A Simple Theory of Offshoring and Reshoring

Similar documents
Combining Semi-Endogenous and Fully Endogenous Growth: a Generalization.

R&D and Economic Growth in a Cash-in-Advance Economy

Growth Accounting and Endogenous Technical Change

International Trade

Depreciation: a Dangerous Affair

ECON Micro Foundations

Supply-side effects of monetary policy and the central bank s objective function. Eurilton Araújo

5. COMPETITIVE MARKETS

A Schumpeterian Analysis of Monetary Policy, Innovation and North-South Technology Transfer

Comparative Statics. What happens if... the price of one good increases, or if the endowment of one input increases? Reading: MWG pp

FDI with Reverse Imports and Hollowing Out

Endogenous Markups in the New Keynesian Model: Implications for In ation-output Trade-O and Optimal Policy

OPTIMAL INCENTIVES IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT MODEL WITH ENDOGENOUS TECHNOLOGY. WP-EMS Working Papers Series in Economics, Mathematics and Statistics

Lobby Interaction and Trade Policy

Learning by Doing and Fragmentation

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #9 - Monopoly

Task O shoring and Organizational Form: Evidence from China

From Solow to Romer: Teaching Endogenous Technological Change in Undergraduate Economics

Intergenerational Bargaining and Capital Formation

Fuel-Switching Capability

Growth with Time Zone Differences

Real Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade Obstfeld and Rogo, Chapter 4

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

ESSAYS ON TRADE LIBERALIZATION WITH FIRM HETEROGENEITY. Aleksandr Vashchilko. Dissertation. Submitted to the faculty of the

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 5: The Ricardo-Viner and Heckscher-Ohlin Models (Theory I)

Lecture Notes 1: Solow Growth Model

Organizing the Global Value Chain: Online Appendix

Price-Taking Monopolies in Small Open Economies

Heckscher Ohlin Model

IS TAX SHARING OPTIMAL? AN ANALYSIS IN A PRINCIPAL-AGENT FRAMEWORK

Endogenous Protection: Lobbying

CEMMAP Masterclass: Empirical Models of Comparative Advantage and the Gains from Trade 1 Lecture 1: Ricardian Models (I)

Upward Pricing Pressure formulations with logit demand and endogenous partial acquisitions

Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model

Stanford Economics 266: International Trade Lecture 8: Factor Proportions Theory (I)

Practice Questions Chapters 9 to 11

Fiscal policy and minimum wage for redistribution: an equivalence result. Abstract

E cient Minimum Wages

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 19: Trade and Labor Markets (Theory)

Advertising and entry deterrence: how the size of the market matters

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 13 of the text.

Fundamental Trade Theorems under External Economies of Scale

2 Maximizing pro ts when marginal costs are increasing

Physical Capital, Knowledge Capital and the Choice Between FDI and Outsourcing

Search, Welfare and the Hot Potato E ect of In ation

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

EconS Micro Theory I 1 Recitation #7 - Competitive Markets

A Theory of Outsourcing and Wage Decline

Lecture 5. Varian, Ch. 8; MWG, Chs. 3.E, 3.G, and 3.H. 1 Summary of Lectures 1, 2, and 3: Production theory and duality

Factor Endowments. Ricardian model insu cient for understanding objections to free trade.

Empirical Tests of Information Aggregation

Technology Differences and Capital Flows

Physical Capital, Knowledge Capital and the Choice Between FDI and Outsourcing

International Trade

Partial privatization as a source of trade gains

Bailouts, Time Inconsistency and Optimal Regulation

Mossin s Theorem for Upper-Limit Insurance Policies

Downstream R&D, raising rival s costs, and input price contracts: a comment on the role of spillovers

Gains from Trade and Comparative Advantage

Upward pricing pressure of mergers weakening vertical relationships

The E ciency Comparison of Taxes under Monopolistic Competition with Heterogenous Firms and Variable Markups

Global Sourcing. Pol Antràs. Harvard University and NBER. Elhanan Helpman. Harvard University, Tel Aviv University, and CIAR.

