Recent Changes in Macro Policy and its Effects: Some Time-Series Evidence

Similar documents
Stabilization, Accommodation, and Monetary Rules

Tentative Lessons from the Recent Disinflationary Effort

Revisionist History: How Data Revisions Distort Economic Policy Research

MA Advanced Macroeconomics 3. Examples of VAR Studies

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

The effects of inflation on growth: some international evidence

COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY GRADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS. Professor Frederic S. Mishkin Fall 1999 Uris Hall 619 Extension:

Macroeconomics: Principles, Applications, and Tools

Monetary and Fiscal Policy Switching with Time-Varying Volatilities

William T. Gavin Emeritus

ECONOMIC POLICY UNCERTAINTY AND SMALL BUSINESS DECISIONS

Inflation Uncertainty, Investment Spending, and Fiscal Policy

Inflation Targeting and Output Stabilization in Australia

Volume 29, Issue 3. Application of the monetary policy function to output fluctuations in Bangladesh

Commentary: Challenges for Monetary Policy: New and Old

Discussion of Trend Inflation in Advanced Economies

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Does Commodity Price Index predict Canadian Inflation?

Relationship between Inflation and Unemployment in India: Vector Error Correction Model Approach

Inflation Persistence and Relative Contracting

DOES MONEY GRANGER CAUSE INFLATION IN THE EURO AREA?*

Augmenting Okun s Law with Earnings and the Unemployment Puzzle of 2011

Monetary Economics Semester 2, 2003

Inflation, Output, and Nominal Money. Growth

THE FED AND THE NEW ECONOMY

How monetary policy affects economic activity

THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK FOR FIFTH DISTRICT STATES IN 1984: FORECASTS FROM VECTOR AUTOREGRESSION MODELS

Productivity, monetary policy and financial indicators

INFORMATION EFFICIENCY HYPOTHESIS THE FINANCIAL VOLATILITY IN THE CZECH REPUBLIC CASE

Prediction errors in credit loss forecasting models based on macroeconomic data

Forecasting Exchange Rates with PPP

IS INFLATION VOLATILITY CORRELATED FOR THE US AND CANADA?

Budget Deficits and Economic Growth

ECONOMIC GROWTH AND UNEMPLOYMENT RATE OF THE TRANSITION COUNTRY THE CASE OF THE CZECH REPUBLIC

The relationship between output and unemployment in France and United Kingdom

Inflation and Inflation Uncertainty in Turkey

Transparency and the Response of Interest Rates to the Publication of Macroeconomic Data

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

The Stock Market Crash Really Did Cause the Great Recession

The Short-Run Tradeoff Between Inflation and Unemployment

Chapter 24. The Role of Expectations in Monetary Policy

Simple monetary policy rules

A New Characterization of the U.S. Macroeconomic and Monetary Policy Outlook 1

Recent Monetary Policy and the Fiscal Theory of the Price Level. Bennett T. McCallum. Carnegie Mellon University. March 12, 2014

Ray C. Fair Curriculum Vitae

Chapter 12: Unemployment and Inflation

Data Dependence and U.S. Monetary Policy. Remarks by. Richard H. Clarida. Vice Chairman. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

The Impact of Model Periodicity on Inflation Persistence in Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

Macro Notes: Introduction to the Short Run

Currency Substitution, Capital Mobility and Functional Forms of Money Demand in Pakistan

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Above-Average National Growth in 1985 and 1986 Robert B. Litterman (p. 3) More Growth Ahead. for Ninth District States

Paper Published in the February 2005 Journal of Business & Economic Research Why the Quantity of Money Still Matters

SOCIAL SECURITY AND SAVING: NEW TIME SERIES EVIDENCE MARTIN FELDSTEIN *

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Why the saving rate has been falling in Japan

MONETARY POLICY AND THE STABILITY OF MACROECONOMIC RELATIONSHIPS

Review of the literature on the comparison

The Price Puzzle and Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism in Pakistan: Structural Vector Autoregressive Approach

Deficits and Money Growth in the United States: A Comment. By: Stuart D. Allen and Donald L. McCrickard

