The Phillips curve (PC) is 60 years old, yet the debate. Does the Phillips curve still exist?

Similar documents
ASYMMETRIES IN THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN INFLATION AND ACTIVITY

Persistent low inflation in the euro area: Mismeasurement rather than a cause for concern?

Recent developments in the euro area suggest. What caused current account imbalances in euro area periphery countries?

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

Gross domestic product per capita in France and in advanced economies: the role of productivity and employment

The outbreak of the 2008 financial crisis led to a. Rue de la Banque No 53 December 2017

Rue de la Banque No. 52 November 2017

The role of China in the trade slowdown

EMPIRICAL ASSESSMENT OF THE PHILLIPS CURVE

The Phillips curve rumours of its death are greatly exaggerated

Since 2014 the macroeconomic situation in the. Rue de la Banque No. 32 October 2016

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Is US inflation picking up?

Characteristics of the euro area business cycle in the 1990s

September 21, 2016 Bank of Japan

According to the life cycle theory, households take. Do wealth inequalities have an impact on consumption? 1

Projections for the Portuguese Economy:

Global Slack as a Determinant of US Inflation *

The ECB Survey of Professional Forecasters. First quarter of 2017

Some Preliminary Evidence on the Globalization-Inflation Nexus *

Regional convergence in Spain:

What Is the Best Strategy for Extending the U.S. Economy s Expansion?

Labour market dualities The impact on aggregate wage growth

Why does the recovery show so little inflation?

Inflation forecasts in the euro area: New Insights from Phillips Curve estimates and quantile regressions

Models of the Neoclassical synthesis

DANMARKS NATIONALBANK

The ECB Survey of Professional Forecasters. Fourth quarter of 2016

Projections for the Portuguese economy in 2017

EXTENSIVE ABSTRACT. Can Phillips curve explain the recent behavior of inflation? Evidence from G7 countries

Should we reject the natural rate hypothesis?

Fixing the Astrolabe:

Asian Economic and Financial Review, 2016, 6(4): Asian Economic and Financial Review. ISSN(e): /ISSN(p):

economic fluctuations. Part 1.

The external and domestic drivers of inflation: the case study of Hungary

Heterogeneity and the ECB s monetary policy

What Explains Growth and Inflation Dispersions in EMU?

Discussion of The Role of Expectations in Inflation Dynamics

2010 Rybczynski Prize Entry Spare a Thought for Spare Capacity

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

Is the Phillips curve dead? - results for Portugal. Sara Serra Banco de Portugal. April 2018

ANNEX 3. The ins and outs of the Baltic unemployment rates

Estimating the Natural Rate of Unemployment in Hong Kong

What is the economic outlook for OECD countries? An interim assessment

Although global economic activity now appears to. Uncertainty and macroeconomics: transmission channels and policy implications

II.2. Member State vulnerability to changes in the euro exchange rate ( 35 )

Svante Öberg: GDP growth and resource utilisation

Economic developments in the euro area

Liquidity Matters: Money Non-Redundancy in the Euro Area Business Cycle

INDICATORS OF FINANCIAL DISTRESS IN MATURE ECONOMIES

Slack and Cyclically Sensitive Inflation by Stock and Watson

The main assumptions underlying the scenario are as follows (see the table):

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

Economic ProjEctions for

Explaining and Forecasting Euro Area Inflation: the Role of Domestic and Global Factors

How to Extend the U.S. Expansion: A Suggestion

Time-varying wage Phillips curves in the euro area with a new measure for labor market slack

The negative relationship between the unemployment rate and inflation, first

1.) Recent inflation divergence in CEE focus on food prices and services

Svante Öberg: Potential GDP, resource utilisation and monetary policy

A measure of supercore inflation for the eurozone

LABOUR MARKET DEVELOPMENTS IN THE EURO AREA AND THE UNITED STATES SINCE THE BEGINNING OF THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS

Potential output, economic slack and THE LINK TO nominal developments since the start of the crisis

The ECB Survey of Professional Forecasters. First quarter of 2018

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

How anchored are inflation expectations in Asia? Evidence from surveys of professional forecasters. Aaron Mehrotra and James Yetman 1

More on Modern Monetary Policy Rules

Is there a decoupling between soft and hard data? The relationship between GDP growth and the ESI

Euro area outlook for 2015

Policy Brief. Some Unpleasant Euro Arithmetic * Summary. Guillaume Gaulier & Vincent Vicard

SENSITIVITY OF THE INDEX OF ECONOMIC WELL-BEING TO DIFFERENT MEASURES OF POVERTY: LICO VS LIM

Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Inflation Targeting on the Risk Premium

Inflation Report. January March 2013

Outlook for the Mexican Economy Alejandro Díaz de León Carrillo, Governor, Banco de México. April, 2018

