Economic Dynamics, 13.1: 15-51. Shorrocks, Anthony F., 1978. The Measurement of Mobility, Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pp. 1013-1024. Figure 5. Fraction of Children in Each Income Quintile Figure 6. The Great Gatsby Curve: More Inequality Is Associated with Less Mobility across the Generations Percent 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Bottom 20 Top 20 1 2 3 4 5 Child's income quintile Generational earnings elasticity (Less mobility ) 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 Sweden Finland Germany Norway Denmark France Italy United Kingdom United States Japan New Zealand Australia Canada 0.1 20 25 30 35 Income inequality (more inequality ) Source: Authors calculations using data from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 1968 2013. Source of fi gure: Corak, Miles, 2013. Income Inequality, Equality of Opportunity, and Intergenerational Mobility, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27:3, fi gure 1, p 82.

Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Research Department P.O. Box 6387 Cleveland, OH 44101 PRSRT STD U.S. Postage Paid Cleveland, OH Permit No. 385 Return Service Requested: Please send corrected mailing label to the above address. Material may be reprinted if the source is credited. Please send copies of reprinted material to the editor at the address above. Daniel R. Carroll is a research economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Anne Chen is a research analyst at the Bank. The views authors express in Economic Commentary are theirs and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or its staff. Economic Commentary is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to 216.579.3050. Economic Commentary is also available on the Cleveland Fed s Web site at www.clevelandfed.org/research.