The Reinvestment Rate Assumption Fallacy for IRR and NPV: A Pedagogical Note

Similar documents
What is an Investment Project s Implied Rate of Return?

A Note on Capital Budgeting: Treating a Replacement Project as Two Mutually Exclusive Projects

Chapter. Capital Budgeting Techniques: Certainty and Risk. Across the Disciplines Why This Chapter Matters to You LEARNING GOALS

Inconsistencies In Textbook Presentation Of Capital Budgeting Criteria Frank Elston, ( Concordia College

Chapter 8. Ross, Westerfield and Jordan, ECF 4 th ed 2004 Solutions

Chapter 10 The Basics of Capital Budgeting: Evaluating Cash Flows ANSWERS TO SELECTED END-OF-CHAPTER QUESTIONS

CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW

WHAT IS CAPITAL BUDGETING?

Relevance or irrelevance of retention for dividend policy irrelevance

UWE has obtained warranties from all depositors as to their title in the material deposited and as to their right to deposit such material.

Capital Budgeting CFA Exam Level-I Corporate Finance Module Dr. Bulent Aybar

CHAPTER 9 NET PRESENT VALUE AND OTHER INVESTMENT CRITERIA

The internal rate of return (IRR) is a venerable technique for evaluating deterministic cash flow streams.

A Note on Effective Teaching and Interpretation of Compound Return Measures of Investment Performance

Running Head: FINAL PORTFOLIO PROJECT 1

The Use of Modern Capital Budgeting Techniques. Howard Lawrence

Many decisions in operations management involve large

Are Capital Structure Decisions Relevant?

CHAPTER 6 PROJECT INTERACTIONS, SIDE COSTS, AND SIDE BENEFITS. Mutually Exclusive Projects

The Mechanics of the Weitzman-Gollier Puzzles

Capital Budgeting Process and Techniques 93. Chapter 7: Capital Budgeting Process and Techniques

My Favorite Two Corporate Finance Puzzles

Development Discussion Papers

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Question: Insurance doesn t have much depreciation or inventory. What accounting methods affect return on book equity for insurance?

MBF1223 Financial Management Prepared by Dr Khairul Anuar

Chapter 1 Microeconomics of Consumer Theory

FINANCE 402 Capital Budgeting and Corporate Objectives. Syllabus

The Professional Refereed Journal of the Association of Hospitality Financial Management Educators

Corporate Finance, Module 4: Net Present Value vs Other Valuation Models

Global Financial Management

Average Internal Rate of Return and investment decisions: a new perspective

STATEMENT OF CASH FLOWS

Time value of money-concepts and Calculations Prof. Bikash Mohanty Department of Chemical Engineering Indian Institute of Technology, Roorkee

Copyright Disclaimer under Section 107 of the Copyright Act 1976, allowance is made for "fair use" for purposes such as criticism, comment, news

Money Demand in India

Examining RADR as a Valuation Method in Capital Budgeting

Investment Decision Criteria. Principles Applied in This Chapter. Learning Objectives

Capital Budgeting Decisions

CAPITAL BUDGETING. John D. Stowe, CFA Athens, Ohio, U.S.A. Jacques R. Gagné, CFA Quebec City, Quebec, Canada

CHAPTER 2. Financial Reporting: Its Conceptual Framework CONTENT ANALYSIS OF END-OF-CHAPTER ASSIGNMENTS

CAPITAL BUDGETING TECHNIQUES (CHAPTER 9)

Lecture 6 Capital Budgeting Decision

Cash Flow and the Time Value of Money

MGT201 Lecture No. 11

The following points highlight the three time-adjusted or discounted methods of capital budgeting, i.e., 1. Net Present Value

Investment Decision Criteria. Principles Applied in This Chapter. Disney s Capital Budgeting Decision

Uberrimae Fidei and Adverse Selection: the equitable legal judgment of Insurance Contracts

KING FAHAD UNIVERSITY OF PETROLEUM & MINERALS COLLEGE OF ENVIROMENTAL DESGIN CONSTRUCTION ENGINEERING & MANAGEMENT DEPARTMENT

INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF MULTIDISCIPLINARY RESEARCH CENTRE (IJMRC)

COPYRIGHTED MATERIAL. Time Value of Money Toolbox CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION CASH FLOWS

CHAPTER 2. Financial Reporting: Its Conceptual Framework CONTENT ANALYSIS OF END-OF-CHAPTER ASSIGNMENTS

A PUZZLE FOR TEACHING THE CONSTANT GROWTH STOCK PRICING MODEL Lynda S. Livingston, University of Puget Sound

Corporate Finance Theory FRL CRN: P. Sarmas Summer Quarter 2012 Building 24B Room 1417 Tuesday & Thursday: 4:00 5:50 p.m.