Estimating Okun s Law for Malta

Economic developments in the euro area

An interim assessment

Monetary Policy Objectives During the Crisis: An Overview of Selected Southeast European Countries

D6.3 Policy Brief: The role of debt for fiscal effectiveness during crisis and normal times

Projections for the Portuguese economy:

The ECB Survey of Professional Forecasters. Second quarter of 2017

September 2017 ECB staff macroeconomic projections for the euro area 1

Measuring the natural interest rate in Brazil

Quarterly Currency Outlook

Advanced Macroeconomics 4. The Zero Lower Bound and the Liquidity Trap

54 ECB RESULTS OF THE ECB SURVEY OF PROFESSIONAL FORECASTERS FOR THE FOURTH QUARTER OF 2009

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, November 2016 Quiz, Unit VI, Stabilization Policies

Global Economic and Market Outlook for Gavyn Davies, Chairman, Fulcrum Asset Management

Economic Policy Uncertainty and Inflation Expectations

Labor market hierarchies - The impact of labor market dualities on aggregate wage growth. Vienna, November 21, 2017

Session 9. The Interactions Between Cyclical and Long-term Dynamics: The Role of Inflation

ARTICLE Strong economic activity but subdued wage increases

MCCI ECONOMIC OUTLOOK. Novembre 2017

RESEARCH PAPERS IN ECONOMICS. GDP Trend Deviations and the Yield Spread: the Case of Five E.U. Countries Periklis Gogas* and Ioannis Pragidis

Erdem Başçi: Recent economic and financial developments in Turkey

The main assumptions underlying the scenario are as follows (see the table):

Estimating the Impact of Changes in the Federal Funds Target Rate on Market Interest Rates from the 1980s to the Present Day

Core Inflation and the Business Cycle

2.10 PROJECTIONS. Macroeconomic scenario for Italy (percentage changes on previous year, unless otherwise indicated)

Global Economic Outlook January 2015

Transcription:

Does the Phillips curve still exist? Clémence Berson, Louis de Charsonville Pavel Diev, Violaine Faubert Laurent Ferrara, Sophie Guilloux Nefussi Yannick Kalantzis, Antoine Lalliard Julien Matheron, Matteo Mogliani Directorate General Economics and International Relations This Rue de la Banque presents the findings of research carried out at the Banque de France. The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Banque de France. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors. Estimates from the Banque de France show that the slope of the Phillips curve in the euro area has remained weak but stable and significantly different from zero since the crisis. In the G7 countries, the coefficient of past inflation has become relatively insignificant since the 1980s, suggesting a shift towards a so-called non-accelerating curve. Global demand conditions are captured by import prices, including oil prices. The persistence of a negative output gap and the fall in oil prices largely explain the low level of inflation in the euro area since 2014. However, other factors such as weak wage dynamics or even the risk of an unanchoring of inflation expectations may have played out, the latter risk having called for a strong monetary policy response. The Phillips curve (PC) is 60 years old, yet the debate on its validity remains active and intense. Today, many observers are raising the question as to the disappearance of the PC (The Economist, 2017, Brainard, 2017, Trésor Eco, 2017). This issue of Rue de la Banque aims to contribute to the debate by presenting a series of recent estimates obtained by the Banque de France. It should be reminded beforehand that there is a large number of possible specifications for the PC (for a review, see Le Bihan, 2009). Starting from a relationship between wage growth and the unemployment rate (Phillips, 1958), the PC rapidly became sophisticated by incorporating inflation expectations as early as the 1960s, and then by replacing wages by prices as the dependent variable in the 1980s (many works also replace the unemployment rate by the output gap as the explanatory variable). Finally, in its most recent version, the New Keynesian Phillips Curve (NKPC) is a relationship between inflation, expected inflation and the output gap. Recent estimates of the Phillips curve at the Banque de France In order to highlight the trend in this relationship at the global level, we first estimate a PC for the panel of G7 countries from the mid 1980s to 2016. This regression on quarterly panel data aims to explain inflation by (i) the gap between unemployment and its structural level and (ii) inflation expectations measured by a moving average of inflation over the last four quarters. The model is estimated over a rolling window of 60 quarters. The slope of the Phillips curve decreased significantly from the 1980s to the mid 1990s (see Chart 1), but has since then remained relatively stable at around in absolute value. As regards the coefficient of past inflation, it remained below but close to 1 until the mid 1990s, then began to decline until it was no longer statistically different from zero 1 www.banque-france.fr