Human capital and the ambiguity of the Mankiw-Romer-Weil model

The Role of Physical Capital

Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with Endogenous Labor Supply * 1

Product Di erentiation. We have seen earlier how pure external IRS can lead to intra-industry trade.

Economics 2450A: Public Economics Section 1-2: Uncompensated and Compensated Elasticities; Static and Dynamic Labor Supply

Measuring the Wealth of Nations: Income, Welfare and Sustainability in Representative-Agent Economies

Demand-Enhancing Investment in Mixed Duopoly

Lectures on Trading with Information Competitive Noisy Rational Expectations Equilibrium (Grossman and Stiglitz AER (1980))

Investment is one of the most important and volatile components of macroeconomic activity. In the short-run, the relationship between uncertainty and

Lecture 2: The neo-classical model of international trade

Econ Review Set 3 - Answers

Working Paper Series. This paper can be downloaded without charge from:

Economics 689 Texas A&M University

Discussion Papers in Economics. No. 12/03. Nonlinear Income Tax Reforms. Alan Krause

Should small countries fear deindustrialization?

On social and market sanctions in deterring non compliance in pollution standards

Some Notes on Timing in Games

SOLUTION PROBLEM SET 3 LABOR ECONOMICS

Title: The Relative-Profit-Maximization Objective of Private Firms and Endogenous Timing in a Mixed Oligopoly

Pharmaceutical Patenting in Developing Countries and R&D

Conditional Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities and Financing Constraints

An Enhancement of Modern Free Trade Area Theory. Earl L. Grinols Peri Silva. October 2003

Auction Theory for Undergrads

Answer: Let y 2 denote rm 2 s output of food and L 2 denote rm 2 s labor input (so

Does Encourage Inward FDI Always Be a Dominant Strategy for Domestic Government? A Theoretical Analysis of Vertically Differentiated Industry

Using Executive Stock Options to Pay Top Management

On the Political Complementarity between Globalization. and Technology Adoption

Costs. Lecture 5. August Reading: Perlo Chapter 7 1 / 63

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES GLOBAL SUPPLY CHAINS AND WAGE INEQUALITY. Arnaud Costinot Jonathan Vogel Su Wang

Aggregation with a double non-convex labor supply decision: indivisible private- and public-sector hours

Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare

Kwok Tong Soo Lancaster University. Abstract

Lecture Notes 1

Emissions Trading in Forward and Spot Markets of Electricity

Bounding the bene ts of stochastic auditing: The case of risk-neutral agents w

Problem Set # Public Economics

Movie Industry: Protection and the Size of the Market. Eduardo C. Andrade

Pure Exporter: Theory and Evidence from China

Transcription:

A Simple Theory of Offshoring and Reshoring Angus C. Chu, Guido Cozzi, Yuichi Furukawa March 23 Discussion Paper no. 23-9 School of Economics and Political Science, Department of Economics University of St. Gallen

Editor: Publisher: Electronic Publication: Martina Flockerzi University of St. Gallen School of Economics and Political Science Department of Economics Bodanstrasse 8 CH-9 St. Gallen Phone +4 7 224 23 25 Fax +4 7 224 3 35 Email seps@unisg.ch School of Economics and Political Science Department of Economics University of St. Gallen Bodanstrasse 8 CH-9 St. Gallen Phone +4 7 224 23 25 Fax +4 7 224 3 35 http://www.seps.unisg.ch

A Simple Theory of Offshoring and Reshoring Angus C. Chu, Guido Cozzi, Yuichi Furukawa Author s address: Angus C. Chu Durham University Business School Durham University UK. School of Economics angusccc@gmail.com Prof. Guido Cozzi FGN-HSG Varnbüelstrasse 9 9 St. Gallen Phone +4 7 224 23 99 Fax +4 7 224 28 74 Email guido.cozzi@unisg.ch Website www.fgn.unisg.ch Yuichi Furukawa Chukyo University School of Economics Nagoya, Japan you.furukawa@gmail.com The authors are grateful to Elhanan Helpman for his helpful advice.

