THE STATEWIDE TAX CAP SQUEEZE

Similar documents
FY 2017 PERS Proj Current

IN THIS ISSUE OCTOBER ISSUE ANCHORAGE EMPLOYMENT REPORT SPONSORED BY. A September jobs update. Anchorage housing market numbers

What do we know about the Alaska economy and where is it heading?

Population Projections, 2007 to 2030

February 2013 Employment Report. Anchorage 5.2% February Unemployment Rate for Anchorage

A Regional Assessment of Borough Government Finances And Employment

Anchorage Employment Report

Anchorage Employment Report

Anchorage Employment Report

Alaska Taxable January Volume L. Sean Parnell, Governor State of Alaska

Department of Commerce, Community & Economic Development

Anchorage Employment Report

Territory to State Double disasters earthquake and flood Prudhoe Bay oil strike $900 million oil lease sale ANCSA passed Pipeline construction boom

Alaska Public School Administrator Salary & Benefits Report

What do we know to date about the Alaska recession and the fiscal crunch? Prepared with support from. Northrim Bank

Alaska Taxable Municipal Taxation - Rates and Policies Full Value Determination Population and G.O. Bonded Debt. January 2014.

HOME BUYER APPLICATION PACKET (Read carefully before submitting application.)

Ketchikan Economic Indicators 2010

STRUCTURAL CHANGE IN THE ALASKAN ECONOMY: THE ALYESKA EXPERIENCE. and. Lee Huskey Assistant Professor of Economics

Local Tax and Regulatory Environments

AMHS Reform Project Strategic Business and Operational Plan

Anchorage Employment Report

AMHS Reform Project Strategic Business and Operational Plan. Update: February 15, 2018

Alaska Department of Labor Tony Knowles, Governor

AMHS Reform Project Strategic Business and Operational Plan. Update: September 2017

Alaska Public School Teacher Salary & Benefits Report

Alaska Oil and Gas Association

Alaska s Petroleum Industry: Transformative, But is it Sustainable?

Brynn Keith, Chief Research and Analysis. Sara Whitney, Editor Sam Dapcevich, Cover Artist. Trends Authors

Frank H. Murkowski, Governor of Alaska Greg O Claray, Commissioner of Labor and Workforce Development

Alaska Public School Teacher Salary & Benefits Report

Your Home, Our Business

The Cost of Living in Alaska 4 Energy prices a large part of 2011 s rise in infl ation. Employment Scene 13 Characteristics of Alaska s labor force

Alaska s 2009 Population 4. The Kenai Peninsula Borough 11. Alaska s Unemployment Insurance Trust Fund 16

Alaska Five-Year Floodplain Management Work Plan

THE EFFECTS OF STATE EXPENDITURES ON RURAL POPULATION SETTLEMENT AND INTRASTATE POPULATION MIGRATION. Volume I. Theodore Lane Will Nebesky Teresa Hull

AMHS Reform Project Strategic Business and Operational Plan. Update: September 2017

ASSEMBLY FINANCE COMMITTEE THE CITY AND BOROUGH OF JUNEAU, ALASKA Wednesday, August 9, 2017, 5:30 PM. Assembly Chambers

FROM THE COMMISSIONER

Sarah Palin, Governor of Alaska Commissioner Click Bishop

The overall cost of living in Anchorage rose

Sitka 2030 Comprehensive Plan. September 6, 2016 Planning Commission Work Session on Sitka s Economy - Presentation by Sheinberg Associates

POPULATION: New Es mates Alaska had 735,601 people in July 2014, a slight decline

July Authors. Neal Fried, a Department

GAUGING ALASKA s ECONOMY PAGE 10

The Role of the Oil and Gas Industry in Alaska s Economy

We recently renewed our ABAWD work requirement waiver. The only change is to the Kenai area.

Kara Moriarty President/ CEO Alaska Oil and Gas Association. AOGA Annual Luncheon May 29, 2014

The Matanuska-Susitna Borough 12. Employment Scene 20

NOTICE AND EXPLANATION OF PROPOSED TARIFF FILING

Partnership Stewardship Integrity

2015 Individual Products

$1.5 Billion A Year and Growing: Economic Contribution of Older Alaskans By Scott Goldsmith and Jane Angvik

New Sustainable Alaska Plan FY2017 Budget Overview. December 14, 2015 Office of Management and Budget

PROPERTY ASSESSMENT AND TAXATION

Gas pipeline project would boost Alaska economy, but less than 1970s oil line

THE ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF SEALASKA CORPORATION ON RURAL SOUTHEAST ALASKA COMMUNITIES

Women earned 65 cents for every dollar earned by men in Alaska in 1997.

