Topic 6. Introducing money

Similar documents
Introducing money. Olivier Blanchard. April Spring Topic 6.

Macroeconomics 2. Lecture 5 - Money February. Sciences Po

Topic 4. Introducing investment (and saving) decisions

Money in a Neoclassical Framework

Fluctuations. Shocks, Uncertainty, and the Consumption/Saving Choice

Money in an RBC framework

Transactions and Money Demand Walsh Chapter 3

Topic 7. Nominal rigidities

Introducing nominal rigidities. A static model.

Ramsey s Growth Model (Solution Ex. 2.1 (f) and (g))

Problem Set 3. Thomas Philippon. April 19, Human Wealth, Financial Wealth and Consumption

Econ 219 Spring Lecture #11

The Ramsey Model. Lectures 11 to 14. Topics in Macroeconomics. November 10, 11, 24 & 25, 2008

A dynamic model with nominal rigidities.

Final Exam II (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Final Exam Solutions

Advanced Macro and Money (WS09/10) Problem Set 4

Lecture Notes. Macroeconomics - ECON 510a, Fall 2010, Yale University. Fiscal Policy. Ramsey Taxation. Guillermo Ordoñez Yale University

Consumption and Asset Pricing

Final Exam (Solutions) ECON 4310, Fall 2014

Lastrapes Fall y t = ỹ + a 1 (p t p t ) y t = d 0 + d 1 (m t p t ).

1 Fiscal stimulus (Certification exam, 2009) Question (a) Question (b)... 6

Cash-in-Advance Model

Equilibrium with Production and Endogenous Labor Supply

Introducing nominal rigidities.

(Incomplete) summary of the course so far

Money Demand. ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy. Eric Sims. Fall University of Notre Dame

Chapter 9 Dynamic Models of Investment

Lecture 2 General Equilibrium Models: Finite Period Economies

Final Exam II ECON 4310, Fall 2014

ECON 4325 Monetary Policy and Business Fluctuations

ECON 6022B Problem Set 2 Suggested Solutions Fall 2011

1 A tax on capital income in a neoclassical growth model

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

In the Name of God. Macroeconomics. Sharif University of Technology Problem Bank

1. Cash-in-Advance models a. Basic model under certainty b. Extended model in stochastic case. recommended)

1 No capital mobility

Money Demand. ECON 30020: Intermediate Macroeconomics. Prof. Eric Sims. Spring University of Notre Dame

1 Dynamic programming

Eco504 Fall 2010 C. Sims CAPITAL TAXES

14.05: SECTION HANDOUT #4 CONSUMPTION (AND SAVINGS) Fall 2005

MACROECONOMICS. Prelim Exam

UNIVERSITY OF OSLO DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. September 2015

Chapter 6. Endogenous Growth I: AK, H, and G

Linear Capital Taxation and Tax Smoothing

Notes on Financial Frictions Under Asymmetric Information and Costly State Verification. Lawrence Christiano

Public budget accounting and seigniorage. 1. Public budget accounting, inflation and debt. 2. Equilibrium seigniorage

A Model with Costly-State Verification

Dynamic Macroeconomics

Macro (8701) & Micro (8703) option

1 Continuous Time Optimization

The Cagan Model. Lecture 15 by John Kennes March 25

The Measurement Procedure of AB2017 in a Simplified Version of McGrattan 2017

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory. Steve Williamson Dept. of Economics Washington University in St. Louis St. Louis, MO 63130

I. The Solow model. Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis. Universidad Autónoma de Madrid. Autumn 2014

The Neoclassical Growth Model

Micro-foundations: Consumption. Instructor: Dmytro Hryshko

Nominal Exchange Rates Obstfeld and Rogoff, Chapter 8

Economics 230a, Fall 2014 Lecture Note 7: Externalities, the Marginal Cost of Public Funds, and Imperfect Competition

B r i e f T a b l e o f C o n t e n t s

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Preliminary Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2009

Overlapping Generations Model: Dynamic Efficiency and Social Security

1 The Solow Growth Model

Lecture 3 Growth Model with Endogenous Savings: Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model

Chapter 6 Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Lecture Notes in Macroeconomics. Christian Groth

Macroeconomics. Lecture 5: Consumption. Hernán D. Seoane. Spring, 2016 MEDEG, UC3M UC3M

Part A: Answer question A1 (required), plus either question A2 or A3.