MONEY AND ECONOMIC ACTIVITY: SOME INTERNATIONAL EVIDENCE. Abstract

Session 9. The Interactions Between Cyclical and Long-term Dynamics: The Role of Inflation

Márcio G. P. Garcia PUC-Rio Brazil Visiting Scholar, Sloan School, MIT and NBER. This paper aims at quantitatively evaluating two questions:

Quarterly Review. What's Wrong With Macroeconomics ( P. v. Summer 1980

Monetary policy and uncertainty

The Relationship between Inflation, Inflation Uncertainty and Output Growth in India

Demand Shocks Fuel Commodity Price Booms and Busts

Relationship between Consumer Price Index (CPI) and Government Bonds

The Federal Reserve s reaction function, which summarizes how the

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Influence the Balancing Item in Japan? An Empirical Note. Tuck Cheong Tang

Advanced Macroeconomics 5. Rational Expectations and Asset Prices

September 21, 2016 Bank of Japan

Dynamic Linkages between Newly Developed Islamic Equity Style Indices

Conditional Convergence: Evidence from the Solow Growth Model

Fractional Integration and the Persistence Of UK Inflation, Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Luis Alberiko Gil-Alana.

Business Cycles in Pakistan

Using Exogenous Changes in Government Spending to estimate Fiscal Multiplier for Canada: Do we get more than we bargain for?

Weak Policy in an Open Economy: The US with a Floating Exchange Rate, Henry Thompson

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * First draft: September 2000 This draft: July 2001

THE SHORT-RUN TRADEOFF BETWEEN INFLATION AND UNEMPLOYMENT

The Importance of Being Predictable. John B. Taylor Stanford University. Remarks Prepared for the Policy Panel on Monetary Policy Under Uncertainty

Re-Normalize, Don t New-Normalize Monetary Policy. John B. Taylor. Economics Working Paper 14109

A Test of Two Open-Economy Theories: The Case of Oil Price Rise and Italy

Public Expenditure on Capital Formation and Private Sector Productivity Growth: Evidence

American Economic Association

Equity Price Dynamics Before and After the Introduction of the Euro: A Note*

y = f(n) Production function (1) c = c(y) Consumption function (5) i = i(r) Investment function (6) = L(y, r) Money demand function (7)

Following World War II, the quantity and quality of macroeconomic data

Productivity and Wages

Journal of Central Banking Theory and Practice, 2017, 1, pp Received: 6 August 2016; accepted: 10 October 2016

Global and National Macroeconometric Modelling: A Long-run Structural Approach Overview on Macroeconometric Modelling Yongcheol Shin Leeds University

Textbook Media Press. CH 28 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

MONEY, PRICES, INCOME AND CAUSALITY: A CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

Government Tax Revenue, Expenditure, and Debt in Sri Lanka : A Vector Autoregressive Model Analysis

Information Technology, Productivity, Value Added, and Inflation: An Empirical Study on the U.S. Economy,

Online Appendix (Not intended for Publication): Federal Reserve Credibility and the Term Structure of Interest Rates

THE BEHAVIOUR OF CONSUMER S EXPENDITURE IN INDIA:

The United States is made up of diverse regions. Regional Economies: Separating Trends from Cycles. Gerald Carlino and Keith Sill*

Is monetary policy in New Zealand similar to

Threshold cointegration and nonlinear adjustment between stock prices and dividends

Transcription:

