From Communism to Capitalism: Private vs. Public Property and Rising. Inequality in China and Russia

Similar documents
From Communism to Capitalism: Private Versus Public Property and Inequality in China and Russia

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL INEQUALITY DYNAMICS: NEW FINDINGS FROM WID.WORLD

The World Wealth and Income Database (WID.world) aims to provide open and convenient access to the historical evolution of

The Elephant Curve of Global Inequality and Growth *

Capital Accumulation, Private Property, and Inequality in China,

!! Inequality in Poland: Estimating the whole distribution by g-percentile,

Working paper series. Simplified Distributional National Accounts. Thomas Piketty Emmanuel Saez Gabriel Zucman. January 2019

Applying Generalized Pareto Curves to Inequality Analysis

Global economic inequality: New evidence from the World Inequality Report

Income Inequality in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

Capital Accumulation, Private Property and Rising Inequality in China,

Inequality Dynamics in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

Capital in the 21 st century

Inequality and growth Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics

World Inequality. Executive Summary. Facundo Alvaredo. Emmanuel Saez Gabriel Zucman. English version. Coordinated by

Capital in the 21 st century

Income Inequality in Korea,

Introduction of World Wealth and Income Database

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2017 preliminary estimates)

Income and Wealth Concentration in Switzerland over the 20 th Century

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Visby, June

Capital in the 21 st century. Thomas Piketty Paris School of Economics Cologne, December 5 th 2013

Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States (Updated with 2009 and 2010 estimates)

Income Inequality and Progressive Income Taxation in China and India, Thomas Piketty and Nancy Qian

Capital is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries Thomas Piketty & Gabriel Zucman Paris School of Economics October 2012

TOP INCOMES IN THE UNITED STATES AND CANADA OVER THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. What is Income? Gabriel Zucman

FIGURE I.1. Income inequality in the United States,

Should the Rich Pay for Fiscal Adjustment? Income and Capital Tax Options

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. Public University of Navarre Pamplona, Spain May 21 st 2018 J. E. Stiglitz

Capitalism, Inequality & Globalization. J. E. Stiglitz Davidson College March 2018

2.5. Income inequality in France

Is China Socialist? By Barry Naughton, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Winter 2017 Introduction A socialist system should be judged on four

China s Financial Markets: An Overview Summary Historical Overview of the Financial Markets

THE GLOBAL PATTERN OF HOUSEHOLD WEALTH

Income Inequality in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

LECTURE 14: THE INEQUALITY OF CAPITAL OWNERSHIP IN EUROPE AND THE USA

Chapter 2 China s National Balance Sheet: Preparation and Analysis

Maurizio Franzini and Mario Planta

Rethinking Wealth Taxation

ECONOMIC COMMENTARY. Income Inequality Matters, but Mobility Is Just as Important. Daniel R. Carroll and Anne Chen

Foreign Trade and Capital Exports

Econ 230B Graduate Public Economics. Models of the wealth distribution. Gabriel Zucman

Labor force participation of the elderly in Japan

World inequality report

McKinsey Global Institute. Mapping the Global Capital Market 2006 Second Annual Report

Measuring Wealth Inequality in Europe: A Quest for the Missing Wealthy

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. What is Income? Gabriel Zucman

LECTURE 12: THE 1 PERCENT IN EUROPE AND THE USA

Attila Tapaszti Zsanett Sütő: Push and pull! Developments in the renminbi exchange rate

Econ 133 Global Inequality and Growth. Inequality between labor and capital. Gabriel Zucman

ec nfip Economists for Inclusive Prosperity

Germany s current account and global adjustment

BOFIT Forecast for China

KGP/World income distribution: past, present and future.

Challenges For the Future of Chinese Economic Growth. Jane Haltmaier* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. August 2011.