A lower bound on seller revenue in single buyer monopoly auctions

Lease Evaluation and Dividend Imputation. Kevin Davis Department of Accounting and Finance University of Melbourne ABSTRACT

Developing Time Horizons for Use in Portfolio Analysis

UNIVERSIDAD DEL CEMA Buenos Aires Argentina. Serie DOCUMENTOS DE TRABAJO. Área: Finanzas

CMA Part 2. Financial Decision Making

New and less common ways of measuring returns

A Study on Cost of Capital

Retirement Withdrawal Rates and Portfolio Success Rates: What Can the Historical Record Teach Us?

J ohn D. S towe, CFA. CFA Institute Charlottesville, Virginia. J acques R. G agn é, CFA

Budgeting and Accounting Perspectives

INVESTMENT CRITERIA. Net Present Value (NPV)

Discussion of: Inflation and Financial Performance: What Have We Learned in the. Last Ten Years? (John Boyd and Bruce Champ) Nicola Cetorelli

Corporate Finance Theory FRL CRN: P. Sarmas Summer Quarter 2014 Building 163 Room 2032 Monday and Wednesday: 8:00 a.m. 9:50 a.m.

DOWNLOAD PDF ANALYZING CAPITAL EXPENDITURES

ADVANTAGES AND LIMITATIONS OF THE FINANCIAL RATIOS USED IN THE FINANCIAL DIAGNOSIS OF THE ENTERPRISE

M.V.S.R Engineering College. Department of Business Managment

Kavous Ardalan. Marist College, New York, USA

What causes the equity premium?

University 18 Lessons Financial Management. Unit 2: Capital Budgeting Decisions

12 Bounds. on Option Prices. Answers to Questions and Problems

European lease pricing and optimisation

Financial Management Warsaw School of Economics

The NPV profile and IRR PITFALLS OF IRR. Years Cash flow Discount rate 10% NPV 472,27 IRR 11,6% NPV

Holding Gains and Interest Accrual

The Cost of Capital. Principles Applied in This Chapter. The Cost of Capital: An Overview

The Cost of Capital. Chapter 14

Investment Information and Criterions. Name of student: Admission: Course: Institution: Instructor: Date of Submission:

Capital Budgeting Theory and Capital Budgeting Practice. University of Texas at El Paso. Pierre C. Ehe MBA

Association of Accounting Technicians response to the Financial Reporting Council (FRC) consultation document Improving the Statement of Cash Flows

A Different Approach of Tax Progressivity Measurement

FUNDING PENSION LIABILITIES: EMPLOYEE VERSUS FIRM PERSPECTIVES. Robert S. Kemp, Jr., CPA

TAXATION CONSIDERATIONS IN ECONOMIC DAMAGES CALCULATIONS

Corporate Finance: Introduction to Capital Budgeting

Capital Budgeting (Including Leasing)

Investing and Financing-Type Projects: A Generalization to Investments

A simple model for cash flow management in nonprofits

INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF MANAGEMENT RESEARCH AND REVIEW

RECOGNITION OF GOVERNMENT PENSION OBLIGATIONS

Reviewing CAPTIALIZATION RATES

SEF Working paper: 19/2011 December 2011

15.414: COURSE REVIEW. Main Ideas of the Course. Approach: Discounted Cashflows (i.e. PV, NPV): CF 1 CF 2 P V = (1 + r 1 ) (1 + r 2 ) 2

IPO Underpricing: The Owners Perspective

Internal Rate Of Return Problems And Solutions

SYLLABUS: AGEC AGRICULTURAL FINANCE

CASH FLOWS OF INVESTMENT PROJECTS A MANAGERIAL APPROACH

Suppose you plan to purchase

Transcription:

MPRA Munich Personal RePEc Archive The Reinvestment Rate Assumption Fallacy for IRR and NPV: A Pedagogical Note Carlo Alberto Magni and John D. Martin University of Modena and Reggio Emilia, Baylor University December 2017 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/83889/ MPRA Paper No. 83889, posted 11 January 2018 20:09 UTC