HAS THE RESPONSE OF INFLATION TO MACRO POLICY CHANGED? Recent Changes in Macro Policy and its Effects: Some Time-Series Evidence Has the macroeconomic policy "regime" changed in the United States in the last few years? If so, has ths change had an effect on macroeconomic relationships, and, in particular, on the relationshp between inflation and unemployment? These two questions have been on the minds of most macroeconomists since the October 1979 switch from interest rates to reserves as an intermediate target for the Federal Reserve and the explicit endorsement of monetarism by the Reagan Administration in early 1981. The questions are important not only for predicting the course of the economy in the future, but also for assessing the practical significance of the Lucas critique.' According to this critique a change in policy regime should cause changes in the way the economy operates. Comparing economic relations before and after a change in regime should provide a test of the critique. The approach in many recent studies has been to assume that the answer to the first question is yes-that there has been a significant change in the macroeconomic policy regime-and to look for changes in the Phllips curve as a test of the Lucas critique. Thus far, the results have been mixed. Otto Eckstein (1983), Steven Englander and Cornelis Los (1983), and George Perry (1983) conclude that there has been no significant *404 Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University. Princeton, NJ 08544. This research was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation at the National Bureau of Economic Research and conducted in part at the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelpha. I am grateful to Steve Fries for research assistance, and to Steven Englander and Cornelis Los for comments on an earlier draft. 'see Robert Lucas (1976). William Fellner's (1978) credibility hypothesis is similar to the Lucas Critique in this context and has been tested in similar ways. 206 change in the Phillips curve relationshp. Phillip Cagan and William Fellner (1983) and Wayne Vroman (1983) find some evidence of a change: wage inflation has come down more quickly-especially in 1982 and early 1983-than would be predicted from a Phillips curve. However, the assumption that there has been a regime change has received little empirical attention. The October 1979 switch from interest rate targetting to reserve targetting at the Fed is usually taken as prima facie evidence of a significant change in policy regime. But such changes in operating procedures per se do not necessarily entail a change in policy regime relevant for macroeconomic purposes. If they did, then the renewed emphasis on interest rates rather than reserves starting in late 1982 should be cited as evidence of a return to the old regime-a view which few researchers have taken. In fact, studies have shown that either interest rates or reserves can be used as intermediate targets for controlling the money supply and ultimately aggregate demand. (The choice between the two depends on whether shocks to the money markets are from the demand side or the supply side.) The issue of importance for assessing whether a regime change has taken place is how much the Fed reacts by adjusting the money supply (appropriately defined) in response to conditions in the economy. The procedure it uses to bring about this response is irrele~ant.~ Implicit in a macroeconomic policy regime is "rule" relating the money supply to economic con- 'some have argued that, for political reasons, by focusing on reserves the Fed would be able to let interest rates go higher than under interest rate targetting. With reserve targetting, Fed officials could shift the blame for high interest rates elsewhere.

VOL. 74 NO. 2 HAS THE RESPONSE OF INFLATION TO MACRO POLICY CHANGED? 207 ditions. The fact that the last three years are a suitable time for testing the Lucas Critique can be established only by providing evidence that this rule has changed significantly. The aim of ths paper is to use simple time-series techniques to examine whether there has been a significant change in macroeconomic policy in the special sense described above, and whether, as a result of this change, the relationship between inflation and unemployment has shifted in ways suggested by recent theories of wage and price determination. To do ths a small vector autoregression is estimated and transformed into a pure moving average form in which changes in macro policy and its effects can be measured. I. Measuring The Change in Aggregate Demand Policy Financial innovations such as sweep accounts and the move toward deregulation of financial services have made it difficult to use any one measure of the money supply for estimating a policy rule in recent years. The relationship between money and nominal GNP has been even more volatile than usual as a result of these innovations and regulatory changes. An alternative aproach is needed. The most direct way to get around the velocity shift problem is to focus on aggregate demand itself as measured by nominal GNP. A change in policy regme would then occur if the Fed altered its rule for adjusting its nominal GNP targets. In particular, the Fed would become less accommodative in the 1980's if it did not permit nominal GNP to increase as much in response to inflation shocks as it has in the past. Such a lessaccommodative policy would permit real GNP to fall by a larger amount in response to inflation shocks. Alternatively stated, it would permit unemployment to rise by a larger amount in response to inflation shocks. During the late 1960's and 1970's the Fed allowed the growth rate of nominal GNP to rise to about 12 percent, whch accommodates a steady 9 percent inflation if potential GNP grows at 3 percent. If there has been a change in the policy regime it is likely to be to one in which the Fed will aim to make nominal GNP less accommodative to inflation. Perhaps it will eventually aim to keep the growth rate of nominal GNP constant at a lower level (say 5 percent) as some economists have recently proposed. These less-accommodative policies would entail larger increases in unemployment in response to inflation shocks. A reaction function for measuring this change can be obtained by regressing the unemployment rate on past inflation rates and past unemployment rates. Adding lagged unemployment terms to the equation allows for reaction lags or other reasons for delayed response by the Fed. If the coefficients on the past inflation rates in this equation have increased in the last few years, then this would be evidence of a change toward a less accommodative policy regime. 11. Measuring Change in the Inflation Process How would the inflation process change as a result of such a change to a less-accommodative policy? Recent research on wage and price determination (see my 1980 article for example) suggests that inflation will be less persistent (i.e., have smaller positive autocorrelation) under a less-accommodative aggregate demand policy. A shock to the inflation rate will not have as prolonged an effect on inflation with a less-accommodative policy. Ths research also suggests that the effect of a given level of unemployment on inflation will increase. This is due to the expectation that the Fed will not accommodate inflation in the future. Expectations of higher unemployment in the future, as well as expectations of lower inflation in the future, will tend to reduce inflation today. These potential changes can be measured by regressing the inflation rate on past inflation rates and on past unemployment rates. If the coefficients on past inflation rates decline and the coefficients on the unemployment rates increase in absolute value, while at the same time macro policy becomes less accommodative, then we would have evidence which is consistent with this theory of wage and price determination.