Graduate Macro Theory II: Two Period Consumption-Saving Models

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Notes on Intertemporal Optimization

Chapter 5 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth

Graduate Macro Theory II: Fiscal Policy in the RBC Model

Real Business Cycle Theory

The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) only, and the presence of them, or of links to them, on the IMF website does not imply

International Macroeconomics and Finance Session 4-6

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Money, Inflation and Economic Growth

Government debt. Lecture 9, ECON Tord Krogh. September 10, Tord Krogh () ECON 4310 September 10, / 55

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Real Business Cycle Model

Growth and Distributional Effects of Inflation with Progressive Taxation

Chapter 11 of Macroeconomics, Olivier Blanchard and David R. Johnson

Macro II. John Hassler. Spring John Hassler () New Keynesian Model:1 04/17 1 / 10

1 Ricardian Neutrality of Fiscal Policy

Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogenous Growth

EC3115 Monetary Economics

Chapter 3 The Representative Household Model

Question 1 Consider an economy populated by a continuum of measure one of consumers whose preferences are defined by the utility function:

Advanced Macroeconomics Tutorial #2: Solutions

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Assets with possibly negative dividends

Classical monetary economics

Incentives and economic growth

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

Lecture 2: The Neoclassical Growth Model

Microeconomics of Banking: Lecture 2

Business Cycles II: Theories

Slides III - Complete Markets

Macroeconomics Qualifying Examination

Transcription:

14.452. Topic 6. Introducing money Olivier Blanchard April 2007 Nr. 1

1. Motivation No role for money in the models we have looked at. Implicitly, centralized markets, with an auctioneer: Possibly open once, with full set of contingent markets. (Remember, no heterogeneity, no idiosyncratic shocks.) (Arrow Debreu) More appealing. Markets open every period. Spot markets, based on expectations of the future. For example, market for goods, labor, and one period bonds. A sequence of temporary equilibria (Hicks). (no heterogeneity) Still no need for money. An auctioneer. Some clearing house. Nr. 2

So need to move to an economy where money plays a useful role. The required ingredients: No auctioneer. Geographically decentralized trades. Then, problem of double coincidence of wants. Barter is not convenient. Money, accepted on one side of each transaction, is much more so. Two types of questions: Nr. 3

Foundations of monetary theory questions: Why money? What kind of money will emerge? Can there be competing monies? silver/gold. dollars/domestic currency. Fiat versus commodity money? Numeraire versus medium of exchange? Should they be the same, or not? Not just abstract, or history. The rise of barter in Russia in the 1990s. Dollarization in Latin America and hysteresis. Units of account, i.e. a numeraire different from the medium of exchange, in Latin America. But most of the time, we can take it as given that money will be used in transactions, that it will be fiat money, and that the numeraire and the medium of exchange will be the same. Nr. 4

If we take these as given, then we can ask another set of questions: How different does a decentralized economy with money look like? What determines the demand for money, the equilibrium price level, nominal interest rates? How does the presence of money affect the consumption/saving choice? Steady state and dynamic effects on real activity and inflation of changes in the rate of money growth. Start by looking at a benchmark model. Cash in advance (CIA). Then, look at variations on the model; money in the utility function. Then focus on price and inflation dynamics, especially hyperinflation. Nr. 5