Abstract In this study, we predict a pattern of offshoring and reshoring over the course of economic development. We achieve this, by extending Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg s (28) model of offshoring in a simple way by assuming that offshoring requires both workers and capital in the offshored country. As a consequence, the accumulation of capital in the offshored country has two opposing effects on offshoring. On the one hand, it increases the wage rate of workers rendering offshoring less attractive. On the other hand, it decreases the rental price of capital rendering offshoring more attractive. Putting these two effects together, we analytically generate the inverted-u pattern of offshoring recently observed in China. Keywords Trade, offshoring, economic development. JEL Classification F, F6.

A growing number of American companies are moving their manufacturing back to the United States. The Economist (23) Introduction Since the mid 99 s, the amount of o shoring from developed countries to China has been steadily increasing; for example, Xing (22) nds that the volume of processing trade in China increased from about US$ billion in 994 to US$3 billion in 28. However, this increasing trend of o shoring in China has recently been reversed; for example, according to The Boston Consulting Group (2), [t]ransportation goods such as vehicles and auto parts, electrical equipment including household appliances, and furniture are among seven sectors that could create 2 to 3 million jobs as a result of manufacturing returning to the U.S. - an emerging trend that is expected to accelerate starting in the next ve years. In a subsequent survey, The Boston Consulting Group (22a) nds that [m]ore than a third of U.S.-based manufacturing executives at companies with sales greater than $ billion are planning to bring back production to the United States from China or are considering it. Porter and Rivkin (22) also nd that the rapidly rising wages abroad represent an important trend that is beginning to make US rms favor locating their production domestically. In this study, we show how a simple model of o shoring can explain this pattern of o shoring and reshoring. As a result of economic development, physical capital in China has been accumulating at a rapid rate; for example, according to Bai et al. (26), gross xed capital formation as a share of gross domestic product in China increased from 3% in 978 to 42% in 25. Furthermore, the wage rate of workers has also been rising rapidly; for example, The Boston Consulting Group (22b) nds that the 5 to 2 percent annual increases in Chinese wages [...] were rapidly eroding China s manufacturing cost advantage over the U.S.. At the rst glance, these two stylized facts seem to suggest that capital accumulation in China should lead to a gradual reduction in o shoring because of its positive e ect on wages, which renders o shoring less attractive. However, if one considers an often neglected fact that o shoring also requires the use of domestic capital in the o shored country (i.e., o shored production requires both workers and equipment in the o shored country), then capital accumulation in China would also have a positive e ect on o shoring. To generate the abovementioned e ects, it su ces to consider the seminal model of o shoring in Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (28). We extend the Grossman-Rossi-Hansberg model by allowing for the possibility that o shoring of labor-intensive tasks requires the use of both workers and capital (e.g., plants, equipment, information and telecommunication structures 2 ) in the o shored country. In this case, an increase in the capital stock in China has two opposing e ects on the incentives of o shoring. On the one hand, it increases the wage rate of workers rendering o shoring less attractive. On the other hand, it decreases the In the literature on o shoring, there is an important alternative strand of studies that focus on the choice of organizational form by rms; see the seminal studies by McLaren (2), Grossman and Helpman (22, 24, 25), Antras (23), Antras and Helpman (24) and Antras et al. (26). 2 Communication between the o shored country and the o shoring country is essential for the o shoring activity, which requires telephones, faxes, and computers, etc. 2