ALASKA S COST of LIVING

2012 Alaska Economic Performance Report

Alaska s Oil Production Tax: Comparing the Old and the New By Scott Goldsmith Web Note No. 17 May 2014

Maximum Sustainable Yield: FY 2014 Update by Scott Goldsmith Web Note No. 14 January 2013

PROPERTY ASSESSMENT AND TAXATION

Sarah Palin, Governor of Alaska Commissioner Click Bishop

Maximum Sustainable Yield: A Fiscal Road Map for Alaska

HS Reform Project ategic Business and Operational Plan. Update: September 201

Alaska Superintendents Association (ASA) Alaska Association of School Business Officials (ALASBO) February 21, 2016

Frank H. Murkowski, Governor of Alaska Greg O Claray, Commissioner of Labor and Workforce Development

PROJECTIONS FOR ALASKA

COMMERCIAL FISHING EMPLOYMENT Jobs declined 5 percent in 2016, mainly in salmon harves ng

TABOR, GALLAGHER, AND MILL LEVIES

Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Maximum Loan Limits for Mortgages Acquired in Calendar Year 2016 and Originated after 10/1/2011 or before 7/1/2007

Managing Alaska s Petroleum Nest Egg for Maximum Sustainable Yield by Scott Goldsmith Web Note No. 10 March 2012

Maximum Sustainable Yield: Wealth Management for the Owner State

ALASKA PRICES AND COSTS

MARIJUANA: A NEW INDUSTRY Jobs, wages, and tax revenue are on a steady rise. MORE WORKERS ARE 55 and OVER. INCOME UP SLIGHTLY in 2017

CRS State Profile: Alaska

Southeast Alaska Resiliency Mapping Weatherizing for the Economic Storm

Observations on Alaska s Economy and Economic Implications of Alaska s Fiscal Choices

How Vulnerable Is Alaska s Economy to Reduced Federal Spending?

ISER FISCAL POLICY PAPERS

ALASKA S ECONOMY. A bright future, but are we prepared? Mike Navarre, Commissioner Department of Commerce, Community and Economic Development

ANWR AND THE ALASKA ECONOMY

The Effects of State Revenue Options on Alaska Households

SOUTHEAST ALASKA by the Numbers 2018

Municipal Advisory Group Resolution Alaska Natural Gas Pipeline Construction Impact Fund

Credit Union 1. Annual Report 2010

Fairbanks Housing Market 4 Renting and buying in Alaska s second-largest city

Alaska After Prudhoe Bay: Prospects for the Economy

Revising the State Fiscal Plan to Account for Petroleum Wealth by Scott Goldsmith Web Note No. 9 May 2011

Legislative Finance Division Page: 1

Property Tax, State and Local Taxes and the New Jersey Constitution ******* Supplemental Slides

Gov. Walker halts megaprojects

rnwehyd ALASKA ECONOMIC The City of Wrangell Alaska's Employment Scene A TRENDS Profile- The Delta Region Warmer Temperatures Heat Up Employment

Anchorage Sales Tax. April 28, 2005

ALASKA MIGRATION and U.S. RECESSIONS How the Lower 48 economy affects moves to and from Alaska

Alaska s Residential Foreclosures 4. Alaska s Workplace Fatalities 10. Employment Scene 17

MAXIMUM SUSTAINABLE YIELD:

Executive Overview and Summary: The Economic Effects of the 7% Assessment Cap in Cook County

ALASKA S ECONOMY. A bright future, but are we prepared? Mike Navarre, Commissioner Department of Commerce, Community and Economic Development

Transcription:

THE STATEWIDE TAX CAP SQUEEZE Scott Goldsmith and Alexandra Hill Institute of Social and Economic Research University of Alaska Anchorage October 6, 2000 A property tax cap of 10 mills would restrict the ability of local governments to utilize one of the two tax bases traditionally available to them the property and sales taxes-- at the same time that their revenue generating capacity is being eroded by growing senior exemptions, disappearing state revenue assistance, and a declining petroleum property tax base. Together the falling ceiling and the erosion of revenue sources would constrain the ability of local governments throughout the state to pay for necessary public services. THE FALLING CEILING Most Alaskan households (89 percent of the population 556 thousand) live in the 25 communities that impose a property tax. Property tax rates in 1999 varied from a low of 4.5 mills in Haines to a high of 20 mills in Valdez. The tax cap would restrict spending for operations and servicing debt incurred for new capital construction, but debt service for previously incurred debt would be exempt, or grandfathered into the mill rate. So in its first year the mill rate would allow up to 10 mills of operations spending plus any grandfathered debt service. Revenues would be cut $137 million in ten communities. (This estimate is based on collections and rates in effect in 1999. The cap would go into effect in 2001 so the revenue loss would be somewhat higher due to growth in the tax base and inflation.) The ultimate revenue loss from the tax cap would be two to three times this amount (assuming no tax base growth or other changes in mill rates in future years). State wide the out year loss would be $376 million, nearly 3 times the $137 million first year loss. Excluding the North Slope Borough, the out year loss would be $186 million, nearly twice the $101 million first year loss. Two factors account for this the retirement of grandfathered debt service and assessment lag. First Year Revenue Loss The statewide local government revenue loss, if the tax cap had been imposed in 1999, would have been $137 million. Only ten communities, with a population of 453 thousand would be affected those communities where more than 10 mills of property taxes pay the operating expenses of government. Most of the loss would be concentrated in the 10/6/00 The Statewide Tax Cap Squeeze 1 of 7

communities of Anchorage, the North Slope Borough 1, Fairbanks, Valdez, and the Matanuska-Susitna Borough (Table 1. and diagram). Mill rates in these communities would not immediately fall to the 10 mill cap. The cap grandfathers debt service payments so actual mill rates in the first year of a cap would be the sum of the mill rate for operations, up to the 10 mill cap, plus the mill rate for grandfathered debt service. Retirement of Grandfathered Debt Service Over time the retirement of grandfathered debt service would further reduce local government revenues in these and other communities as mill rates gradually all fell to the 10 mill limit. When all this grandfathered debt service has been retired, communities would be able to spend their property taxes on either operations or servicing new debt as long as the total stayed under the tax cap. The retirement of grandfathered debt would take many years, but eventually the maximum mill rate in every community would fall to 10 mills. If the tax cap had been imposed in the 1980s the cap throughout the state would be 10 mills by today. Table 1. shows the revenue loss in 1999 at a 10 mill cap for all communities. Taking debt retirement into account adds $213 million to the lost revenues, $60 million excluding the North Slope Borough. The total loss would have been 53 percent of property tax revenues statewide, or $349 million. Net of the North Slope Borough the loss would have been 36 percent, or $161 million. The North Slope Borough and Anchorage would account for most of the revenue loss associated with grandfathered debt. Assessment Lag Over time another provision of the tax cap would further erode the property tax revenues of these and other communities with mill rates close to the 10 mill cap. The tax cap would limit the annual increase in assessed value of property to 2 percent except when the property was sold. At the time of sale the property would be assessed at the sale price (not necessarily the market price). 1 The North Slope Borough is a special case. Their assessed value for the purpose of determining property tax revenues for operations is only a fraction of the total assessed value of property in the Borough. Consequently although the level of their operations spending implied an operations mill rate of 5.02 in 2000, the effective operations mill rate was 24.39 mills. See Alaska Taxable 1999, page 25. 10/6/00 The Statewide Tax Cap Squeeze 2 of 7