Unprecedented Change. Investment opportunities in an ageing world JUNE 2010 FOR PROFESSIONAL ADVISERS ONLY

GLOBAL INEQUALITY AND AUSTRALIA S ROLE

China s Growth Miracle: Past, Present, and Future

Finance, an Inequality Factor

Update on Homeownership Wealth Trajectories Through the Housing Boom and Bust

Tools of Budget Analysis (Chapter 4 in Gruber s textbook) 131 Undergraduate Public Economics Emmanuel Saez UC Berkeley

Wealth Inequality Reading Summary by Danqing Yin, Oct 8, 2018

SYMPOSIUM ON PUBLIC BUDGETING AND FINANCE REFORMS IN CHINA: PART I Editor: Kuotsai Tom Liou

Globalization, Inequality, and Tax Justice

About Capital in the 21 st Century

2012 Canazei Winter Workshop on Inequality

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS. Economics 134 Spring 2018 Professor David Romer LECTURE 19

Inheritances and Inequality across and within Generations

Income Inequality in France, : Evidence from Distributional National Accounts (DINA)

Two Cheers for Piketty

BANK OF FINLAND ARTICLES ON THE ECONOMY

Money and Banking. Lecture XII: Financial Risks in the Chinese Economy. Guoxiong ZHANG, Ph.D. December 5th, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Antai

WORKING PAPER SERIES N

arxiv: v2 [q-fin.ec] 1 Sep 2014

The Distribution of US Wealth, Capital Income and Returns since Emmanuel Saez (UC Berkeley) Gabriel Zucman (LSE and UC Berkeley)

Wealth, Inequality & Taxation T. Piketty, IMF Supplementary slides

POST-CRISIS GLOBAL REBALANCING CONFERENCE ON GLOBALIZATION AND THE LAW OF THE SEA WASHINGTON DC, DEC 1-3, Barry Bosworth

Banking Crises Throughout the World

Crestmont Research. Rowing vs. The Roller Coaster By Ed Easterling January 26, 2007 All Rights Reserved

Ross Garnaut The University of Melbourne 8 April The Centre for Contemporary Chinese Studies

Azerbaijan s foreign trade; Comparative Analysis

long run inequality History and Inequality University of Oslo

Global Imbalances and Current Account Imbalances

an eye on east asia and pacific

Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Policy Note WHEN A RISING TIDE SINKS MOST BOATS: TRENDS IN US INCOME INEQUALITY

STRUCTURAL REFORM REFORMING THE PENSION SYSTEM IN KOREA. Table 1: Speed of Aging in Selected OECD Countries. by Randall S. Jones

Research on the Synergy Effect of Cross-border Mergers and. Acquisitions in High-tech Enterprises in Shanghai. Yuzhu FENG

Executive Summary. Trends in Inequality: Globally and Nationally. How inequality constraints growth

Introduction. industrialization (ISI) to export-oriented growth was due to numerous supply side


INCOME AND WEALTH INEQUALITY: EVIDENCE AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS*

Lecture 3: Income & Wage Taxation Over Time & Across Countries (check on line for updated versions)

OVERVIEW of INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS

Ibbotson Associates Research Paper. Lifetime Asset Allocations: Methodologies for Target Maturity Funds (Summary) May 2009

Distributional National Accounts DINA

The Economic Program. June 2014

Antonio Fazio: Overview of global economic and financial developments in first half 2004

Deciphering the fall and rise in the net capital share by Matthew Rognlie, MIT BPEA Conference Draft (March, 2015)

Statistics Brief. Inland transport infrastructure investment on the rise. Infrastructure Investment. August

Transcription:

From Communism to Capitalism: Private vs. Public Property and Rising Inequality in China and Russia Filip Novokmet (Paris School of Economics) Thomas Piketty (Paris School of Economics) Li Yang (Paris School of Economics) Gabriel Zucman (UC Berkeley and NBER) Abstract: This paper combines national accounts, survey, wealth and fiscal data (including recently released tax data on high-income taxpayers) in order to provide consistent series on the accumulation and distribution of income and wealth in China and Russia over the 1978-2015 period. We contrast the different speed and magnitude of privatization observed in the two countries and relate these findings to the differences in inequality levels.