2. A cash-in-advance model Ignore uncertainty (need to reintroduce it if look at unexpected changes in money. Also ignore the labor/leisure choice. This will make the basic structure of the model much easier to understand. The optimization problem of consumers i= β i U(C t+i ) subject to: i=0 P t C t +M t+1 +B t+1 +P t K t+1 = W t +Π t +M t +(1+i t )B t +(1+r t )P t K t +X t and P t C t M t + X t Nr. 6

P t C t + M t+1 + B t+1 + P t K t+1 = W t + Π t + M t + (1 + i t )B t + (1 + r t )P t K t + X t P t is the price of goods in terms of the numeraire (the price level). M t, B t, K t are holdings of money, bonds, and capital at the start of period t. W t and Π t are the nominal wage and nominal profit received by each consumer respectively. i t is the nominal interest rate (in dollars, not goods) paid by the bonds. r t is the rental rate (in goods) on capital. Money pays no interest. X t is a nominal transfer from the government (which has to be there if and when we think of changes in money as being implemented by distribution of new money to consumers). Nr. 7

P t C t M t + X t Consumers care only about consumption. Do not derive utility from money. The first constraint is the budget constraint in nominal terms. If the only constraint was the first, then people would hold no money: Bonds pay interest, capital pays a rent, money does not. The second constraint explains why people hold money. Known as the cash in advance (CIA) constraint. People must enter the period with enough nominal money balances to pay for consumption. One potential story: Households: a worker and a consumer. The worker goes to work. The consumer goes to buy goods, before the worker has been paid. More sophisticated formulations? For example: The cost of buying consumption goods decreasing in money balances. Return to this below. Nr. 8

Let λ t+i β i be associated with the budget constraint (the shadow value of wealth), µ t+i β i be associated with the CIA constraint (the shadow value of liquidity). Set up the Lagrangian and derive the FOC. 1 C t : U (C t ) = (λ t + µ t )P t ( C t = λ t + µ t ) P t M t+1 : λ t = β(λ t+1 + µ t+1 ) B t+1 : λ t = β(1 + i t+1 )λ t+1 K t+1 : λ t P t = β(1 + r t+1 ) λ t+1 P t+1 Nr. 9

We can manipulate these conditions to get an intertemporal condition on the marginal utility of consumption: From the third and the fourth: (1 + i t+1 ) = (1 + r t+1 ) P t+1 = (1 + r t+1 )(1 + π t+1 ) P t From the first and second: Replacing in the third: U (C t+1 ) U (C t+2 ) λ t = β λ t+1 = β P t+1 P t+2 U (C t+1 ) = β(1 + it+1 ) U (C t+2 ) P t+1 P t+2 Divide both sides by (1 + i t+1 ), and then multiply and divide the second term by (1 + i t+2 ), to get: Nr. 10

U (C t+1 ) = β(1 + rt+2 ) U (C t+2 ) 1 + i t+1 1 + i t+2 Interpretation: Because people have to hold money one period in advance, the effective price of consumption is not 1 but 1 + i. Once we adjust for this price effect, get the same old relation, between marginal utility this period, marginal utility next period, and the real interest rate. Note the role of both the nominal and the real interest rates. Note that if the nominal interest rate is constant, the equation reduces to the standard Euler equation (Why not C t and C t+1?) U (C t+1 ) = β(1 + r t+2 )U (C t+2 ) Nr. 11

Turn to the characterization of money demand. From the second and third condition: µ t+1 = i t+1 λ t+1 So as long as the nominal interest rate is positive, µ will be positive, and so: M t + X t = C t P t Pure quantity theory. No interest rate elasticity. Nr. 12

Equilibrium Assume firms rent capital and labor, so P t F N (K t, N t ) = W t F K (K t, N t ) = r t δ Given constant returns and competitive markets, pure profit Π t = 0 Employment, N t is equal to 1 (inelastic supply) Money introduced through lump sum transfers to consumers ( helicopter drops ). (Alternative: Money used by the government to buy goods). M t+1 M t = X t As bonds are issued by agents (not firms, renting capital and labor services) and all agents are identical, in equilibrium, there are no bonds outstanding B t+1 = B t = 0 Nr. 13