Table 1. 10 MILL PROPERTY TAX CAP FIRST AND OUT YEAR REVENUE EFFECTS BY COMMUNITY (MILLION $) -------------- --------------------------------------------------------------------------- ---------------------------- ------------------------------- -------------- Revenue Loss Percent Mill Rate Excess Community Actual Loss of Property Imposing Property First Year Out Years Out Years Out Years Property Tax First Out Tax Property Taxes Cut in Cut in from Total Today Year Year Capacity Tax Collected Operations Capital Below Value First Out With With With in 1998 Assessments Year Year Cap Cap Cap 1 2 3 1+2+3 -------------- --------------------------------------------------------------------------- ---------------------------- ------------------------------- -------------- STATE TOTAL $664.5 $136.7 $212.6 $26.7 $376.0 20.6% 56.6% $5.7 TOTAL NET NORTH SLOPE BOROUGH $453.5 $101.2 $60.1 $24.4 $185.7 22.3% 41.0% $5.7 COMMUNITIES WITH OPERATIONS $609.6 $136.7 $212.0 $26.0 $374.7 22.4% 61.5% SPENDING OVER CAP Anchorage $252.0 $64.3 $49.0 $13.9 $127.1 25.5% 50.4% 18.2 13.5 10.0 - North Slope Borough $211.0 $35.5 $152.5 $2.3 $190.3 16.8% 90.2% - - - - Fairbanks $59.9 $18.5 $4.4 $3.7 $26.6 30.9% 44.4% 16.2 11.2 10.0 - Valdez $17.6 $8.8 $0.0 $0.9 $9.7 50.0% 55.0% 20.0 10.0 10.0 - Matanuska Susitna Borough $36.8 $7.7 $2.8 $2.6 $13.1 21.0% 35.7% 14.0 11.1 10.0 - Juneau $25.8 $1.1 $3.2 $2.1 $6.5 4.2% 25.1% 12.0 11.5 10.0 - Nome $1.9 $0.3 $0.0 $0.2 $0.5 16.7% 25.0% 12.0 10.0 10.0 - Cordova $1.5 $0.3 $0.1 $0.1 $0.5 20.8% 35.7% 14.0 11.1 10.0 - Wrangell $1.2 $0.2 - - $0.2 16.7% 16.7% 12.0 10.0 11.1 $0.0 Bristol Bay Borough $2.0 $0.0 $0.0 $0.2 $0.2 2.4% 12.2% 10.3 10.0 10.0 - COMMUNITIES WITH DEBT SERVICE $4.0 $0.0 $0.6 $0.3 $1.0 0.0% 23.5% $0.0 SPENDING OVER CAP Unalaska $3.9 - $0.6 $0.3 $0.9 0.0% 23.6% 11.8 11.8 10.0 - Nenana $0.2 - $0.0 $0.0 $0.0 0.0% 21.7% 11.5 11.5 10.0 - COMMUNITIES LESS THAN 10% $8.4 $0.0 $0.0 $0.4 $0.4 0.0% 4.2% $0.0 UNDER CAP - Kodiak $6.6 - - $0.2 $0.2 0.0% 2.7% 9.3 9.3 10.0 - Petersburg $1.8 - - $0.2 $0.2 0.0% 10.0% 10.0 10.0 10.0 - COMMUNITIES MORE THAN 10% $42.4 $0.0 $0.0 $0.0 $0.0 $5.7 UNDER CAP Haines $0.8 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 4.5 4.5 5.0 $0.8 Kenai Peninsula Borough $28.2 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 8.6 8.6 9.6 $1.3 Ketchikan $7.1 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 7.5 7.5 8.3 $1.4 Sitka $3.3 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 6.0 6.0 6.7 $1.6 Yakutat $0.3 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 9.0 9.0 10.0 $0.0 Craig $0.4 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 6.0 6.0 6.7 $0.2 Dillingham $1.0 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 8.0 8.0 8.9 $0.1 Eagle $0.0 - - - $0.0 ERR ERR 0.0 0.0 0.0 $0.1 Pelican $0.1 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 6.0 6.0 6.7 $0.0 Skagway $1.2 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 8.8 8.8 9.8 $0.0 Whittier $0.2 - - - $0.0 0.0% 0.0% 5.0 5.0 5.6 $0.12 SOURCE: NOTES TO TABLE: Based on data from Alaska Taxable for 1999, an unpublished analysis by the state assessor, and authors' estimates. It is unclear how the tax cap would be interpreted for the 11 Boroughs that contain incorporated cities. (For example, the Kenai Borough imposes a property tax on top of the city of Kenai property tax.) In this analysis we assume that the sum of the property taxes imposed by local gtovernment could not exceed 10 mills in any location. Unified Home Rule Boroughs are Anchorage, Juneau, and Sitka. Yakutat and Bristol Bay Borough contain no incorporated cities. Revenue loss is based on the assumption that communities above the cap will cut their mill rates to the cap but no lower. Communities with debt service spending over the cap can undertake new capital construction, as long as the debt service does not exceed the cap. In communities below the cap, mill rates will need to rise to maintain property tax revenues when assessment lag commences. Assessment lag occurs when growth in assessed values falls behind growth in the market value of property. 10/6/00 The Statewide Tax Cap Squeeze 3 of 7

