Economics 101. Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand

Similar documents
ECON Micro Foundations

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture II: Production Function and Profit Maximization

ECMB02F -- Problem Set 2 Solutions

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Chapter 8. Slutsky Equation

Intro to Economic analysis

Buying and Selling. Chapter Nine. Endowments. Buying and Selling. Buying and Selling

ECO 352 International Trade Spring Term 2010 Week 3 Precepts February 15 Introduction, and The Exchange Model Questions

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Mathematical Economics dr Wioletta Nowak. Lecture 1

ARE 202: Welfare: Tools and Applications Spring Lecture notes 03 Applications of Revealed Preferences

Effects of a Price Change. Chapter Eight. Effects of a Price Change. Effects of a Price Change. Effects of a Price Change. Effects of a Price Change

Lecture Demand Functions

Chapter Eight. Slutsky Equation

Midterm 1 (A) U(x 1, x 2 ) = (x 1 ) 4 (x 2 ) 2

p 1 _ x 1 (p 1 _, p 2, I ) x 1 X 1 X 2

Understand general-equilibrium relationships, such as the relationship between barriers to trade, and the domestic distribution of income.

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

ECON 2001: Intermediate Microeconomics

1 Consumer Choice. 2 Consumer Preferences. 2.1 Properties of Consumer Preferences. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 4 of the text.

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Income and Substitution Effects in Consumer Goods Markest

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Midterm Questions and Answers Econ 8712

Problem Set VI: Edgeworth Box

ECON 5113 Advanced Microeconomics

Marshall and Hicks Understanding the Ordinary and Compensated Demand

MICROECONOMICS Principles and Analysis Frank Cowell

Economics 101. Lecture 8 - Intertemporal Choice and Uncertainty

ECN 2001 MICROECONOMICS I SLUTSKY EQUATION Class Discussion 6 (Ch. 7) - Answer Key TRUE-FALSE

Practice Problems: First-Year M. Phil Microeconomics, Consumer and Producer Theory Vincent P. Crawford, University of Oxford Michaelmas Term 2010

Foundational Preliminaries: Answers to Within-Chapter-Exercises

EconS Constrained Consumer Choice

EconS 301 Written Assignment #3 - ANSWER KEY

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 2 Consumer Behaviour 2.1 THE CONSUMER S BUDGET

Microeconomics I. Dr. S. Farshad Fatemi. Fall ( st Term) - Group 1 Chapter Two Consumer Choice

Trade Expenditure and Trade Utility Functions Notes

Answer Key Practice Final Exam

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

(a) Ben s affordable bundle if there is no insurance market is his endowment: (c F, c NF ) = (50,000, 500,000).

Chapter 6: Supply and Demand with Income in the Form of Endowments

Extraction capacity and the optimal order of extraction. By: Stephen P. Holland

Gains from Trade. Rahul Giri

Macroeconomics I, UPF Professor Antonio Ciccone SOLUTIONS PROBLEM SET 1

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

We will make several assumptions about these preferences:

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

UNIT 1 THEORY OF COSUMER BEHAVIOUR: BASIC THEMES

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. The Budget Set for Consumers. Indifference Curves are Like a Topographical Map for Utility.

Topic 2 Part II: Extending the Theory of Consumer Behaviour

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #4

Macroeconomics for Development Week 3 Class

Economics II - Exercise Session # 3, October 8, Suggested Solution

University of Toronto Department of Economics ECO 204 Summer 2013 Ajaz Hussain TEST 1 SOLUTIONS GOOD LUCK!

Radner Equilibrium: Definition and Equivalence with Arrow-Debreu Equilibrium

U(x 1, x 2 ) = 2 ln x 1 + x 2

CONSUMPTION THEORY - first part (Varian, chapters 2-7)

Econ205 Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus Chapter 1

Preferences and Utility

Best Reply Behavior. Michael Peters. December 27, 2013

Take Home Exam #2 - Answer Key. ECON 500 Summer 2004.