Replacing all these conditions in the accumulation equation of consumersworkers gives: P t C t + P t K t+1 = P t F N (K t, 1) + (1 + F K (K t, 1) δ)p t K t Or, dividing by P t, and reorganizing: K t+1 = F (K t, 1) + (1 δ)k t C t So, exactly the same condition as in the non monetary economy. Nr. 14

Putting the relevant equations together: U (C t+1 ) = β(1 + rt+2 ) U (C t+2 ) 1 + i t+1 1 + i t+2 (1 + i t ) = (1 + r t )(1 + π t ) (1 + r t ) = 1 δ + F K (K t, 1) M t + X t = C t P t K t+1 = F (K t, 1) + (1 δ)k t C t Nr. 15

Steady state Let growth of nominal money be x, so (X t /P t ) = x(m t /P t ) From the FOC of the consumers, and the demand for capital by firms: (1 + r) = 1 + F K (K, 1) δ = 1/β Same as without money: Modified golden rule. Using these relations in the budget constraint gives: C = F (K, 1) δk Money growth has no effect on activity. Superneutrality In steady state, real money balances must be constant, so: π = x Inflation is equal to money growth. And so, i = π + r = x + r. Fisher effect (from Irving Fisher). Nr. 16

Dynamics Harder to characterize. Come from the consumption wedge. x i. Easy however to guess the solution to simple paths for money. π An unexpected permanent increase in money leads to an equal proportional increase in the price level, and no change in the real variables. An unexpected permanent increase in money growth, from x to x. In this case, this leads to a proportional increase in the price level today, and inflation at rate x from then on. Nominal interest rates increase by x x. Real variables are unaffected. Any path that generates a decrease in the interest rate and an increase in consumption in response to an increase in nominal money growth? (Stylized facts) Not obvious: Think temporary increase in money growth: temp increase in inflation, in nominal rates. Temporary decrease in consumption. Nr. 17

Conclusions We have seen how we can introduce money as a medium of exchange in GE models. The monetary economy does not look very different from the economies we had looked at until now. The consumption/saving choice is modified, but not transformed. There is now a demand for money is a function of transactions. The real effects of money are limited. In steady state, money is not only neutral, but superneutral Changes in money may have dynamic effects on real variables. But these effects appear to be limited. Nr. 18

Extensions The CIA model we looked at had an extremely simple cash in advance constraint. More general ones, with money demand function of interest rate. GE version of Baumol Tobin, by Romer (See BF, Chapter 4) Baumol-Tobin: Households decide how often to go to the bank to exchange money for bonds. The higher the interest rate, the more often they go, the lower their average real money balances. In these models, changes in money have distributional effects (between those who go to the bank and those who do not) and thus effects on real activity. But effects appear limited (and exotic). CIA models can become very unwieldy. Short cuts? Money in the utility function. Nr. 19

3. Money in the Utility function Consider the following optimization problem (Sidrauski model): Consumers/workers maximize: subject to: β i U(C t+i, M t+i ) P t+i P t C t + M t+1 + B t+1 = W t + Π t + M t + (1 + i t )B t + X t (Consumers/workers own the firms) Think of the utility function as a reduced form of a more complex problem in which by holding more money, households can shop more efficiently, increase leisure time, and so on. Plausibly U m > 0 and U mc 0 (why?). Nr. 20

First order conditions For simplicity, ignore uncertainty. Let λ t+i β i be the lagrange multiplier associated with the constraint. Then the FOC are given by: M t C t : U c (C t, ) = λ t P t P t B t+1 : λ t = λ t+1 β(1 + i t+1 ) 1 M t+1 M t+1 : λ t = β[λ t+1 + U m (C t+1, )] P t+1 P t+1 Nr. 21