*This paper has been prepared for presentation at the AEA 2018 meetings (Philadelpia). Novokmet: Paris School of Economics, 48 Boulevard Jourdan, 75014 Paris, (e-mail: filip.novokmet@psemail.eu); Piketty: Paris School of Economics, 48 Boulevard Jourdan, 75014 Paris, (e-mail: piketty@psemail.eu); Yang: Paris School of Economics, 48 Boulevard Jourdan, 75014 Paris and Xiamen University (e-mail: li.yang@psemail.eu); Zucman: University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720, and NBER (e-mail: zucman@berkeley.edu).

Introduction Since 1980, many economies around the world saw two strong ongoing trends: rise of private wealth together with rise of income inequality (Piketty and Zucman 2014; Piketty 2014). These trends are especially phenomenal in China and Russia since their transitions away from communism (Piketty, Yang, and Zucman 2017; Novokmet, Piketty, and Zucman 2017). Indeed, the transition away from communism in both China and Russia had profound effects on aggregate wealth and income inequality in both countries. However, there were also considerable differences between the two countries due to the institutional differences, particularly their respective privatization strategies for public assets. In China, the transition ushered in gradual but nevertheless wide-reaching reforms, expanding geographically from special economic zones in coastal cities towards inland provincial regions, and in sectoral waves, while Russia has experienced a big-bang model of transition from the previously planned, state-led economy to one that was to be led by free-market principles after the fall of the Soviet Union in 1990 1991. In this paper, we compare our recent findings of private and public wealth accumulation, as well as rise of income inequality resulting from the different strategies of privatization in the two countries. Privatization and Rise of Private Wealth Private Wealth vs. Public Wealth Figure 1

A general rise in the ratio between net private wealth and national income has been observed in nearly all countries in recent decades (Piketty and Zucman 2014; Piketty 2014; Piketty, Yang, and Zucman 2017; Novokmet, Piketty, and Zucman 2017), which can be attributed to a combination of factors including the combination of growth slowdowns and relatively high saving rates and general rises in asset prices. The case of China and Russia can be viewed as an extreme case of this general evolution. Especially, the liberalization and public asset privatization strategies chosen by the two countries also had crucial impacts on the development of these countries wealth to national income ratios. After the transitions away from communism, China and Russia both experienced large rises in their private wealth-income ratios. While to some extent these increases are to be expected (as a large proportion of public wealth is transferred to the private sector), the scale of change experienced is particularly striking in China. At the time of the opening-up policy reforms in 1978, private wealth in China amounted to just over 110% of national income, but by 2015, this figure had reached 490%, following almost unrelenting rises. Russia s transition began twelve years later in 1990, but the change since has been no less spectacular. Over this shorter period of time, Russia s private wealth-income ratio more than tripled from around 120% to 370%, which mostly come at the expense of public wealth. In Russia, the voucher privatization strategy chosen aimed to transfer public assets into the private sector as quickly as possible, and subsequently had the effect of reducing the net public wealth to national income ratio enormously, from over 230% of national income in 1990 to around 90% in 2015. In contrast, the gradual process of privatization of public wealth in China led to a slight over-fall in the value of public wealth as a proportion of national income, from just over 250% of national income in 1978 to approximately 230% in 2015, in a context of rapidly rising asset prices. (See Figure 1)

Composition of Private Wealth Figure 2 In order to better understand the processes at work, it is critical to look separately at the different asset categories. The most noticeable finding is the critical role played by housing in the rise of private wealth (Figure 2). Although the method by which property wealth was privatized was different, private housing assets has been increasing dramatically since the beginning of transition in both countries. In order to transform the welfare housing system into market-oriented housing system, the Chinese central government launched several waves housing reforms since 1978 (Yang&Chen 2014). Especially, in 1991 the property rights of privatized housing were officially recognized by the State Council. 1 Since then Chinese citizens had had been experiencing rapid urban housing privatizing transition and huge reductions in welfare housing allocations, and by 2002, 85% of urban housing was privately-owned (by 2015, the percentage increases to 95%). Additionally, following the housing privatization and housing market liberalization, housing price has been escalating. As the result, private housing (net debt) has increased more than 3 times since 1991 from 60% of national income to 182% of national income in 2015 (Figure 2 Panel A). In Russia, on the other hand, private housing increased from less than 50% of national income in 1990 to 250% of national income in 2008-2009 (at the peak of the housing bubble), down to about 170% of national income by 2015 (Figure 2 Panel B). In addition to real estate price movements, the gradual rise of private housing between 1990 and 2015 can be accounted for by the fact that housing privatization happened in a more continuous manner than the voucher privatization 1 The resolutions of the state council about actively and appropriately carry out urban housing reform (SC [1991] No. 30)