208 AE,4 PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 1984 111. The Evidence from Vector Autoregressions The regressions suggested above for measuring changes in macro policy and in the inflation process can be combined to form a simple vector autoregression in whch the vector of unemployment and inflation observations is regressed on past values of itself. Ths bivariate autoregression was estimated over two sample periods: 1954: 1-1981 :1 and 1954:l-1983:3. The longer sample period includes the recent disinflation period where the effects of a regime change should be noticeable. Unfortunately the period 1981:l- 1983:3 is too short to estimate a vector autoregression separately. Let y, = (w,, u,)' where w, is the rate of change in average hourly earnings index (a measure of inflation), and u, is the unemployment rate for prime age males (a demographcally stable measure of unemployment).3 The estimated equations are of the form and are based on quarterly observations. The moving average for ths system is given by where the 19, matrices can be obtained directly from the A, mat rice^.^ As Christopher Sims (1980) has argued, the moving average coefficients usually show a smoother pattern than the autoregressive coefficients and are therefore easier to interpret. The autoregressions for the two periods are reported in Table 1 and the moving average representation is shown in Figure 1. In assessing the change in macro policy and in the inflation process we can compare these two vector autoregressions and their moving 3~he nominal wage series prior to 1961 was provided Robert Gordon. See his 1971 paper. 4The covariance matrix of the E, in this representation has not been orthogonalized and is equal to the covariance matrix estimated in equation (1). Sims discusses alternative ways of presenting the moving average representation. Lags 1 2 3 4 SSR Sample: 1954:l-1981:l wequation 11..40.26.12.22 u.03.02.02 -.05 98.0 u-euqation M. -.45.56 -.51.30 u 1.62 -.89.21 -.01 11.1 Correlation of Residuals: p,, = -,290 Sample 1954:l-1983:3 w-equation w.41.26.10.19 u.03.o1.04 -.04 105.2 u-equation M -.50.65 -.63.28 u 1.66 -.88.16.03 13.4 Correlation of Residuals: p,,, = -,306 Note: M. is the percentage quarterly change in the average hourly earnings index measured at an annual rate, u is the unemployment rate for males 25 to 54; SSR is the sum of squared residuals for each equation; the equations were estimated with a constant term. average representations. This procedure is not entirely satisfactory since the sample period whch contains the last eleven quarters also includes the earlier period; if there has been a change in the last eleven quarters, then these estimates will be a mixture of two dissimilar periods between which a structural change has occurred. Assuming that the new policy is maintained, future studies may be able to utilize additional observations to estimate separate autoregressions and moving average representations under the new regime. Visual inspection of the autoregressive equations in Table 1indicates that the effect of adding additional sample points during the disinflation period has a relatively small effect on the autoregressive coefficients. The F-tests for structural homogeneity give values of.735 and 2.07 for the inflation and unemployment equations, respectively. The 5 percent significance point is 1.94. Hence there is more evidence of a structural change in the policy equation than in the behavioral equation for inflation. But neither change is dramatic. Note that the changes in the coefficients do indicate a shift to a less-accommodative policy, and that the effects of ths change are exactly as predicted above. The sum of the coefficients on lagged wages in the unem-