C1 Estimated coefficient of the unemployment gap in G7 countries - -1.5-2.0-2.5-3.0-3.5-4.0 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Coefficient of the unemployment gap 95% confidence interval C2 Estimated coefficient of past inflation in G7 countries 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2-0.2-0.4-0.6-0.8 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 Q1 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Coefficient of past inflation 95% confidence interval over the recent period (see Chart 2). We have thus moved from a so called accelerationist Phillips curve, where the unemployment rate influences inflation variations, to a so called non accelerationist curve, where it influences the level of inflation. This change mainly reflects a change in the formation of expectations by economic agents. Two potential explanatory factors have been put forward, notably by Blanchard (2018), who empirically obtains a similar result with American data. First, the improved credibility of monetary policy, in particular via the adoption of inflation targeting, has made the process of forming inflation expectations more forward looking than backward looking. Second, given that inflation is low and stable, it may no longer be taken into account in the price and wage setting process. Distinguishing the relative importance of these two factors is not obvious, and may depend on the type of economic agents considered (households or firms). For the euro area, we tested a number of specifications using various variables of underemployment (unemployment and different output gap measures) and of import prices (import deflator, Brent prices, etc.). While the results are largely similar, our preferred specification 1 is the following: SA SA Δlog HICP t = const + c 1 Δlog HICP t-1 + c 2 OG (t-1) + c 3 Δlog PI t + c 4 DVAT t + ε t where HICP t SA is the seasonally adjusted harmonised index of consumer prices, OG is the output gap, PI is the relative price of imports (non euro area import prices, divided by the GDP deflator), and DVAT is a dummy variable indicating the change in the main VAT rate. The recursive estimate of this equation over a rolling window of 36 quarters 2 enables us to assess the variation in the medium term slope of the Phillips curve (i.e. c 2 1-c 1 ). The results (see Chart 3) show a stable slope, at around 0.4 in annual terms. It is also significantly different from zero on all the samples considered. Auer, Borio and Filardo (2017) stress the growing role of the global output gap and the diminishing role of the domestic output gap in domestic price dynamics, in a context of global integration of production chains. C3 Slope of the Phillips curve in the euro area (rolling window over 36 quarters, start of the first estimate: Q4 1998) 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 Output gap medium-term coefficient +/- 2 standard error Note: Annual medium-term slope given by 4*c 2 /(1-c 1 ). 1 See also Rue de la Banque No. 6 and No. 37. 2 Data for the euro area starts in 1999, which leads us to reduce the size of the rolling window to cover the period of the crisis. 2

T1 Phillips curves for the total euro area HICP a) (1999-2017, quarterly data) Endogeneous variable: π (t) Equation 1 Equation 2 Constant 0.26*** 0.32*** π (t-1) 0.39*** 0.27** Output gap euro area (t-1) 4* 7*** Global output gap excluding euro area (t-1) 0-2 import price (t) 9*** VAT increase dummy 0.17** 0.22*** Adjusted R² 0.23 7 a) Harmonised index of consumer prices. Note: The global output gap excl. euro area is calculated using a Hodrick Prescott filter. The results are robust to the use of other measures, derived from production functions. The ***, ** and * signs indicate the significance at the thresholds of 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. C4 Contributions to euro area inflation (deviation from the sample average, in percentage points) 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 - -1.5-2.0-2.5-3.0 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 Output gap VAT Relative import prices Note: Average HICP inflation of the sample: 1.9%. Residuals HICP (%, year-on-year) However, there is no consensus on these conclusions. Mikolajun and Lodge (2016) conclude that the global output gap has no direct effect on inflation in OECD economies. The authors consider that once commodity prices have been taken into account, it is not necessary to include other global factors in the Phillips curve. The Phillips curves estimated for the euro area show (see Table 1) that global demand conditions do impact domestic inflation, but through import prices, in particular oil prices. Why inflation has remained weak Between 2014 and 2017, inflation in the euro area averaged %, well below its long term average. Our preferred PC specification described above enables us to quantify the role played by the economic cycle and international prices in the recent decline in inflation in the euro area (see Chart 4). This breakdown shows that the fall in import prices caused by the decrease in oil prices and the negative output gap contributed to lowering inflation over the 2014 2016 period, in similar proportions. However, the presence of negative residuals from 2014 suggests that other factors may have played a role. These negative residuals can be partly explained by the weak wage dynamics since the recovery. Several factors can be put forward, among which: (i) workforce composition effects; (ii) a compensation of downward nominal wage rigidity; (iii) an ageing labour force. During the 2008 2011 period, the limited adjustment of average wages is mainly due to the fact that job losses concerned low skilled and inexperienced workers with lower wages (Verdugo, 2016). During a recovery, the same workforce composition effect should work in the opposite direction: less qualified and less experienced workers are reintegrated into the workforce, thus lowering the average wage. The empirical literature on wage developments shows the existence in Europe of downward nominal wage rigidity (see in particular Marotzke et al., 2017). In times of low inflation, this may have reduced firms ability to adapt to negative shocks. In times of growth, firms take into account this rigidity and anticipate the difficulty of making future wage cuts. They are thus able to limit wage growth when activity picks up (Elsby, 2009). The ageing of the population may also have limited wage hikes during the recovery. From 2009 to 2016, the share in employment of the over 50s increased compared to the share of the 15 49 age group, as a result of the various pension reforms as well as the generational effects related to increased women participation in the labour market. This rise represents a positive shock to labour supply, which is likely to put downward pressure on wages (Mojon and Ragot, 2018). 3

