Corporate Control. Itay Goldstein. Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Similar documents
Discussion Paper. University of Michigan. Center for Research on Economic and Social Theory Research Seminar in Quantitative Economics C - 7

Sequential Decision-making and Asymmetric Equilibria: An Application to Takeovers

Exercises Solutions: Game Theory

Answers to Problem Set 4

Exercises Solutions: Oligopoly

Duopoly models Multistage games with observed actions Subgame perfect equilibrium Extensive form of a game Two-stage prisoner s dilemma

Markets with Intermediaries

Markets with Intermediaries

Problem 3 Solutions. l 3 r, 1

Infinitely Repeated Games

ECON 459 Game Theory. Lecture Notes Auctions. Luca Anderlini Spring 2017

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: August 7, 2017

Answer Key: Problem Set 4

February 23, An Application in Industrial Organization

1 Two Period Exchange Economy

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 5. Property Rights Theory. The key question we are staring from is: What are ownership/property rights?

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications Final Exam Ronaldo Carpio Jan. 13, 2015

Financial Fragility A Global-Games Approach Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania

Game Theory: Global Games. Christoph Schottmüller

MA300.2 Game Theory 2005, LSE

Other Regarding Preferences

Econ 101A Final Exam We May 9, 2012.

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Second Midterm Examination Answers

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer 2016

Chapter 7 Review questions

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

CUR 412: Game Theory and its Applications, Lecture 4

Notes for Section: Week 4

Alon Brav and Richmond D. Mathews. October 17, 2007

March 30, Why do economists (and increasingly, engineers and computer scientists) study auctions?

G5212: Game Theory. Mark Dean. Spring 2017

The Ohio State University Department of Economics Econ 601 Prof. James Peck Extra Practice Problems Answers (for final)

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 6. Separation of Ownership and Control

HW Consider the following game:

Recap First-Price Revenue Equivalence Optimal Auctions. Auction Theory II. Lecture 19. Auction Theory II Lecture 19, Slide 1

ECONS 424 STRATEGY AND GAME THEORY HANDOUT ON PERFECT BAYESIAN EQUILIBRIUM- III Semi-Separating equilibrium

PROBLEM SET 6 ANSWERS

Econ 8602, Fall 2017 Homework 2

Chapter 11: Dynamic Games and First and Second Movers

Lecture 6 Dynamic games with imperfect information

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Commitment to Overinvest and Price Informativeness

MA200.2 Game Theory II, LSE

Answers to Microeconomics Prelim of August 24, In practice, firms often price their products by marking up a fixed percentage over (average)

Microeconomics III. Oligopoly prefacetogametheory (Mar 11, 2012) School of Economics The Interdisciplinary Center (IDC), Herzliya

Exercise Chapter 10

Econ 101A Final exam May 14, 2013.

Microeconomic Theory II Preliminary Examination Solutions Exam date: June 5, 2017

1 Optimal Taxation of Labor Income

Elements of Economic Analysis II Lecture XI: Oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand Competition

Bounded Rationality Mitigates the Free-Rider Problem: An Experimental Study on Corporate Takeovers*

Moral Hazard Example. 1. The Agent s Problem. contract C = (w, w) that offers the same wage w regardless of the project s outcome.

Stochastic Games and Bayesian Games

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Fundamental Theorems of Welfare Economics

Microeconomic Theory August 2013 Applied Economics. Ph.D. PRELIMINARY EXAMINATION MICROECONOMIC THEORY. Applied Economics Graduate Program

Université du Maine Théorie des Jeux Yves Zenou Correction de l examen du 16 décembre 2013 (1 heure 30)

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW. Contracts. I.1 Bargain Theory. I.2 Damages Part 1. I.3 Reliance

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 19 May, 2008.

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Economics 171: Final Exam

Chapter 23: Choice under Risk

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 5

Economics 209A Theory and Application of Non-Cooperative Games (Fall 2013) Repeated games OR 8 and 9, and FT 5

Ph.D. Preliminary Examination MICROECONOMIC THEORY Applied Economics Graduate Program June 2017

Repeated Games. Econ 400. University of Notre Dame. Econ 400 (ND) Repeated Games 1 / 48

In Class Exercises. Problem 1

PAULI MURTO, ANDREY ZHUKOV

The Nash equilibrium of the stage game is (D, R), giving payoffs (0, 0). Consider the trigger strategies:

Web Appendix: Proofs and extensions.