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Expenditure minimization

3/1/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 4: Solving the Consumer s Problem. The Story So Far. Today s Aims. Solving the Consumer s Problem

Lecture 10: Two-Period Model

Lecture 2A: General Equilibrium

Choice. A. Optimal choice 1. move along the budget line until preferred set doesn t cross the budget set. Figure 5.1.

Do Not Write Below Question Maximum Possible Points Score Total Points = 100

Inflation. David Andolfatto

Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)

1a. Define and comment upon Slutsky s substitution effect.

Problem Set 2. Theory of Banking - Academic Year Maria Bachelet March 2, 2017

Chapter 4. Consumption and Saving. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

ECON 3020 Intermediate Macroeconomics

Economics 11: Solutions to Practice Final

Department of Economics The Ohio State University Final Exam Answers Econ 8712

Lecture Note 7 Linking Compensated and Uncompensated Demand: Theory and Evidence. David Autor, MIT Department of Economics

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis October 16, 2008 Professor John Parman. Midterm 1

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

International Economics Lecture 2: The Ricardian Model

Lecture 2 Consumer theory (continued)

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Final Examination December 14, Economics 5010 AF3.0 : Applied Microeconomics. time=2.5 hours

Please do not leave the exam room within the final 15 minutes of the exam, except in an emergency.

A. Introduction to choice under uncertainty 2. B. Risk aversion 11. C. Favorable gambles 15. D. Measures of risk aversion 20. E.

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 3: Demand Theory Applications

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

Budget Constrained Choice with Two Commodities

Homework 3 Solutions

Economics 101A Spring A Revised Version of the Slutsky Equation Using the Expenditure Function or, the expenditure function is our friend!

Price Changes and Consumer Welfare

14.03 Fall 2004 Problem Set 2 Solutions

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program August 2017

I. More Fundamental Concepts and Definitions from Mathematics

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE TRADE

Preferences - A Reminder

The Rational Consumer. The Objective of Consumers. Maximizing Utility. The Budget Set for Consumers. Slope =

Transcription:

Economics 101 Lecture 3 - Consumer Demand 1 Intro First, a note on wealth and endowment. Varian generally uses wealth (m) instead of endowment. Ultimately, these two are equivalent. Given prices p, if we have endowment e, our wealth is simply w = p e. Conversely, if we have wealth w, this is the same as have an endowment e given by e i = w j p j so that p e = w. Note that there are many other endowments that lead to wealth w. Last lecture we investigated how consumers make choices by maximizing their utility subject to the budget constraint. Given prices and endowment, we found what the consumer s optimal choice was. Now we ll formalize this Demand Function: For any prices and endowment, a demand function gives the bundle of goods x(p, e) optimally chosen by the consumer. Notice that give the relationship between endowment and wealth, it is equivalent to define demand simply as a function of prices and wealth. Sometimes, to avoid confusion I will add superscripts to denote which function I m talking about. These functions are related by x e (p, e) = x w (p, p e) We are free to do this because the only thing that determines the shape of the budget set is normalized prices and wealth. Changing the endowment while keeping wealth constant does not change the budget line. It only changes where the endowment lies on the budget line, which does not affect the optimal choice. 1

Also note that we assume throughout that x is a function, meaning that the is one and only one optimal choice. In general, it may be there are multiple choice of x that yield the same maximal utility, in which case x would be a set-valued function. Assuming that utility is strictly increasing rids us of this problem. 2 Comparative Statics Often we will be interested in how a consumer s choice will vary with certain economic variables such as market prices, wealth, or certain preference parameters. We ll be interested primarily in two of these. Price Effects: Holding wealth constant, how does price affect the optimal choice? 0 Wealth Effects: Holding prices constant, how does wealth affect the optimal choice? w We ll look at each of these separately. 2.1 Wealth Effects Increasing wealth while holding prices constant simply shifts the budget line outwards while keeping the slope the same. Decreasing wealth does the opposite. Each change in wealth will lead to a new optimal consumption bundle. Fixing a certain price vector, if we were to map out the choice for each possible value of w, this would sketch out what is known as the wealth offer curve. This would necessarily start from the origin and move out from there. 0 Proposition 1. If w w, then x(p, w ) x(p, w). Since the budget set becomes strictly larger when wealth increases to w, if it optimal to decrease consumption in every good upon this increase in wealth, 2