2017 The Reinvestment Rate Assumption Fallacy for IRR and NPV A PEDAGOGICAL NOTE CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN

Table of Contents 1 Introduction... 1 2 The fallacy... 1 3 Potential sources of the reinvestment rate fallacy... 2 Early contributions to capital budgeting literature... 2 Ranking Alternative Investments... 3 The multiple IRR problem... 3 The modified IRR... 3 The scale effect... 4 What s the harm of assuming required reinvestment rates?... 5 Is this really a problem of semantics?... 5 4 Summary remarks... 5 References... 7 CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN 1

The Reinvestment Rate Assumption Fallacy for IRR and NPV: A Pedagogical Note 1 Introduction The notion that the internal rate of return (IRR) and net present value (NPV) have reinvestment rate assumptions built into them has long been settled in the academic finance literature. 1 Specifically, there are no reinvestment rate assumptions built into, or implicit to, the computation and use of either the IRR or NPV. Once an investment s cash flows are received they can be distributed to the firm s creditors or shareholders without any necessity to reinvest them. However, there persists the notion that IRR and NPV have implicit reinvestment rate assumptions embedded in them. For example, the following statement was taken from Investopedia:... the traditional internal rate of return (IRR) assumes the cash flows from a project are reinvested at the IRR. 2 Here are two more quotes taken from different websites, that focus on student users that make the same point: The IRR rule assumes that intermediate cash flows from the project get reinvested at the IRR. Implicit is the assumption that the firm has an infinite stream of projects yielding similar IRRs. 3 NPV and PI assume reinvestment at the discount rate. IRR assumes reinvestment at the internal rate of return. 4 In this brief note, we first review the theoretical underpinnings of the rate of return assumption fallacy. Next, we offer two possible origins from the academic finance literature that may be responsible for the fallacy. Specifically, Ezra Solomon s discussion of the ranking of mutually exclusive investments and Jack Hirshleifer s discussion of the multiple IRR problem. We conclude that the reinvestment assumption is a sufficient condition, not an implicit assumption, for solving the problems of conflicting ranking and multiple IRRs. 2 The fallacy To illustrate the fallacy of rate of return assumptions behind IRR and NPV we use a simple example. Here s how it works. Consider a security market in which borrowing and lending rates (r) are the same. Assume now that an investor has an opportunity to undertake a project with cash-flow stream f = ( C 0, f 1,, f n ), where f t > 0 for each t and C 0 is the initial cash outlay required to finance the investment. The investor may then borrow an amount equal to the present value of the project s future cashflows, i.e., V 0 = n t=1 f t (1 + r) t. By taking these actions, the investor (i) realizes a cash inflow equal to V 0 from the loan proceeds, (ii) pays C 0 to finance the investment, and (iii) obligates the 1 Dudley (1972, p. 908) put it bluntly, There is no such assumption implicit in the technique. More recent papers include Rich and Rose (2014) and Walker et. al. (2010). 2 https://www.investopedia.com/terms/m/mirr.asp. 3 https://www.coursehero.com/file/p7plecl5/the-irr-rule-assumes-that-intermediate-cash-flows-on-the-projectget-reinvested/. 4 https://www.boundless.com/finance/textbooks/boundless-finance-textbook/capital-budgeting-11/introductionto-capital-budgeting-91/reinvestment-assumptions-394-8295/. CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN 1