rental price of capital rendering o shoring more attractive; for example, according to Bai et al. (26), the rate of return to non-mining capital in China decreases from 3% in the mid 98 s to less than 2% in the early 2 s. Putting these two e ects together generates an inverted-u e ect of capital accumulation on the equilibrium level of o shoring, which is consistent with the recently observed inverted-u pattern of o shoring in China. However, our prediction does not apply only to the albeit very important Chinese case, but also to the generality of other o shored countries. 2 A simple model of o shoring and reshoring We consider the Grossman-Rossi-Hansberg model of o shoring. The model consists of two goods j 2 fx; yg, which are produced using labor and capital in the form of two varieties of tasks: L-tasks and K-tasks. The measure of each variety of tasks is normalized to one. Firms in the developed country produce both goods. In addition to employing local workers, they can also o shore some of the L-tasks to workers in the developing country. Here we di er from Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (28) by assuming that this o shoring process also requires the use of capital in the developing country in order to capture a simple fact that workers in China require local equipment to complete the o shored tasks. Therefore, both capital and labor in the developing country can either be used for domestic production or for o shoring production. We will refer to the developing country (for example, China) as the home country, which is assumed to be a small open economy for simplicity. In order for the e ects of factor supplies to work explicitly, as is well known in international trade theory, we need more factors than produced goods; therefore, we assume that the home country produces only one good, say good y. In this industry, a rm needs a fy units of domestic factor f 2 fl; Kg to perform a typical f-task. Due to substitutability between L-tasks and K-tasks, rms choose a Ly and a Ky to minimize their cost. Following Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (28), we assume that there is no substitution within the f-tasks, so that each task must be performed once to produce a unit of good y. If a foreign rm in industry j performs L-task i using local workers, it requires a Lj units of local labor. If the foreign rm performs L-task i through o shoring, it requires l j (i) = a Lj t(i) units of labor and k j(i) = l j (i) units of capital in the o shored country. Here > is a shift parameter that inversely captures technological improvement in o shoring and measures the extent to which each o shoring worker requires local capital (e.g., the equipment that each worker needs to perform the tasks). For convenience, we order the tasks by increasing di culty of o shoring (i.e., t (i) > for i 2 [; ]). Due to the assumption of the home country being a small open economy, all foreign variables denoted by superscript are given exogenously. Naturally, we focus on the equilibrium in which o shoring exists by assuming that a Lj w > a Lj t()(w + r) and a Lj w < a Ljt()(w + r). Therefore, there must exist a threshold value of i, denoted as I, such that w = t(i)(w + r). () The left-hand side of () is the wage cost for rms in the foreign country whereas the right-hand side is the o shoring costs of task I. In both industries j 2 fx; yg, for i I, 3

foreign L-tasks are o shored to the home country. For i > I; foreign L-tasks are performed domestically in the foreign country. In the home country, the unit cost for domestic rms in industry y is wa Ly +ra Ky. Perfect competition implies wa Ly + ra Ky = p y =, (2) where we normalize the world price of good y to p y =. The factor-market condition for labor in the home country is given by a Ly y + Z Z I t(i)di = L, where Z a Lx x + a Ly y captures the production scale in the foreign economy. In other words, labor in the home country is either used for domestic production a Ly y or o shoring production Z R I t(i)di for foreign rms. Similarly, the factor-market condition for capital in the home country is given by a Ky y + Z Z I t(i)di = K. In other words, capital in the home country is either used for domestic production a Ky y or o shoring production Z R I t(i)di for foreign rms.3 From cost minimization, we can derive a fy (w=r) as a function of w=r, where w is the wage rate of workers and r is the rental price of capital. Taking a fy (w=r) into account, the equilibrium conditions (), (2) and (3) determine fw; r; y; Ig. Using (3), we can express capital intensity in the home country as R I (3a) (3b) a Ky = K Z t(i)di a Ly L Z R. (4) I t(i)di Given that a Ky =a Ly is naturally an increasing function of w=r, 4 the ratio w=r can be expressed using (4) as w!(i; K). (5) r By (4), we may note two properties of the function!: (a)! is increasing (decreasing) in I if K > (<) L; and (b)! is increasing in K. We now solve (2) and (5) for r and w to obtain the expressions of w (!(I; K)) 5 and r(!(i; K)) 6, where w () > and r () <. 7 We substitute w (!(I; K)) and r(!(i; K)) into () to obtain w = t(i)[w (!(I; K)) + r (!(I; K))], (6) 3 To ensure a positive output of y, we assume L > Z R I t(i)di and K > R Z I t(i)di. 4 We will consider an explicit production function below. 5 Speci cally, w (!(I; K)) =!(I; K)=[!(I; K)a Ly (!(I; K)) + a Ky (!(I; K))]. 6 Speci cally, r(!(i; K)) = =[!(I; K)a Ly (!(I; K)) + a Ky (!(I; K))]. 7 In the appendix, we derive these comparative statics. 4

