Discussion of Risks to Price Stability, The Zero Lower Bound, and Forward Guidance: A Real-Time Assessment

Similar documents
Monetary policy regime formalization: instrumental rules

Inflation Targeting and Optimal Monetary Policy. Michael Woodford Princeton University

Information Processing and Limited Liability

The science of monetary policy

Monetary Fiscal Policy Interactions under Implementable Monetary Policy Rules

Advanced Financial Economics Homework 2 Due on April 14th before class

ON INTEREST RATE POLICY AND EQUILIBRIUM STABILITY UNDER INCREASING RETURNS: A NOTE

Evaluating Policy Feedback Rules using the Joint Density Function of a Stochastic Model

Mean Variance Analysis and CAPM

Monetary Policy in a New Keyneisan Model Walsh Chapter 8 (cont)

1 The empirical relationship and its demise (?)

Monetary Policy in Pakistan: Confronting Fiscal Dominance and Imperfect Credibility

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Discussion. Benoît Carmichael

Lecture 23 The New Keynesian Model Labor Flows and Unemployment. Noah Williams

Money Market Uncertainty and Retail Interest Rate Fluctuations: A Cross-Country Comparison

Interest Rate Smoothing and Calvo-Type Interest Rate Rules: A Comment on Levine, McAdam, and Pearlman (2007)

Monetary Policy and Stock Market Boom-Bust Cycles by L. Christiano, C. Ilut, R. Motto, and M. Rostagno

Optimal Monetary Policy

TOPICS IN MACROECONOMICS: MODELLING INFORMATION, LEARNING AND EXPECTATIONS LECTURE NOTES. Lucas Island Model

Inflation Target Uncertainty and Monetary Policy

Optimal Interest-Rate Rules: I. General Theory

Risk shocks and monetary policy in the new normal

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE doi /mnsc ec

Exam #2 Review Questions (Answers) ECNS 303 October 31, 2011

Has the Inflation Process Changed?

1 Dynamic programming

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

Comment on: The zero-interest-rate bound and the role of the exchange rate for. monetary policy in Japan. Carl E. Walsh *

Advanced Topics in Monetary Economics II 1

Expected Utility And Risk Aversion

Linda Allen, Jacob Boudoukh and Anthony Saunders, Understanding Market, Credit and Operational Risk: The Value at Risk Approach

Homework 3: Asset Pricing

Andreas Wagener University of Vienna. Abstract

Assignment 5 The New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil

Endogenous employment and incomplete markets

Notes on Estimating the Closed Form of the Hybrid New Phillips Curve

On the Welfare and Distributional Implications of. Intermediation Costs

SDMR Finance (2) Olivier Brandouy. University of Paris 1, Panthéon-Sorbonne, IAE (Sorbonne Graduate Business School)

OPTIMAL TAYLOR RULES IN NEW KEYNESIAN MODELS *

Optimal Monetary Policy Rule under the Non-Negativity Constraint on Nominal Interest Rates

THE POLICY RULE MIX: A MACROECONOMIC POLICY EVALUATION. John B. Taylor Stanford University

Capital Constraints, Lending over the Cycle and the Precautionary Motive: A Quantitative Exploration

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Portfolio theory and risk management Homework set 2

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

What is Cyclical in Credit Cycles?

Liquidity, Asset Price, and Welfare

Discussion of The Role of Expectations in Inflation Dynamics

CHAPTER II LITERATURE STUDY

Asymmetric Information: Walrasian Equilibria, and Rational Expectations Equilibria

Monetary Policy Frameworks and the Effective Lower Bound on Interest Rates

Wind in balancing markets: the role of net demand

Taylor Rule and Macroeconomic Performance: The Case of Pakistan

Monetary Policy and Financial Stability Connections. James Clouse Division of Monetary Affairs Board of Governors

Monetary policy under uncertainty

Discussion of Limitations on the Effectiveness of Forward Guidance at the Zero Lower Bound

CPI Inflation Targeting and the UIP Puzzle: An Appraisal of Instrument and Target Rules

Effi cient monetary policy frontier for Iceland

Optimally Thresholded Realized Power Variations for Lévy Jump Diffusion Models

Stability in geometric & functional inequalities

Solving dynamic portfolio choice problems by recursing on optimized portfolio weights or on the value function?