project s future cash flows to repay the loan. The resulting net cash-flow vector then is (V 0 C 0, 0,0,,0) = (NPV, 0,0,,0). Of course, the project is worth undertaking if and only if NPV = n t=0 f t (1 + r) t > 0. Note that since all the project s future cash flows are converted to their present value equivalent via the loan, and the project s future cash flows are committed to repaying the loan, there are no future cash flows available to reinvest! That NPV analysis does not assume reinvestment can be demonstrated in several other ways, abstracting from any consideration of borrowing. Most notably, consider the price V 0 of a portfolio traded in the market replicating the project s cash flow. Shareholders may undertake the project by investing C 0 or buy a replicating portfolio by investing V 0. The sequence of prospective cash flows is the same from both alternatives, so acceptance only depends on the difference between the project s cost and the price of the portfolio (i.e., the NPV), not on reinvestments of cash flows. 5 As for IRR, assuming f = ( C 0, f 1,, f n ) is a conventional cash flow stream (outflows preceding inflows), the NPV function is monotonically decreasing so that NPV > 0 if and only if IRR > r. As the condition NPV > 0 has been determined with no reinvestment consideration, the condition IRR > r is not tied to reinvestment consideration as well. The IRR is the (assumed constant) rate of return on the invested capital, period by period. The condition that IRR > r only means that if, in any given period, an investor invests an amount of capital equal to the capital that remains invested in the project, then the rate of return earned with the former would be greater than the rate earned with the latter. 3 Potential sources of the reinvestment rate fallacy How is it that many analysts continue to refer to the IRR as a required reinvestment rate for future cash flows when using the IRR as a project evaluation tool, and the cost of capital as the required reinvestment rate when using NPV? The answer may lie in some of the early writings regarding the difficulties encountered when (i) ranking mutually exclusive investment opportunities (where IRR and NPV rankings are often in conflict), and (ii) multiple IRRs arise in some nonconventional projects. Early contributions to capital budgeting literature In the 1950s the finance literature devoted to the analysis of mutually exclusive investment projects and the analysis of multiple IRRs both incorporated consideration for reinvestment rates. The discussion of reinvestment rates in this context, we believe, may well be the source of the confusion about reinvestment rates and project IRRs and NPVs. For example, it seemed natural to consider reinvesting cash flows as one way to eliminate interim cash flows which were the source of the ranking conflicts between NPV and IRR or to overcome the difficulties encountered in comparing mutually exclusive investment proposals with different initial investments and/or different investment lives and/or different cash-flow patterns, and for projects whose cash flows have multiple IRRs. Even more so considering that, in 1950s, modern finance was not yet fully established, and the concept of terminal value seemed still common, as opposed to the idea of 5 The rate r is the expected rate of return of the replicating portfolio. CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN 2

a present value equal to the price of a portfolio replicating the project s cash flows. 6 Significant contributions to this discussion came from Solomon (1956) and Hirshleifer (1958) and both suggested that incorporating consideration of reinvestment rates for interim project cash flows might prove beneficial. Ranking Alternative Investments Solomon (1956) provided an important contribution to the analysis of mutually exclusive investment alternatives in which he raised the question as to implicit reinvestment rates for IRR and NPV. 7 In short, Solomon believed that both NPV and IRR have implicit reinvestment rates, the former at the cost of capital, the latter at the IRR itself. According to the author, the cause of the conflict lies in the different reinvestment assumptions of IRR and NPV. To solve the conflict, he suggested that the analyst make an explicit and common assumption regarding the rate at which funds can be reinvested up to the investment s terminal date to arrive at an appropriate ranking: If a common assumption is adopted, both approaches will always rank projects identically (p. 126). The multiple IRR problem Hirshleifer (1958) provided an early and important discussion of the problem of multiple IRRs that can arise in projects that have non-conventional investment cash flows (see Section III B. of his paper). While he suggested that the IRR assumes reinvestment at the IRR itself, he criticized this implicit assumption, deeming it unrealistic. Consistent with Solomon, Hirshleifer recommended making an explicit reinvestment rate estimate for the interim cash flows, which would turn the project into a course of action with a unique IRR (later called Modified Internal Rate of Return). This unique IRR is compatible with the NPV of the entire course of action, in the sense that NPV is positive if and only if the MIRR is greater than the cost of capital. The modified IRR Solomon (1956) and Hirshleifer (1958) may then be considered forerunners of the modified internal rate of return (MIRR) approach. If multiple IRRs occur only in projects with interim cash flows, then Solomon s and Hirshleifer s arguments may be used to solve the multiple-irr problem: making an NPVinvariant modification of the project such that the modified project has no interim cash flows, and consequently the project s IRR will be unique. Among the infinitely many ways to adjust a cash-flow stream, one may consider the explicit reinvestment of interim cash flows up to the terminal. However, the assumption of reinvestment of interim cash flows at some rate is introduced only for making the multiple IRR problem (and the ranking problem) disappear, not because any reinvestment option is implicit in the IRR procedure, as seen above. Note, however, that by modifying the cash-flow stream, the meaning of the resulting rate (MIRR) changes. Further, the MIRR does not measure the project s rate of return because it takes account of 6 Which in turn, is equal to the price that the project would have if it were traded in the security market. 7 Renshaw (1957) summarized Solomon s position on reinvestment rates as follows: The contribution of the Solomon article was to point out that the apparent conflict between these two ranking procedures was due to differing implicit assumptions about reinvestment rates (the present-value approach assumes reinvestment of intermediate cash receipts at the discounting rate, while the internal rate of return approach assumes reinvestment at the internal rate) and to suggest that the conflict could be eliminated by making an explicit assumption about the expected return from reinvestment. p. 193 A key observation here is the statement regarding implicit assumptions regarding reinvestment rates. CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN 3