method used for companies. What is particularly striking is the very low level of recorded financial assets owned by Russian households. Household financial assets have always been less than 70-80% of national income throughout the 1990-2015 period, and they have often been less than 50% of national income (e.g. in 2015 household equity assets are 18% of national income and household saving is 38% of national income). In effect, it is as if the privatization of Russian companies did not lead to any significant long-run rise in the value of household financial assets, although, it is the private sector now own the equity shares of Russian firms. While in China household equity and saving assets have been increasing significantly since 1978. Following the reform of SOEs and establishment of stock exchange markets in China, corporate sector saw its private capital increasing significantly from 0 in 1978 to 90% of national income in 2015, which accounts for more than 30% of total corporate equity in China. Meanwhile, due to the high saving rate and tight capital outflow control, together with the increase of the economy, Chinese household saving increases from 17% of national income to 140% national income. In our view, the widely divergent patterns of household financial assets accumulation observed in Russia and China can be accounted for the substantial offshore wealth hold by a small subset of Russian households. According to Novokmet, Piketty, and Zucman (2017), offshore wealth has gradually increased between 1990 and 2015, and represents about 75% of national income by 2015, ie., roughly as much as the recorded financial

assets of Russian households. 2 It is hard to pin down an accurate number of China s offshore private wealth, however, it is reasonable acclaim that China s offshore wealth is much less than Russia s due to the tight control of capital flow. The Decline of Public Property Figure 3 It is also interesting to compare the evolution of the overall share of public property in Russia and other countries (Figure 3). In developed countries, the share of net public wealth in net national wealth was significantly positive in the post-ww2 decades up until about 1980, around 15-25% of national wealth, reflecting low public debt and significant public assets. Net public wealth declined significantly since the 1980s, due both to the rise of public debt and the privatization of public assets. By 2015 net public wealth has turned negative in Britain, Japan and the U.S., and is barely positive in Germany and France. Ex-communist countries like Russia, China and the Czech Republic have followed the same general pattern as developed countries in recent decades namely a declining share of public property but starting from a much higher level of public wealth. In these three ex-communist countries, the share of net public wealth was as large as 70-80% in 1980, and falls between 20% (Russia) and 30-35% (China and the Czech Republic) in 2015, i.e. a level that is higher but not incomparable to that observed in capitalist countries during the mixed 2 Novokmet, Piketty, and Zucman (2017) estimate the magnitude of the offshore wealth in Russia by exploiting the large discrepancies between trade balance surpluses (in the first place, from oil and gas exports) and net foreign assets accumulation. Namely, they cumulate net errors and omissions and capital transfer outflows in the balance of payments.

economy period (1950-1980). In other words, these countries have ceased to be communist, in the sense that public ownership has ceased to be the dominant form of property, but they still have much more significant public wealth than other capitalist countries. This is due both to low public debt and significant public assets (including in Russia in the energy sector). There are also strong differences between these countries. In particular, the privatization process was much more gradual in China than in Russia: it started earlier, and is still going on. In China public owned corporate equity increase from about 60% of national income in 1990 to 149% of national income in 2015, which account for about 55% of the total corporate equity in China. In contract the public owned equity stabilized in a very low level since 1990 in Russia, by 2015, public equity assets is only 13% of national income. The gradual privatization pattern observed in the Czech Republic is intermediate between the two, and is in some ways closer to China. Income Inequality Next, we present the findings on income inequality dynamics in China and Russia in Figure 4. The new income distribution series for China and Russia are constructed by combining national accounts, survey, wealth, and fiscal data. Income inequality has increased markedly in both China and Russia since the beginning of their respective transition to the market economy. Figure 4 displays the income inequality dynamics in China and Russia since 1978 by looking at the evolutions of the top 10% and the bottom 50% income shares (Panel A) and the evolution of the top 1% income share (Panel B). According to our estimates, inequality was somewhat higher in China than in Russia in 1978 (due in particular to the substantial