VOL. 74 NO. -7 HAS THE RESPONSE OF INFLATION TO MACRO POLICY CHANGED? 1.0-.8- WAGE PERSISTENCE 812.4-,6- IMPACT OF WAGE SHOCK ON UNEMPLOYMENT,2-,.---. 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 IMPACT OF UNEMPLOYMENT ON WAGES Note: 1954:l-1981:l --; 1954:l-1983:3 --- ployment equation increases, the sum of the that the direction of the changes correspond coefficients on lagged wages in the wage to what would be predicted from a lessequation declines, and the sum of the coeffi- accommodative policy is suggestive that thls cients on unemployment in the wage equa- may be the case. tion increases in absolute value. The moving average coefficients shown in It is likely that the lack of strong statistical the four charts in Figure 1 suggest the same significance in these equations is due to the interpretation as the simple comparison of small number of observations in the post- the sum of lagged coefficients. They also 1980 period and the resulting low power of provide information about how the dynamics the structural homogeneity tests at conven- of the economy have changed. The charts in tional significance levels. If so, then if policy Figure 1 are normalized so that zero is the remains less accommodative in the future, steady-state value for each variable. For exthe additional observations will strengthen ample, the normal level of the unemploythe statistical significance. The strihng fact ment rate is zero.

210 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 1984 The chart in the upper right-hand corner of the figure shows that the initial impact of a wage shock on unemployment is larger for the sample that includes the post-1980 data. The impact remains larger for 25 quarters, but eventually the response of unemployment falls below that in the earlier period. According to these estimates, policy seems to have become less accommodative, not only by responding by a larger amount to inflation shocks, but also by responding more quickly. Ths policy would generate recessions which are larger than under the old policy, but which do not last as long. Examining the upper left-hand portion it is clear that wage inflation is much less persistent for the sample that includes the last three years. The impact of any shock to wages deteriorates more rapidly than in the pre-1980 sample. Finally the impact of unemployment on inflation is shown in the lower left-hand corner of the figure. The initial and medium-term impacts of unemployment on wage formation are larger for the sample which includes the last three years. Eventually, however, the effect of the unemployment shock is smaller. IV. Concluding Remarks The purpose of this paper has been to look for changes in the behavior of macroeconomic policy and the relation between inflation and unemployment during the last three years using time-series techniques. There is evidence that the policy "rule" has changed in the direction of a less-accommodative policy and that the inflation process has become less persistent. Under the less-accommodative policy, the increase in unemployment caused by inflation "shocks" is larger but less prolonged. The results, however, are based on a relatively small number of observations during the new regime and are not strongly significant statistically. While the results are in general agreement with recent theories of the effect of macro policy on wage and price formation, they must therefore be viewed as tentative. REFERENCES Cagan, Phillip and Fellner, William J., "Tentative Lessons from the Recent Disinflationary Effort," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1983, 603-08. Eckstein, Otto, "Disinflation," Alternatives for the 1980s, No. 10, Center for National Policy, October 1983. Englander, A. Steven and Los, Cornelis A., "The Stability of the Phillips Curve and its Implications for the 1980s," Research Paper No. 8303, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, February 1983. Fellner, William J., "The Core of the Controversy about Reducing Inflation: An Introductory Analysis," in his Contemporary Economic Problems, Washngton: American Enterprise, 1978. Gordon, Robert J., "Inflation in Recession and Recovery," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1971, 105-66. Lucas, Robert E. Jr., "Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique," in Karl Brunner and Alan Meltzer, eds., The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets, Vol. 1, Carnegie- Rochester Conferences on Public Policy, Journal of Monetary Economics, Suppl. 1976,19-46. Peny, George L., "What Have We Learned about Disinflation?," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:1983, 587-602. Sims, Christopher A., "Macroeconomics and Reality," Econometrica, January 1980, 48, 1-48. Taylor, John B., "Output and Price Stability: An International Comparison," Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, February 1980,2, 109-32. Vroman, Wayne, Wage Inflation: Prospects for Deceleration, Washmgton: The Urban Institute Press, 1983.