1 x i c i if x 1 +x 2 > 0 u i (x 1,x 2 ) = 0 if x 1 +x 2 = 0

6.6 Secret price cuts

Name. Answers Discussion Final Exam, Econ 171, March, 2012

Game Theory Lecture #16

Now we return to simultaneous-move games. We resolve the issue of non-existence of Nash equilibrium. in pure strategies through intentional mixing.

Optimal selling rules for repeated transactions.

On Forchheimer s Model of Dominant Firm Price Leadership

Introduction to Political Economy Problem Set 3

The Irrelevance of Corporate Governance Structure

M.Phil. Game theory: Problem set II. These problems are designed for discussions in the classes of Week 8 of Michaelmas term. 1

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2012

Econ 101A Final exam Mo 18 May, 2009.

January 26,

S 2,2-1, x c C x r, 1 0,0

Econ 711 Homework 1 Solutions

FDPE Microeconomics 3 Spring 2017 Pauli Murto TA: Tsz-Ning Wong (These solution hints are based on Julia Salmi s solution hints for Spring 2015.

Comparing Allocations under Asymmetric Information: Coase Theorem Revisited

Auctions: Types and Equilibriums

Economics 51: Game Theory

p =9 (x1 + x2). c1 =3(1 z),

Game Theory. Wolfgang Frimmel. Repeated Games

General Examination in Microeconomic Theory SPRING 2014

d. Find a competitive equilibrium for this economy. Is the allocation Pareto efficient? Are there any other competitive equilibrium allocations?

Product Di erentiation: Exercises Part 1

Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 3

ECON DISCUSSION NOTES ON CONTRACT LAW-PART 2. Contracts. I.1 Investment in Performance

Game Theory: Additional Exercises

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LEGAL INVESTOR PROTECTION AND TAKEOVERS. Mike Burkart Denis Gromb Holger M. Mueller Fausto Panunzi

Econ 101A Final exam Th 15 December. Do not turn the page until instructed to.

Economics 101A (Lecture 25) Stefano DellaVigna

Transcription:

Corporate Control Itay Goldstein Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania 1

Managerial Discipline and Takeovers Managers often don t maximize the value of the firm; either because they are not capable of doing so or because of an agency problem. An important disciplining device is the possibility of a takeover: o If a firm operates under potential, an outsider may step in, buy it, and increase its value. Grossman and Hart (1980) demonstrate a fundamental free-rider problem in this process of takeovers: o Small shareholders refuse to sell at below post-takeover value. 2

Grossman and Hart (1980): Free-Rider Problem and Dilution Manager takes an action, which generates value. Denote value given chosen action as:. Manager derives utility, which is affected by the value of the firm, and also some private cost needed to derive this value. As a result, the chosen action might not be the one maximizing firm value: max 3

A raider announces he wants to buy shares of the firm at a price p. If he acquires enough shares (usually, 50%), he gets control over the firm, and can change its value to: max The raider changes value by: o Having different ability (captured by ). o Choosing the value-maximizing action. Shareholders decide whether to sell. The assumption is that they are all atomistic. They don t realize they affect takeover success. 4

Free-Rider Problem Focus on equilibria where takeovers either succeed with probability 1 or with probability 0. The paper shows that there is no equilibrium where the takeover succeeds. o If the raider offers, each shareholder prefers not to sell, and get the higher value upon completion of the takeover. o If the raider offers, he is losing money, assuming that making a bid has some private cost c. 5

The Role of Dilution The problem with the takeover mechanism according to Grossman and Hart (1980) is that: o On the one hand, in order to make a profit the raider has to offer a price to shareholders, which is below the ultimate value under his control. o On the other hand, shareholders, not realizing their effect on the success of the takeover, prefer to wait and capture the higher value than to get the lower price. 6

The solution is to dilute existing shareholders in the takeover process: Giving them a lower value than v after the takeover is completed. Denote the dilution factor as. Then, the raider can guarantee the completion of the takeover by offering a price:, This gives the raider a profit of:,, 7