then x(p, w ) should have been the optimal choice for (p, w) as well. Notice with vectors, is not equivalent to. With this, we can now define two classes of goods, depending on how their demand responds to changes in wealth. Normal Good: Consumption is increasing in wealth w 0 Inferior Good: Consumption is decreasing in wealth w We ll often say that these are properties of goods. Really, they are properties of utility functions (and their associated demand functions). Additionally, this is a local property, so some goods may be normal for certain prices or wealth levels and inferior for others. Often, using these terms implicitly means that the above conditions hold for all (p, w). An immediate implication of the proposition above is that at any (p, w), there must be at least one normal good. We may also be interested in how the fraction of income spent on a particular good changes with wealth. The fraction of wealth spent on good i is p i x i (p, w) j p jx j (p, w) = p ix i (p, w) w If this fraction is increasing, then the good is called a luxury good. Otherwise, it is called a necessary good. When this fraction is constant for all w, we say that preferences are homothetic. If the optimal choice can be written in the form then x(p, w) = z(p) w p i x i (p, w) j p jx j (p, w) = p iz i (p) j p jz j (p) 3

and thus the fraction is independent of w, meaning preferences are homothetic. Notice that this is the case for Cobb-Douglas, CES, and Leontieff preferences. It is not the case for the modified Cobb-Douglas preferences we looked at. Example 1. Consider the utility function u(x 1, x 2 ) = x γ 1 1 + x γ 2 2 where γ 1 = 3 and γ 4 2 = 1. Let p 4 1 = p 2 = 1. Find the optimal choices as functions of w. Which good is inferior and which is normal? What about luxury vs. necessary? 2.2 Price Effects Now we re going to do the same exercise but for price changes instead of wealth changes. Again, here we change prices while keeping wealth fixed. Decreasing the price of good i will rotate the budget set out towards good i. Increasing the price of good i will do the opposite. We have two analogous classifications for price effects Ordinary Good: Consumption decreases when price increases Giffen Good: Consumption increases when price increases 0 As before, these are local properties and may or may not hold at different prices and wealth levels. Giffen goods are remarkably hard to spot in the wild. In addition to direct price effects, there are also cross-good effects. That is, we can look at how the change in the price of good i affects consumption of good j. We classify these effects as Substitutes: Consumption of good i increases with the price of good j p j > 0 4

Complements: Consumption of good i decreases with the price of good j p j < 0 One important things to note is that in settings where there are only 2 goods, it can be that good i is a substitute for good j, but good j is not a substitute for good i. 3 Price Effects Up until now, we have been considering changes in prices or wealth keeping the other fixed. Now we wish to determine the total of effect of a price change on consumption. To do this, we must switch back to thinking about endowments. This way, price has a direct effect as well as a wealth effect, since changing prices also changes the value of a consumers endowment, that is, their wealth. To avoid confusion, I will explicitly label the functions x e (p, e) and x w (p, w). Recall that these two functions are related by x e (p, e) = x w (p, p e) Differentiating the above equation with respect to p i, we arrive at x e i (p, e) }{{} net price effect = xw i (p, w) }{{} pure price effect + xw i (p, w) e i } w {{} pure wealth effect This decomposes the net price effect into the pure price effect and the wealth effect. Rearranging yields = xe i (p, e) xw i (p, w) e i w The value of the endowment e here is arbitrary. Suppose it is the case that e = x e (p, e) = x. Assuming increasing utility, this will satisfy w = p e = p x. Therefore = xe i (p, x ) xw i (p, w) x i w 5