C5 Inflation expectations in the euro area (annual average - %) 2.05 2.00 2.80 2.50 expectations (see Mario Draghi s speech at Jackson Hole, August 2014). This is the reason why the Eurosystem then implemented a series of measures to support demand and credit. 1.95 1.90 1.85 1.80 1.75 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 5-year ahead average inflation forecast, SPF (left-hand scale) 5-year inflation-linked swaps (ILS) rate 5 years ahead (right-hand scale) 2.20 1.90 1.60 1.30 1.00 These measures, by their number and unprecedented scale, have helped to sustain demand and stem the fall in inflation expectations. In line with the usual time lags for the transmission of monetary policy to the real economy, they aim to get inflation to converge towards its long term target, close to but below 2%. Conclusion Sources: ECB (SPF); Bloomberg (ILS). Note: The ILS are expressed in quarterly terms by forming calendar averages. Monetary policy response Another factor is the sharp drop in long term inflation expectations in mid 2014 compared to the target below, but close to 2% (see Chart 5), whether they are measured using the results of the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) or using market data (inflation linked swaps, ILS). At the same time, the share of HICP fluctuations explained by the residuals of the Phillips curve increased significantly (see Chart 4). According to new neoclassical synthesis models, these negative residuals may also be the sign of a downward drift in inflation expectations. All of these elements point to a risk of an unanchoring of inflation The results of our estimates show that the price activity relationship flattened out in the 1980s but has remained significant since then. The implications for monetary policy are twofold: (i) First, an accommodating monetary policy is less likely to result in an inflationary spiral; (ii) However, the real economy lever for halting a drop in inflation expectations would be less powerful than it was before 1990. Given that the risk of declining inflation expectations has not been completely eliminated, this could argue for maintaining an accommodative bias in the monetary policy normalisation process. However, our estimates of the Phillips curve remain uncertain. We must remain attentive to all the determinants of inflation and, in particular, to the structural changes in the economy, notably those related to globalisation and new technologies, both in the goods and services market and in the labour market. 4

References Auer (R.), Borio (C.) and Filardo (A.) (2017) The globalisation of inflation: the growing importance of global value chains, BIS Working Papers, No. 602, Bank for International Settlements, January. Blanchard (O.) (2018) Should we reject the natural rate hypothesis?, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 32, No. 1, Winter, pp. 97 120. Brainard (L.) (2017) Understanding the disconnect between employment and inflation with a low neutral rate, Remarks at the Economic Club of New York, 5 September. Chatelais (N.), De Gaye (A.) and Kalantzis (Y.) (2015) Low inflation in the euro area: import prices and domestic slack, Rue de la Banque, No. 6, Banque de France, May. Chatelais (N.) and Schmidt (K.) (2017) The impact of import prices on inflation in the euro area, Rue de la Banque, No. 37, Banque de France, January. Draghi (M.) (2014) Unemployment in the euro area, speech at the Annual Central Bank Symposium in Jackson Hole, August. Elsby (M.) (2009) Evaluating the economic significance of downward nominal wage rigidity, Journal of Monetary Economics, Elsevier, Vol. 56, No. 2, pp.154-169, March. Le Bihan (H.) (2009) 1958-2008, avatars et enjeux de la courbe de Phillips, Revue de l OFCE, No. 111, October. Marotzke (P.), Anderton (R.), Bairrao (A.), Berson (C.) and Tóth (P.), (2017) Asymmetric wage adjustment and employment in European firms, Working Paper Series, No. 2103, European Central Bank, October. Mikolajun (I.) and Lodge (D.) (2016) Advanced economy inflation: the role of global factors, Working Paper Series, No. 1948, European Central Bank, August. Mojon (B.) and Ragot (X.) (2018) The labor supply of baby boomers and the weakness of wage inflation, mimeo, Banque de France and OFCE. Phillips (A. W.) (1958) The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861 1957, Economica, Vol. XXV, November. The Economist (2017) The Phillips curve may be broken for good, November. Trésor-Éco (2017) Pourquoi l inflation reste-t-elle si faible dans le monde?, No. 208, October. Verdugo (G.) (2016) Real wage cyclicality in the Eurozone before and during the Great Recession: Evidence from micro data, European Economic Review, Vol. 82, pp. 49-69. Published by Banque de France Managing Editor Olivier Garnier Editor in Chief Françoise Drumetz Production Press and Communication Department February 2018 www.banque-france.fr 5