There are various ways to achieve dilution: o Allowing the raider to pay large salary to himself. o Allowing the raider to sell assets of the acquired firm at below fair value to another firm under his control. These measures are often perceived as bad since they expropriate value from shareholders. Grossman and Hart show that these measures can actually be good for existing shareholders. o They break a free-riding result and allow welfare enhancing takeover to happen. 8

The Choice of Managerial Action The corrective effect of takeover is not limited to ex-post replacement of a bad manager, but extends to ex-ante provision of incentive for the manager. o If the manager is replaced in a takeover, he has an incentive to choose an action more closely aligned with value maximization. Suppose that v and c are stochastic, and that the realization of v becomes known to the raider and the shareholders, while the realization of c becomes known to the raider. 9

A raid will occur for a realization of v and c such that, 0 Assuming that the manager receives a utility of zero when he is replaced, and using, to denote the probability that a raid will occur (i.e., that, 0), we can write the manager s utility from q as: 1, The first order condition determining the level of becomes: 10

1,, 0 In the absence of takeover considerations, the manager would simply set q so that 0. Now, the manager considers not only the direct effect of q, but also the indirect effect that it has via the probability of a takeover. In general, a higher level of q reduces the probability of a takeover (, 0) because the raider is less likely to be able to offer a price that will generate a profit. Hence, the threat of takeover induces the manager to increase q. 11

The Choice of Dilution Factor Shareholders have control over the value of the firm, in that they can set the dilution factor. They do it to maximize the expected value: 1,,, 0, Overall, an increase in the dilution level has three effects: o It makes takeovers more likely. o It reduces the payment to shareholders in the event of a takeover. 12

o It increases the output q produced by the manager. Since the probability of a takeover is the probability that, 0, a high makes it more likely that the manager will need to set q high to prevent a takeover. To gain some intuition, let s consider the case where v and c are non-stochastic, and where 0. o Since there is no uncertainty, takeover happens with probability 1 or 0. o Since 0, the manager prefers to produce value than be taken over and let raider produce this value. 13

o By setting at any level above c, shareholders guarantee that the manager will set q high enough to prevent a takeover. Specifically,. o At this optimum, takeovers never occur. Note that this example is a bit simplistic. Since takeovers never occur, there is no cost in increasing, and the shareholders are indifferent about how high will be. To consider this cost, suppose that v is stochastic. o Again, shareholders want to set above to have a takeover threat. 14

o Takeovers will sometime occur, depending on the realization of v. The manager will not find it optimal to always set q sufficiently high. o Since takeovers occur whenever, their probability is independent of, once is above c. Hence, there is no additional benefit in increasing. o Since there is a cost in increasing, it will be optimal to set it only slightly above c. The paper goes on to consider the results when c is stochastic, etc. 15

Bagnoli and Lipman (1988): Accounting for Pivotal Shareholders The problem with takeovers in the Grossman-Hart model stems from the fact that shareholders do not take into account their effect on the success of the takeover. Bagnoli and Lipman analyze a model where shareholders are not atomistic, and thus consider their effect on bid outcome. They show that takeovers can be successful even without dilution, and calculate the equilibria that can arise in such a game. 16

The Model A firm has N shares owned by I shareholders. Shareholder i holds shares. The value of the firm under current management is, and under the raider s management it is. The raider needs to acquire K shares to get control over the firm. There is a sequential game, where the raider chooses what price b to offer per share, and then shareholders decide whether to sell. We are looking for subgame perfect equilibria. 17

Takeover Equilibria in the Subgame (with No Dilution) The basic result in Grossman and Hart was that there is no equilibrium where the takeover succeeds at a price below. This is no longer true in the current model. Consider a bid price,. There are many pure-strategy equilibria where shareholder i sells, such that probability 1, and the raider makes a profit. o This is an equilibrium because:, and so the takeover succeeds with 18

No agent has an incentive to sell more, because, given the behavior of others, the takeover will succeed, so why sell a share worth for b. No agent has an incentive to sell less, because, given the behavior of others, the takeover will fail if he sells less, so selling a share worth for b is a good deal. o Essentially, each shareholder is made pivotal. There are no pure-strategy equilibria where. o If more (less) than K shares are sold, agents can benefit by reducing (increasing) sold quantity for similar considerations. 19