10/6/00 The Statewide Tax Cap Squeeze 4 of 7

Since property values are likely to continue to increase at a rate at least equal to inflation, which historically has averaged about 3 percent, the assessed value of property will tend to lag behind its market value, unless all property changed hands through sale every year. This gradual erosion of the property tax base assessment lag--has been particularly severe in some cities in California where property has appreciated rapidly and turned over slowly. The effective mill rate (property taxes collected / market value of property) in some California communities is less than 6 mills, little more than half the 10 mill statutory rate imposed by their tax cap. Although it is unlikely that such a low effective mill rate would happen here, the effective mill rate will gradually fall below the statutory rate, and could easily be 9 mills in a few years. (This based on 4 percent inflation and an 8 year holding period for property). Assessment lag at this rate eventually adds $27 million to the local government revenue loss from the tax cap. This increases the total out year revenue loss to $376 million and extends it to 14 communities with a population of 475 thousand (76 percent of the state total). The total loss is equal to 57 percent of property taxes collected in 1999 and 41 percent of property taxes collected net of the North Slope Borough. Unaffected Communities At current property tax mill rates, 11 communities would be unconstrained by the 10 mill cap. One of these has a mill rate of 9 that would just put it on the line with no excess capacity (taking into account assessment lag). The rest have mill rates less than 9 mills. Their combined excess capacity, the amount of additional revenues they could generate if they taxed up to the effective cap, is $5.75 million, over and above their actual collections of $42.4 million. Although these communities would not lose property tax revenues, assessment lag would require that they increase their mill rates to prevent a loss of revenues. If they did not raise their mill rates their revenues would fall below what they would have been in the absence of the tax cap. New Capital Construction With the tax cap, payment of the debt service for any new capital construction financed by general obligation bonds would need to fit under the 10 mill limit. The ten communities at the 10 mill limit for operations would be unable to take on new debt without further reducing operating expenditures. Only communities spending less than 10 mills for operations would be able to continue some debt financed capital construction without further reducing their operating expenditures. Shift of Petroleum Tax Revenues to the State 10/6/00 The Statewide Tax Cap Squeeze 5 of 7

If the tax cap had been in place in 1999 state petroleum property tax revenues would have increased by $44.5 million at the expense of local governments primarily the North Slope Borough, Valdez, and Fairbanks. This is because the state collects a 20 mill property tax on petroleum property and passes a share on to those local governments that have taxable petroleum property. The amount shared with these local governments is based on the local property tax mill rate. Reducing the local mill rate increases the share of petroleum property taxes retained by state government. Over time the amount retained by the state would increase as local tax rates fell to 10 mills. If the full effect of the tax cap were in effect in 1999 the state would have retained $187.8 million more than it did. Net of the North Slope Borough the loss would have been $10.7 million. These local government revenue losses are included in Table 1. (Since petroleum property assessments are falling, the actual loss in the future would be less than this amount.) EROSION OF REVENUE SOURCES Three revenue sources that local government has relied upon in the past to support public spending have been dropping. Table 2. shows that together they have fallen by 50 percent since 1990. By 2010 they may be providing less than half as much revenue as today, or only a third as much per person. Property taxes have been shouldering a larger share of the total revenue burden, and demand on the property tax will continue to grow in the future. Table 2. Decline of Some Important Local Government Revenues (million 1999$) projected 1990 2000 2010 Total $412 $210 $74 Petroleum Property Tax $308 $209 $142 State Assistance $116 $ 31 $ 11 Senior Citizen Exemption -$ 11 -$ 29 -$ 79 Population (000) 553 625 700 Total per Capita ($) $745 $336 $105 Growing Senior Exemption Statewide in 1999 tax exemptions totaling $27 million were granted to senior citizens 6.3 percent of actual collections. (Without this exemption mill rates could have been about 5.6% lower.) The dollar value of these exemptions has been growing much faster than actual property tax collections (13 percent per year vs. 6 percent per year since 10/6/00 The Statewide Tax Cap Squeeze 6 of 7

1990). At this rate the exemption would grow to $79 million in 2010 (1999$), 12 percent of actual collections. (Without this exemption mill rates could be 11 percent lower in 2010.) Falling State Fiscal Assistance Local revenues from state revenue sharing and municipal assistance peaked in 1982 at $144 million, $222 million in 1999$. In fiscal year 2001 the appropriation was $28.5 million. Continuation of the trend since 1990 would reduce this assistance to $11 million by 2010 (1999$). Education support (not included in Table 2.), both the foundation program for operations and debt repayment for construction of new facilities, has also been falling in real dollars. Erosion of the Petroleum Tax Base Local revenues from the taxation of petroleum property peaked in 1986 at $274 million, $383 million in 1999$. By 1999 revenues had fallen to $217 million. Continuation of this trend would reduce local petroleum taxes to $142 million by 2010 (1999$) in the absence of the tax cap. However with the cap, local governments would get a smaller share of this shrinking tax base due to the shift in revenues to the state government. With the tax cap local governments would get only about 75 million by 2010 (Figure 1.). $250 $200 $150 $100 $50 $0 OIL PROPERTY TAX WITH CAP million 1999$ 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 Retained by the state WITHOUT CAP Shifted from local govt to state WITH CAP Shared with local government WITH CAP Assumes.5 mill annual reduction in actual mill rate in effected local communities 10/6/00 The Statewide Tax Cap Squeeze 7 of 7