urban-rural gap), but has now become substantially higher in Russia. In particular, it is striking to see that the rise in income inequality in Russia occurred so rapidly after the fall of the Soviet Union. The top 10% income share in Russia rose from less than 25% in 1990-1991 to more than 45% already in 1996, and has stagnated at levels around 45-50% since then. This enormous rise of the top 10% income share in Russia came together with a massive collapse of the bottom 50% share, which dropped from about 30% of total income in 1990-1991 to less than 10% in 1996, before gradually returning to about 18% by 2015. In China, the rise in income inequality was substantial between 1978 and 2015 with the top 10% income share rising from 27% to 41% and the bottom 50% income share declining from 27% to 15% but it occurred in much more gradual manner than observed in Russia. However, the development of the top 1 percent income share suggests markedly higher top income concentration in Russia than in China (Panel B). In Russia, we observe a sharp and continuous rise of the top 1% income shares, from less than 6% in 1989 to about 16% in 1996, and over 26% in 2008, which then dropped in the aftermath of the 2008-2009 financial crisis and stabilized around 20-22% since 2010. In China, the top 1 percent income share has more than doubled in size since the beginning of the market reforms, rising from 6% to 14% between 1978 and 2015, but is still substantially lower than in Russia. As a result, Russia, who used to be more equal than China, has become one of the most unequal countries in the world. Figure 4 The evolution of income inequality in China and Russia also reflects the different privatization strategies pursued in the two countries. As noted above, this can be related to the fact that the privatization process was

much more gradual in China, where the government is still the largest corporate owner. We also observe much higher increase in top income shares in Russia than in ex-communist countries in Eastern Europe (Novokmet 2017), suggesting overall the importance of post-communist transition policies and institutions for the divergent income and wealth inequality dynamics in former communist countries. In Russia, there was arguably the most dramatic regime shift, manifested in very fast shock therapy and voucher privatization. It is plausible that within a chaotic monetary and political context of the Russian transition (e.g. institutional economies of scale ; Guriev and Rachinsky 2008), small groups of individuals were able to buy back large quantities of vouchers at relatively low prices, and also in some cases to obtain highly profitable deals with public authorities (e.g. via the infamous loans-for-shares agreements). Together with capital flight and the rise of offshore wealth, this process arguably led to extreme level of wealth and income concentration in Russia (Figure 5). This finding is consistent with the Forbes billionaire data, showing a much higher level of billionaire wealth in Russia than in China or ex-communist countries in Eastern Europe. Figure 5 A further insight into divergent transition outcomes could be obtained by looking at the distributional impact of growth in Table 1. The economic transformation has produced much higher growth in China than in Russia. Notwithstanding the fact that in both countries growth has not been equally shared, with higher income groups enjoying higher growth rates, the outstanding growth experience in China entailed that lower income groups also saw a substantial increase in their living standards. On the other hand, the bulk of the post-communist growth in Russia has been captured by the top incomes. Over the 1989-2016 period, the top 1% experienced very high growth rates and captured more than two-third of the total growth in Russia, while the bottom 50%

actually saw a decline in its living standard. This suggests that Russian capitalism places few constraints on top incomes (partly coming from outright plundering of the country s natural resources and foreign reserves), and shows high tolerance for extreme inequality after the failure of Soviet Communism and its egalitarian ideology. Ideology matters. The enormous ideological shift that occurred in Russia could be seen as an extreme version of the ideological reversal in the US and many western countries since the 1980s. On the other hand, it is plausible that the present Chinese development model is subject to stronger ideological constraints that may mitigate the more extreme rise of inequality in the future. Table 1 Conclusion The dramatic economic transformation has resulted in the substantial increase in inequality in China and Russia. However, the rise of inequality was much more pronounced and immediate in Russia, and more limited and gradual in China. Markedly divergent post-communist inequality patterns suggest that the rise in inequality is not inevitable and point to the importance of policies, institutions and ideology in shaping inequality.