which determines the equilibrium level of o shoring I for a given K. The o shoring costs in the right-hand side of (6) may increase or decrease with!(i; K), and the following chart summarizes the intuition. K )!(I; K) ) r # ) o shoring cost # w ) o shoring cost ) I #. As K increases, the capital cost r decreases but the wage cost w increases. To understand how these e ects a ect o shoring, we consider a CES technology with the following unit i production function h (a Ky ) + ( ) (a Ly ) =, where > is the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. Cost minimization implies that the factor price ratio in (5) becomes!(i; K) = aky a Ly = K L Z R I t(i)di! Z R I t(i)di. (7) Finally, using (7) and the unit production function, we can express (6) as 8 8 9 >< w = t(i)! (I; K) + ( ) >= + h + ( ) (! (I; K) )i. (8) {z } >: {z } >; w(!(i;k)) r(!(i;k)) We rst consider the special case of = as in Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg (28). In this case, a larger stock of capital increases the wage rate of workers rendering o shoring less attractive; in other words, capital has a monotonically negative e ect on o shoring I, which is inconsistent with empirical observation. When >, the negative e ect of capital on the rental price r generates an additional positive e ect on o shoring. Putting these two e ects together generates an inverted-u relationship between o shoring and capital, which is consistent with the recently observed inverted-u pattern of o shoring in China. We summarize all these e ects in the following proposition. Proposition As capital K increases in the o shored country, the wage rate w increases and the rental price r of capital decreases. As for the equilibrium level of o shoring I, it rst increases and then decreases after K exceeds L. In other words, there is an inverted-u relationship between o shoring I and the capital stock K in the o shored country. Proof. Di erentiating the right-hand side of (8) with respect to I, we can show that it is monotonically increasing in I, noting (7). 9 Given that the left-hand side of (8) is constant, there uniquely exists an equilibrium level of I that is determined by the intersect of both sides. Di erentiating the right-hand side of (8) with respect to K, we can show that it is decreasing (increasing) in K when K < (>)L, noting (7). Then, simple graphical analysis would su ce to complete the proof. 8 In the appendix, we provide the derivations. 9 In the appendix, we provide the derivations. In the appendix, we provide the derivations. 5

3 Conclusion In this study, we rst documented a pattern of o shoring and reshoring in China. Then, we developed a simple framework to explain this stylized fact. In summary, we nd that economic development in o shored countries initially causes an increase in o shoring activities but eventually leads to a return of o shoring tasks to developed countries. Intuitively, capital accumulation as a result of economic development in o shored countries raises the wage rate of workers and reduces the rental price of capital giving rise to a U-shaped pattern in the cost of o shoring over the course of economic development, and these theoretical implications are consistent with the empirical trends in China. 6

References [] Antras, P., 23. Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 8, 375-48. [2] Antras, P., Garicano, L., and Rossi-Hansberg, E., 26. O shoring in a Knowledge Economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2, 3-77. [3] Antras, P., and Helpman, E., 24. Global Sourcing. Journal of Political Economy, 2, 552-58. [4] Bai, C., Hsieh, C., and Qian, Y., 26. The Return to Capital in China. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 37, 6-2. [5] Grossman, G., and Helpman, E., 22. Integration versus Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 7, 85-2. [6] Grossman, G., and Helpman, E., 24. Managerial Incentives and the International Organization of Production. Journal of International Economics, 63, 237-262. [7] Grossman, G., and Helpman, E., 25. Outsourcing in a Global Economy. Review of Economic Studies, 72, 35-59. [8] Grossman, G., and Rossi-Hansberg, E., 28. Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of O shoring. American Economic Review, 98, 978-997. [9] McLaren, J., 2. Globalization and Vertical Structure. American Economic Review, 9, 239-254. [] Porter, M., and Rivkin, J., 22. Choosing the United States. Harvard Business Review, 9, 8-9. [] The Boston Consulting Group, 2. Transportation Goods, Electrical Equipment, and Furniture Are Among Sectors Most Likely to Gain Jobs as US Manufacturing Returns. Press Releases, October 7, 2. [2] The Boston Consulting Group, 22a. More Than a Third of Large Manufacturers Are Considering Reshoring from China to the US. Press Releases, April 2, 22. [3] The Boston Consulting Group, 22b. Return of Manufacturing from China, Rising Exports Could Create Up to 3 Million Jobs in the US. Press Releases, March 22, 22. [4] The Economist, 23. Reshoring Manufacturing: Coming Home. January 9, 23. [5] Xing, Y., 22. Processing Trade, Exchange Rates and China s Bilateral Trade Balances. Journal of Asian Economics, 23, 54-547. 7