Rewrite as: An intertemporal condition: An intratemporal condition U c (C t, M t ) = β(1 + r t+1 )U c (C t+1, M t+1 ) P t P t+1 U m (C t, M t )/U c (C t, M t ) = i t P t P t Ratio of marginal utilities has to be equal to the opportunity cost of holding money, so i, the nominal interest rate. Nr. 22

If for example, U(C, M/P ) = log(c) + a log(m/p ) (not an appealing assumption, as U cm = 0, but very convenient) Then, (1/C t ) = β(1 + r t+1 )(1/C t+1 ) (M t /P t ) = a(c t /i t ) This gives us an IS and an LM relation. The IS: the higher the interest rate, the lower consumption given expected consumption in the future. The LM: The demand for money is a function of the level of transactions, here measured by consumption, and the opportunity cost of holding money, i. Under these assumptions, no distortion in the intertemporal consumption decision. Nr. 23

Steady state The firms side is the same as before, so: 1 + F K (K, 1) δ = 1/β C = F (K, 1) δk M M U m (C, )/U c (C, ) = (x + r) P P So, same real allocation again. Superneutrality of money. And a level of real money balances inversely proportional to the rate of inflation, itself equal to the rate of money growth. Nr. 24

What is the optimal rate of money growth? As money is costless to produce, the optimal rate is such as to drive the marginal utility of real money to zero, so to drive i = x + r to zero. In other words, it is to have x = r: Money growth or inflation negative and equal to minus the marginal product of capital. This result is known as the Optimum Quantity of Money (the semantics are not great, as this is a result about money growth, not level.) Nr. 25

Dynamics and conclusions Dynamic effects of changes in money on real activity? In general, yes, but limited. (see next slides) And nothing which looks like the real effects of money in the real world. Bottom line: Money as a medium of exchange, without nominal rigidities gives us a way of thinking about the economy, the price level, the nominal interest rate, but not much in the way of explaining fluctuations. Very useful however when money growth and inflation become high and variable. Turn to this. Nr. 26

[A simulation of the Sidrauski model] Utility function given by: 1 U(C t, m t ) = 1 σ [(ac 1 b t + (1 a)m 1 t b ) 1/(1 b) ] 1 σ 1/b elasticity of substitution between C and m, equal to 1/16. σ =.5, a =.975. (U Cm > 0 if b > σ). Effects of an increase in the rate of nominal money growth of 1%, returning to normal at rate.8 per period. Interpretation of results. Why does consumption go down? What would happen to labor supply if it were endogenous. Nr. 27

0.12 3 inflation 0.45 nominal r 0.2 money 0.1 0.1 2.5 0.4 0.35 0 0.2 0 0.1 0.08 2 0.3 0.4 0.6 0.2 0.25 0.06 1.5 0.8 0.3 0.04 0.02 capital 0 0 5 10 1 0.5 0 0 5 10 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 0 5 10 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 0.4 0.5 0.6 consumpti 1.8 0 5 0.7 10 0 5 10 Nr. 28

3. Money growth, inflation, seignorage Inflation and Money Growth during Seven Hyperinflations of the 1920s and 1940s Country Beginning End P T /P 0 Av Monthly Inf rate (%) Av Monthly M Growth (%) Austria Oct. 1921 Aug. 1922 70 47 31 Germany Aug. 1922 Nov. 1923 1.0x10 10 322 314 Greece Nov. 1943 Nov. 1944 4.7x10 6 365 220 Hungary 1 Mar. 1923 Feb. 1924 44 46 33 Hungary 2 Aug. 1945 Jul. 1946 3.8x10 27 19,800 12,200 Poland Jan. 1923 Jan. 1924 699 82 72 Russia Dec. 1921 Jan. 1924 1.2x10 5 57 49 P T /P 0 : Price level in the last month of hyperinflation divided by the price level in the first month. Source: Philip Cagan, 1956. Nr. 29