the reinvestments of the interim cash flows, which have nothing to do with the original investment opportunity. The MIRR is simply the internal rate of return of a course of action which includes the project being analyzed and other projects that are associated with the reinvestment of interim cash flows. Ross et. al., 2011, p. 250 describes the MIRR as follows: it s a rate of return on a modified set of cash flows, not the project s actual cash flows. Therefore, the MIRR is the IRR of a portfolio of projects, not the original investment. The key point here is that a project s rate of return should not be affected by the choice of a reinvestment rate for its cash flows. Brealey, Myers and Allen (2011) put it very succinctly The prospective return on another independent investment should never be allowed to influence the investment decision (p. 141). The MIRR also solves the problem of conflicting ranking (if the initial outlays are the same): The comparison of any two MIRRs will result in the same ranking as the comparison of the two associated NPVs. In other words, explicitly incorporating consideration for the reinvestment rate is sufficient to make IRR and NPV consistent and to ensure existence and uniqueness of IRR. As a result, scholars and practitioners have mistaken a sufficient condition for an implicit assumption. Scale effects Keane (1979) supplied an enlightening view that contributes to dispel the misconception of the reinvestment assumption. He attributed the problem of ranking projects as evidence of the scale effect. That is, the conflict between NPV and IRR ranking is due to difference in scale of the projects under consideration, not to different reinvestment assumptions. By scale one should not merely refer to initial outlays, but to the total units of capital outstanding and capital length of the project (see Keane 1979, pp. 53-54). While NPV considers project scale as well as economic efficiency, IRR only measures economic efficiency, so it is not adequate for ranking projects. It is worth noting that the conflict between the notion of rate of return and NPV disappears if explicit reinvestment assumptions are made on competing projects (if the initial outlays are the same), 8 because this changes the project scale in a way that makes the IRR ranking and the NPV ranking identical (as long as the initial outlays are equal). 9 In other words, reinvestment assumptions can be used to solve the problem of conflicting ranking. 10 It is worth noting that, while not mentioned by Keane (1979), the scale effect is also the essential reason why reinvestment assumption solves the multiple-irr problem: indeed, it can be shown that, if interim cash flows are reinvested, then the resulting modified project possesses outstanding capital which has the same sign in each period (i.e., a higher scale), thereby ensuring unique a IRR. 11 8 The NPV must be computed on the modified cash-flow streams. 9 It may be proved that a higher IRR is associated with a higher scale. Therefore, the project with higher IRR also has a higher value created. 10 The role of the scale effect and the relation of scale to rate of return is analyzed in Magni et al. 2017, where a reconciliation between NPV ranking and rate-of-return ranking is supplied with no need of assuming any reinvestment. See also Keefe and Rousch (2001) for a relatively recent paper on the inexistence of reinvestment assumptions. 11 Multiple IRRs may not arise if capital outstanding has the same sign in each period. CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN 4