Appendix Comparative statics of r() and w(): Assume that the unit production function F (a Ky ; a Ly ) satis es the standard neoclassical properties: for each i = K; L; @F (a Ky ; a Ly ) =@a iy = F i (a Ky ; a Ly ) > ; @ 2 F (a Ky ; a Ly ) =@ (a iy ) 2 = F ii (a Ky ; a Ly ) < ; F (a Ky ; a Ly ) = F (a Ky ; a Ly ) for any > : First, given the homogeneity of degree in function F (a Ky ; a Ly ), we can have r = F (a Ky ; a Ly ) and w = F 2 (a Ky ; a Ly ), (A) noting p y = : We can easily verify from Euler s homogeneous function theorem that F i (a Ky ; a Ly ) is homogeneous of degree for each i; implying F (a Ky ; a Ly ) = F (a Ky =a Ly ; ) and F 2 (a Ky ; a Ly ) = F 2 (a Ky =a Ly ; ) : Given these two expressions, with F ii (a Ky ; a Ly ) < ; F (a Ky ; a Ly ) is a decreasing function in a Ky =a Ly : Since @ 2 F (a Ky ; a Ly ) = (@ (a Ky ) @ (a Ly )) = F 2 (a Ky ; a Ly ) > holds due to the neoclassical properties, F 2 (a Ky ; a Ly ) = F 2 (a Ky =a Ly ; ) is an increasing function in a Ky =a Ly : By the cost minimizing condition F 2 (a Ky ; a Ly ) =F (a Ky ; a Ly ) = w=r; we then verify a positive relationship between a Ky =a Ly and w=r: As a result, F (a Ky ; a Ly ) (F 2 (a Ky ; a Ly )) is a decreasing (increasing) function in w=r. Equation (A) ensures that r (w) increases (decreases) with w=r: Derivations of equation (8): The cost minimization condition gives rise to a Ky = a Ly w. r (A2) By (A) and (A2), r = + ( ) w r ( ) and w = w + ( ) r are calculated from the CES production function. Together with (6), these expressions would prove (8). Comparative statics of equation (8): w = t(i) B @! (I; K) + ( ) + + ( )! (I; K) ( ) {z } (I;K) C A. First, with (7), di erentiating (I; K) with respect to I yields where @(I; K) @I = + ( )! (I; K) ( ) 2 (I; K) L K (I; K) Z R I t(i)di! Z R I t(i)di d!(i; K) ; di 8

and d!(i; K) di = (!(I; K)) Z t(i) L K L Z R 2 : I t(i)di Note that both (I; K) and d!(i; K)=dI are strictly positive if and only if K > L. Thus, @(I; K)=@I > always holds. Given t (I) >, the right-hand side of (8) increases with I: Next, di erentiating with respect to K yields @ (I; K) @K =! (I; K) + ( ) 2! (I; K) 2 (I; K) d!(i; K) dk ; where, in the same way as above, (I; K) > if and only if K > L: Given that d!(i; K)=dK > always holds, we have shown that the right-hand side of (8) increases with K if K > L and decreases with K if K < L. 9