Mixed-Strategy Equilibria Suppose that each shareholder holds one share: 1,. Consider the following mixed-strategy equilibrium: each agent sells with probability, and doesn t sell with probability 1. For this to be an equilibrium: 1 1 1 1 20

o That is, each shareholder is indifferent between selling and not selling (and thus chooses to mix) given that other agents sell with probability. o The left-hand side is the payoff if he sells, which is given by the fixed offer. o The right-hand side is the expected payoff if he doesn t sell. Here, he may get or, depending if the number of other agents who sell is below or not. Note that the right-hand side is equal to when 0, and is equal to when 1. It is continuous and increasing in. 21

As a result, for each,, there is a unique 0,1 satisfying the above equation and giving rise to a mixed-strategy equilibrium. In this equilibrium, the raider makes the following profit: 1 1 Substituting for b and rearranging, we get: 1 22

We can thus see that the raider makes a positive profit. Moreover, this profit is proportional to the probability that exactly K shares are sold, i.e., that each shareholder is pivotal. Given the equilibrium played in the second stage, the raider chooses the offer price in the first bid to maximize his expected profit. Based on the results discussed so far, it follows that when the raider can improve the value of the firm ( ), he can always make an offer that will generate a positive probability of a takeover and a positive gain for him. 23

Shleifer and Vishny (1986): The Role of Large Shareholders Shleifer and Vishny offer a different, yet related, solution to the free-rider problem in corporate control. A shareholder, who owns a large proportion of the firm, has the right incentive to monitor managers, as this will benefit his portfolio. Other shareholders are more likely to go along with the large shareholders, knowing that his incentives are aligned. 24

The Model A large shareholder (L) holds fraction 0.5 of a firm s shares, while 1 is held by a group of atomistic shareholders. The large shareholder can pay a cost to find a way to improve the value of the firm by Z with probability I. o Z is drawn from a cumulative distribution function between 0,. o is increasing and convex: 0, 0. o The value of the firm under current management is q. 25

If the large shareholder finds the improvement of value Z, he can attempt to gain control by making an offer to buy 0.5 of the shares. This costs him. Denoting the offer price as, this is worthwhile if: 0.5 0.5 0 Small shareholders will sell their shares if and only if they expect that is greater than Z. Their expectation of Z is calculated based on the function, and on the fact that L chose to go along with the takeover: 26

Equilibrium in the Takeover Game Based on the above, small shareholders sell their shares if and only if: 1 2 2 0 The large shareholders will then offer a premium that is the minimum that satisfies this condition. The role of size is illustrated by the result that is decreasing in : the large shareholder has to pay a lower premium when he owns a bigger fraction of the firm. 27

To see this, consider : o For every, 1 2 2 1 2 2. o Hence, there are more levels of that satisfy the selling condition under than under. o Since is the minimum that satisfies the condition,. Essentially, when he owns a large share, the large shareholder can profit from a takeover even when is not large relative to, and this makes small shareholders willing to sell their shares. o This breaks the Grossman-Hart result. 28

Now, define as the cutoff level of the improvement Z, above which the large shareholder chooses to make a takeover attempt: 1 2 2 Given that is decreasing in, is also decreasing, implying that the large shareholder is more likely to make a takeover bid when he has higher stake at the firm. o With a higher stake, he can pay a lower takeover premium, making the takeover more profitable. 29

The Decision to Monitor In the first stage of the game, the large shareholder has to decide how much effort to put on monitoring. This will determine the probability I that he finds ways to improve the current management. The benefit from monitoring is: o Essentially, the large shareholder goes ahead with takeover when, in which case he benefits from the improvement Z on his shares and pays the cost of takeover. 30

Since this benefit of monitoring increases in the share, an immediate result (given the cost function for I) is that the intensity of monitoring I is increasing in. It is also shown (based on these results) that the value of the firm is increasing with the share held by the large shareholder. Overall, the paper demonstrates the importance of having a large shareholder, who will have an incentive to monitor existing management, and who can profit from conducting a takeover attempt. 31