Was hyperinflation the result of money growth, and only money growth? Why was money growth so high? Did it maximize seignorage (revenues from money creation). And if not, then why? What was the role of fiscal policy? Nr. 30

Start with the money demand in the spirit of that we have just derived: M t = C t L(r t + π t e ) P t If money growth and inflation are high and variable, M, P and π e will move a lot relative to C and r. So assume, for simplicity, that C t = C, and r t = r, so: M t = C L(r + π t e ) P t This gives a relation between the price level and the expected rate of inflation. The higher expected inflation, the lower real money balances, the higher the price level. Nr. 31

Shift to continuous time, more convenient here. Assume a particular form for the demand for money: M/P = exp( απ e ) So, in logs: m p = α π e Log real money balances are a decreasing function of expected inflation. Differentiating with respect to time: x π = α dπ e /dt Assume that people have adaptive expectations about expected inflation. (In an environment such as hyperinflation, this assumption makes a lot of sense. More on rational expectations below). dπ e /dt = β (π π e ) Nr. 32

Money growth and inflation Suppose money growth is constant, at x. Will inflation converge to π = x? Combine the two equations above to get: β dπt e = (x π e ) 1 αβ If αβ > 1, then unstable. Why? (x π dπ e π, and so on) If αβ < 1, then the equilibrium is stable. Start with x > 0, and π = 0. Then converge to π = π e = x. Effects of an increase in x? Jump in π above the new x, then back to new x over time. Why? Cagan estimated α and β, found αβ < 1. Hyperinflation was the result of money growth, not a bubble. Nr. 33

Seignorage and money growth What is the maximum revenue the government can get from money creation: So, in steady state: S dm/dt = dm/dt M = x exp( απ e ) P M P S = x exp( αx) So x = 1/α Much lower than the growth rates of money observed during hyperinflation. But just a steady state result. Can clearly get more in the short run, when π e has not adjusted yet. This suggests looking at dynamics: Given seignorage, dynamics of money growth and inflation. Nr. 34

Start from: 1 S = x exp( απ e ) or π e = (log(x/s) α For a given S, draw the relation between π e and x in π e, x space. Concave. Can cross the 45 degree line twice, once if tangent, not at all if no way to generate the required seignorage in steady state. Which equilibrium is stable? Using the equation for adaptive expectations and the money demand relation in derivative form: dπ e /dt = β/(1 αβ) (x π e ) If αβ < 1, and if two equilibria, lower one is stable. Start from it (A), and suppose S increases so no equilibrium (go below G G ). See Figure. Then, money growth and inflation will keep increasing. This appears to capture what happens during hyperinflations. Nr. 35

Dynamics of seignorage and inflation e ab<1 B e = x GG G G Max ss seignorage G G A A S S* S** x Nr. 36

Nominal Money Growth and Seignorage, during hyperinflations. Austria Germany Greece Hungary 1 Hungary 2 Poland Russia Rate of Money Growth Maximizing Seignorage (% per month) 12 20 28 12 32 54 39 Implied Seignorage (% of output) 13 14 11 19 6 4.6 0.5 Actual Rate of Money Growth (% per month) 31 314 220 33 12,200 72 49 Monthly rate of nominal money growth, in percent. Nr. 37

Some other issues Adaptive or rational expectations? (see BF 5-1) Recent work by Sargent. Learning. Fiscal policy, and the effects of inflation on the need for seignorage. (See Dornbusch et al) Inflation may itself reduce revenues. Unpleasant monetarist arithmetic? (see BF 10-2) For a given deficit, government can finance by debt or money. Which will lead to more inflation today? Nr. 38

Summary Need to introduce money for transactions. CIA constraints. but can get complicated. Shortcut. (Real money) in the utility function. Nominal interest rates affect the demand for money, real interest rates affect the slope of consumption. Money often superneutral. Real effects from dynamics do not resemble what is in the data. Money growth central to inflation, hyperinflation. The strong link be tween fiscal policy and monetary policy. Nr. 39