What s the harm of assuming required reinvestment rates? To illustrate the type of problems that can arise when assuming implicit reinvestment rates consider the following paraphrased conversation that occurred between the CFO and a financial analyst at a major public firm (relayed to the authors via a phone conversation): We have an investment opportunity that promises an extremely high IRR of 30%. However, we are worried about the decision to undertake the investment since the firm does not expect to have investment opportunities to reinvest those cash flows to earn 30%. The implication being that without the opportunity to reinvest the cash thrown off by the 30% project at a similar rate of return, the project s IRR would not be realized. This type of reasoning can be quite misleading and costly to the firm. Specifically, it might lead the firm to avoid very high rate of return projects (paradoxically, the higher the IRR of the project, the more problematic is the project s acceptance). In fact, the cash flows the investment opportunity promises can simply be distributed as they are received to the firm s creditors in the form of interest and/or principal payments or to stockholders via dividends or share repurchases, and the firm will realize the promised 30% return, regardless of the destination of those cash flows, because the IRR is the return generated by one dollar of capital that remains invested in the project. As such, the IRR does not have anything to say about the rate of return of the capital that is divested from the project. Instead IRR speaks to the return earned on the capital that is invested in the project. Is this really a problem of semantics? To this point we have been using adjectives like implicit and explicit when referring to reinvestment rates. Is it possible that some of the misunderstanding about reinvestment rates has something to do with language? For example, when an analyst attempts to move project cash flows either forward or backward in time in such a way as to not alter the project s NPV, then the rate of interest that preserves the investment s NPV is the rate used to evaluate the investment (i.e., the cost of capital). Similarly, if the analyst wishes to preserve the project s IRR, the rate of interest that should be used to move cash flows either forward or backward is the IRR of the project itself. Does this observation mean that these rates of interest are implied reinvestment rates? Asked somewhat differently, do interim cash flows have to be reinvested to realize the promised NPV or IRR? The answer is, of course, no. Remember that the investment cash flows do not need to be reinvested to guarantee the NPV or IRR of the project. It is easy to imagine that this relationship between interest rates and preserving NPV or IRR might be misconstrued to mean these rates are required or mandatory when they are not. Reinvestment is not implicit in the IRR and NPV; rather, it is a sufficient condition for solving ranking conflicts between NPV and IRR and the multiple-irr problem. 4 Summary remarks Despite demonstrated theory to the contrary, many continue to believe that NPV and IRR have implicit reinvestment rates. The reinvestment rate for NPV being the cost of capital for the investment and for IRR it is the IRR itself. The notion that project cash flows must be reinvested to assure the investor realizes the IRR as a rate of return (should cash flows materialize as expected) or that these cash flows must earn the cost of capital to earn the estimated NPV is simply not the case. Once received, the CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN 5

investment cash flows can be distributed to the firm s creditors or shareholders, or simply held in shortterm investments awaiting reinvestment at some future date at a yet unknown rate of return. We offer a possible explanation for the persistence of the reinvestment rate assumption that derive out of some of the foundational work on the evaluation of investments. Specifically, the answer may lie in some of the early writings regarding the ranking of mutually exclusive investment opportunities where IRR and NPV rankings are often in conflict and the problem of multiple IRRs arising in some nonconventional projects. This assumption may solve the problems, which is an explanation of why scholars and practitioners turned a sufficient condition into an implicit assumption. The problem with believing in the reinvestment rate assumption is that it can bias corporate investment decisions. Specifically, where using the IRR is presumed to require that the cash thrown off by the investment must be reinvested to earn the IRR, corporate decision makers may shy away from very high IRR projects, believing that a lack of equally high rate of return investments might jeopardize their realization of a high rate on the initial project. CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN 6

References R. Brealey, S. Myers, and F. Allen, 2011, Principles of Corporate Finance, 10 th ed., (McGraw-Hill Irwin). C. Dudley, 1972, A note on reinvestment assumptions in choosing between net present value and internal rate of return, The Journal of Finance, Vol. 27, No. 4 (September), pp. 907-15. J. Hirshleifer, 1958, On the theory of optimal investment decisions, Journal of Political Economy, 66, 329-352. S.M. Keane 1979, The Internal Rate of Return and the reinvestment fallacy, Abacus, 15(1), 44-55. S.P. Keef and M.L. Roush, 2001, Discounted cash flow methods and the fallacious reinvestment assumption: a review of recent texts, Accounting Education: An International Journal, 10(1), 105-116. C.A. Magni, P. Veronese, R. Graziani, 2017, Chisini means and and rational decision-making: Equivalence of investment criteria. Mathematics and Financial Economics. DOI 10.1007/s11579-017-0201-4 S. Rich and J. Rose, 2014, Re-examining an old question: Does the IRR Method Implicitly Assume a Reinvestment Rate? Journal of Financial Education, Spring/Summer, pp. 152-166. E. Renshaw, 1957, A note on the arithmetic of capital budgeting decisions, The Journal of Business, Vol. XXX, No. 3 (July), pp. 193-201. S. Ross, R. W Westerfield, and B. D. Jordan, 2011, Essentials of Corporate Finance, 7 th ed., (McGraw-Hill Irwin). E. Solomon, 1956, The Arithmetic of Capital Budgeting Decisions, Journal of Business, 29, pp. 124-29. J. Walker, H. Check, JR., and K. Randall, 2010, Does the internal rate of return calculation require a reinvestment rate assumption? There is still no consensus, Journal of the Academy of Business Education, 11, Proceedings, November. CARLO ALBERTO MAGNI AND JOHN D. MARTIN 7