Reference Guriev, S., & Rachinsky, A. (2008) The Evolution of Personal Wealth in the Former Soviet Union and Central and Eastern Europe, In J.B. Davies ed., Personal Wealth Prom a Global Perspective, pp. 134-149, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2008. Novokmet, F., Piketty, T., & Zucman, G. (2017) From Soviets to Oligarchs: Inequality and Property in Russia, 1905-2016, NBER working paper 23712. Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st Century. Cambridge: Harvard Uni, 696. Piketty, T., Yang, L., & Zucman, G. (2017). Capital Accumulation, Private Property and Rising Inequality in China, 1978-2015. NBER working paper 23368, June 2017, R&R American Economic Review. Piketty, T., & Zucman, G. (2014). Capital is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries 1700-2010. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(3), 1255 1310. Yang, Z., & Chen, J. (2014). Housing affordability and housing policy in urban China. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer.

500% 450% 400% 350% Figure 1: Public vs private property in China andrussia 1978-2015 (% national income) Net private wealth (China) Net public wealth (China) Net private wealth (Russia) Net public wealth (Russia) 300% 250% 200% 150% 100% 50% 0% 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014

500% 450% 400% 350% Savings Equity Figure 2 Panel A: Composition of Private Wealth in China 1978-2015 (% national income) Non housing-non financial assets Housing (net debt) 300% 250% 200% 150% 100% 50% 0% 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014

500% 450% 400% 350% Figure 2 Panel B: Composition of Private Wealth in Russia 1990-2015 (% national income) Offshore wealth Savings Equity Non housing-non financial assets Housing (net debt) 300% 250% 200% 150% 100% 50% 0% 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014

100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% Figure 3: The decline of public property: China vs Russia vs other countries (share of net public wealth in net national wealth) China Russia Czech Rep. USA Japan France Britain Germany 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% -10% 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 2008 2012

55% 50% 45% 40% Figure 4 Panel A: Income shares in China and Russia, 1978-2015 Top 10% (China) Bottom 50% (China) Top 10% (Russia) Bottom 50% (Russia) 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 Distribution of pretax national income (before taxes and transfers, except pensions and unempl. insurance) among adults. Corrected estimates combine survey, fiscal, wealth and national accounts data. Raw estimates rely only on self-reported survey data. Equal-split-adults series (income of married couples divided by two).

30% Figure 4 Panel B: Income shares in China and Russia, 1978-2015 25% Top 1% (China) 20% Top 1% (Russia) 15% 10% 5% 0% 1978 1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014 Distribution of pretax national income (before taxes and transfers, except pensions and unempl. insurance) among adults. Corrected estimates combine survey, fiscal, wealth and national accounts data. Raw estimates rely only on self-reported survey data. Equal-split-adults series (income of married couples divided by two).

50% 45% Figure 5: Top 1% wealth share: China, Russia, the US and France Russia USA China France 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 Distribution of personal wealth among adults. Estimates obtained by combining Forbes billionaire data for Russia, generalized Pareto interpolation techniques and normalized WID.world wealth distributions.

Table 1: Average annual growth rate 1978-2015 Income group (distribution of per adult pre-tax national income) China (1978-2015) Russia (1980-2015) USA (1978-2015) Full Population 6.2% 1.1% 1.3% Bottom 50% 4.5% -0.5% 0.0% Middle 40% 6.0% 0.5% 0.9% Top 10% 7.4% 3.3% 2.1% incl. Top 1% 8.4% 6.2% 3.0% incl. Top 0.1% 9.1% 9.9% 4.0% incl. Top 0.01% 9.8% 13.4% 4.7% incl. Top 0.001% 10.4% 17.0% 5.7% Souces: China: Piketty, Yang and Zucman (2017). Russia: Novokmet, Piketty and Zucman (2017). USA: Piketty- Saez-Zucman (2016). Distribution of pre-tax national income among equal-split adults. The unit is the adult individual (20-year-old and over; income of married couples is splitted into two). Fractiles are defined relative to the total number of adult individuals in the population. Corrected estimates (combining survey, fiscal, wealth and national accounts data).