Monetary policy, leaning and concern for financial stability

14.05 Lecture Notes. Endogenous Growth

EC3115 Monetary Economics

Estimating Canadian Monetary Policy Regimes

CHOICE THEORY, UTILITY FUNCTIONS AND RISK AVERSION

ECON 815. A Basic New Keynesian Model II

On Existence of Equilibria. Bayesian Allocation-Mechanisms

PORTFOLIO THEORY. Master in Finance INVESTMENTS. Szabolcs Sebestyén

Mean Reversion in Asset Returns and Time Non-Separable Preferences

Properties of the estimated five-factor model

Practice Problems 1: Moral Hazard

Oil and macroeconomic (in)stability

Noureddine Kouaissah, Sergio Ortobelli, Tomas Tichy University of Bergamo, Italy and VŠB-Technical University of Ostrava, Czech Republic

Risks to Price Stability, the Zero Lower Bound, and Forward Guidance: A Real-Time Assessment

Lecture 10: Performance measures

Martingale Pricing Theory in Discrete-Time and Discrete-Space Models

Estimated, Calibrated, and Optimal Interest Rate Rules

WHAT IT TAKES TO SOLVE THE U.S. GOVERNMENT DEFICIT PROBLEM

Equity correlations implied by index options: estimation and model uncertainty analysis

Online Appendix. Bankruptcy Law and Bank Financing

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * First draft: September 2000 This draft: July 2001

Internet Appendix to: Common Ownership, Competition, and Top Management Incentives

Disaster risk and its implications for asset pricing Online appendix

Economic policy. Monetary policy (part 2)

The Liquidity Effect in Bank-Based and Market-Based Financial Systems. Johann Scharler *) Working Paper No October 2007

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Applied Macro Finance

On the economic significance of stock return predictability: Evidence from macroeconomic state variables

The Risky Steady State and the Interest Rate Lower Bound

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Teaching Inflation Targeting: An Analysis for Intermediate Macro. Carl E. Walsh * September 2000

1 The Solow Growth Model

Asset Pricing in Production Economies

ECON FINANCIAL ECONOMICS

Was The New Deal Contractionary? Appendix C:Proofs of Propositions (not intended for publication)

Lecture 8: Introduction to asset pricing

Transcription:

Discussion of Risks to Price Stability, The Zero Lower Bound, and Forward Guidance: A Real-Time Assessment Ragna Alstadheim Norges Bank 1. Introduction The topic of Coenen and Warne (this issue) is of core importance to central bankers: the assessment of inflation risk. Their narrative of euro-area inflation risk from the end of 2008 through 2011 establishes a benchmark against which one may regard the monetary policy decisions made by the European Central Bank. The density forecasts for inflation are derived based on the NAWM s (New Area Wide Model s) interpretation of Consensus forecasts for endogenous variables in terms of the model s structural shocks at each point in time. The density forecasts are made by simulations based on these derived structural shocks and the estimated covariance matrix of the NAWM, while taking into account the effective lower bound on interest rates when drawing shocks and simulating the model. Referring to Kilian and Manganelli (2007), Coenen and Warne specify a particular loss function for the central banker and apply the Kilian-Manganelli concept of balance of risks (BR) when reporting the development of inflation risk through time. My main comment to the paper is that the BR concept might seem more useful as a tool for the design of policy than as a device to communicate inflation risk. Coenen and Warne s own assessment of appropriate forward guidance for monetary policy provides a nice example. But given this perspective, one might want to include more arguments than just inflation in the loss function. With only inflation in the loss function, I suggest a different interpretation of the loss function it could be seen as an expression of a concern for the nominal anchor. 55

56 International Journal of Central Banking June 2014 2. The Balance of Risks and Optimal Monetary Policy Kilian and Manganelli (2008) 1 show that the risk-management approach to monetary policy coincides with the more traditional loss-function approach (expected utility model) given the definitions of deflation risk (DR) and excessive inflation risk (EIR) that Coenen and Warne apply. Furthermore, the first-order and second-order stochastic dominance definitions (FOSD and SOSD) that Kilian and Manganelli (2003) establish 2 relating to the central banker s problem, and the associated proposition regarding preference rankings of inflation distributions, apply. 3 In particular, all distributions that can be ranked according to Kilian and Manganelli s (KM s) FOSD criterion will have the same ranking, regardless of the central bank s preferences (that is, for any α, β), given some critical value for inflation U for which dislike for inflation kicks in (π in KM s notation), and the critical value L (or π) for which dislike for low inflation or deflation kicks in. The FOSD criterion expresses that distributions that have both less mass below L and less mass above U that is, mass is more centered within the target range will be preferred. Furthermore, densities that can be ranked according to SOSD will imply the same preference ranking for any α, β such that the central banker is weakly risk averse (that is, for any α, β 1), given some range for inflation within which loss equals zero. The SOSD criterion expresses that distributions for which more of the mass in the tails are (at least weakly) closer to both L and U, respectively, are preferred. The BR measure is intended to summarize the central banker s attitude towards risk and the underlying density forecast in a simple number. It adds information, since FOSD and SOSD provide far-from-complete rankings of distributions. Given the FOSD and SOSD results, though, we know that different BR numbers, scaled up or down by different α s and β s, reflecting different calibrations 1 See definition 4 in Kilian and Manganelli (2008). See also section 2.2 in Kilian and Manganelli (2003). 2 The standard first-order and second-order stochastic dominance (FOSD and SOSD) results are not directly applicable, because unlike in the risky asset problem a higher mean and stronger skewness to the right is not always preferred. Rather, in the central banker s problem, utility is higher when the density is more centered around the target value or within the target interval. 3 See section 2.3 in Kilian and Manganelli (2003).