The above equations is called the Slutsky equation. We can plug this equation into the decomposition equation above to yield an alternate form x e i (p, e) = xe i (p, x ) xw i (p, e) (x i e i ) w Now consider the following result. Lemma 1. When the optimal choice is the endowment, the net substitution effect is negative. That is, when x e (p, e) = e = x, we have x e i (p, x ) Proof. Consider if we go from p i to p i. Let the new price vector with other elements unchanged to p. We wish to show that x e i (p, x ) x e i (p, x ) p i p i Since x is the optimal choice in B(p, x ), it is preferred to every point in B(p, e). If x e (p, x ) = x e (p, x ), then we are all set. Otherwise, the new point x = x e (p, x ) must be strictly preferred to x. In this case, x cannot be in B(p, x ). It is however, in B(p, x ). These imply Rearranging Summing p x > p x and p x p x p (x x ) < 0 and p (x x ) (p p) (x x ) < 0 and since p and p differ only in the i th dimension (p i p i )(x i x i ) < 0 x i x i p i p i < 0 when p i p i, as we wished to show. Taking the limit as p i p i, yields the derivative form. 6

Tying this back to the Slutsky equation, we can also see the following result Proposition 2. If good i is a normal good, then it is also an ordinary good. Proof. Being a normal good means that 0 w Looking back to the Slutsky equation, having established that the first term is negative and subtracting a positive term, we conclude that meaning good i is an ordinary good. Using the alternate form of the Slutsky equation, we can conclude using a proof similar to the above that Proposition 3. If good i is a normal good and x i e i, then demand is decreasing in the price of i, that is x e i (p, e) Example 2 (Cobb-Douglas). Recall from last lecture that with Cobb-Douglas utility, the agent spends a fraction α i of his wealth on good i. This implies demand functions of the form x e i (p, e) = α i(p e) and x w i (p, w) = α iw p i p i All goods are normal goods with C-D since = α i > 0 w p i Thus they are ordinary goods as well, as we can check Now let s find the net price effect = α iw p 2 i x e i (p, e) = p iα i e i α i (p e) p 2 i < 0 = α [ ] i p p 2 i e i w < 0 i So here the net price effect is negative, regardless of whether x i is larger or smaller than e i. This is fine, since that was only a sufficient condition. 7

4 Offer Curves Recall before we discussed the concept of a wealth offer curve. Given any price p, this function mapped from any price level w into the optimal choice x w (p, w). Now we ll consider the same concept for prices. Thus, the price offer curve is a function that maps from prices p into an optimal choice x w (p, w), given some w or e. Consider the case of only two goods. Here, we need know only the price ratio, rather than each price individually. So the offer curve is a function that maps from one positive real number (the price ratio) into an allocation x R 2 +, meaning it is a curve in 2-dimensions. Imagine we broke the Cartesian plane into 4 quadrants as usual (1 in the northeast, increasing counterclockwise), but we center them at the endowment rather than the origin. We can say the following about the offer curve 1. The offer curve can never lie quadrant 1. If a consumption bundle has more of both good 1 and 2 than the endowment, it must cost more and thus be outside of the budget set. 2. So long as utility is increasing, the optimal choice will always lie on the budget line, so the offer curve cannot lie in quadrant 3. 3. As p 1 0, x 1. Similarly, as p 2 0, x 2. If the price of a good goes to zero, then the consumer should start optimally choosing more and more of it. 4. The offer curve is continuous. We didn t prove it formally, but continuity of the optimal choice arises from concavity of the utility function. This is result is called Berge s Maximum Theorem. 5. Since the offer curve is continuous and must pass between quadrants 2 and 4 without going through quadrants 1 and 3, it must pass through the endowment at some point. Offers curves can be useful for understanding the intuition behind certain results. They ll be of use next lecture when we start discussing Walrasian equilibrium. 8

5 Labor Supply 9