Vol. 10 No. 2 Discussion: Alstadheim 57 of the DR/EIR measures, may represent the same ranking of inflation distributions by the central banker. 4 Moreover, the same BR number may reflect different distributions of inflation, if the number is calculated using different α s and β s. Hence, in order to interpret the BR, it seems necessary to know either the central banker s preferences or the underlying density forecast. Or, like Coenen and Warne, one may solve this by highlighting the time-series properties of the balance of risks, rather than the absolute level. Information about the time path of the BR will indicate the degree to which the central bank implements optimal policy: In Kilian and Manganelli (2003), 5 it is shown that the first-order condition for the central bank s optimal policy problem is BR = 0, given the loss function that Coenen and Warne apply. This suggests that the BR measure may be more useful as a tool for the central banker when designing policy than it is for the public to draw conclusions about inflation risk in a more objective sense. In fact, the BR that Coenen and Warne apply is an example of Giannoni and Woodford (2012) s target criterion 6 : the target criterion is precisely the first-order condition for minimization of the central banker s loss function. Like Kilian and Manganelli (2008), Giannoni and Woodford (2012) highlight that a nice property of the target criterion is that it may give guidance to monetary policy that is robust to model misspecification. But for the BR to provide guidance for stabilization aspects of monetary policy, it would seem natural to include more arguments than just inflation in the loss function. 7 4 FOSD and SOSD do not offer complete rankings of distributions. Hart (2011) establishes two new stochastic orders, which provide complete rankings of distributions. These measures apply to risky assets, like traditional stochastic dominance does. An extension of those stochastic orders to the central banker s problem might be worth exploring in order to provide a more objective index measure of inflation and deflation risk. 5 See section 2.4. See also Kilian and Manganelli (2008). 6 See also Giannoni and Woodford (2003). 7 As shown by Kilian and Manganelli (2008), the risk-management approach may more generally be applied to the problem of choosing among feasible joint distributions of inflation and other goal variables, e.g., unemployment. The same is the case with the target criterion approach. The monetary policy decision problem then concerns the choice among those joint distributions, where the distributions are conditional on monetary policy. Determinacy has to be established when implementing policy with this approach, as discussed by Giannoni and Woodford (2012).

58 International Journal of Central Banking June 2014 3. The Loss Function with Only One Argument: A Concern about the Nominal Anchor The loss function that Coenen and Warne apply could be interpreted to express concern about the nominal anchor rather than a vehicle to assess optimal stabilization policy. A very simple model may serve as an illustration. Let the aggregate supply equation be and the demand equation be y t = a(π t E t 1 π t ) (1) y t = b(i t E t π t+1 )+u t. (2) Let monetary policy follow a rule, where the price level is pinned down when λ>1 8 : The solution to the model is 9 i t = λπ t + λ u u t + λ u 1 u t 1. (3) y t =[a(1 + bλ u + bλ u 1 /λ)/(a bλ)] u t, π t = [(1 + bλ u + bλ u 1 /λ)/(a bλ)] u t (λ u 1 /λ) u t 1. From equation (1), we know that inflation has to be predictable in order for output to be stabilized. From the solution for y t,wesee that a(1 + bλ u + bλ u 1 /λ)/(a bλ) = 0 is required. Output may be stabilized by using λ u,λ,or λ u 1 : Case 1. Stabilize using λ u. One may let monetary policy absorb the contemporaneous shock and thereby stabilize expected inflation in order to make it predictable; λ u = 1/b and λ u 1 =0. This creates a variable nominal interest rate that absorbs the shock in equilibrium: i t = 1/b u t and π t =0. 8 λ>1 pins down the initial inflation rate π 0. With π 0 = P 0 P 1, P 0 is pinned down when π 0 is determined. But for stabilization of output, it is inflation going into the next period that matters, π 1 = P 1 P 0. Therefore, one may close the output gap by stabilizing inflation without necessarily establishing determinacy at the same time. 9 The solution may be obtained by the method of undetermined coefficients.

Vol. 10 No. 2 Discussion: Alstadheim 59 Table 1. First and Second Moments of Inflation under Different Policies Stable Expected Inflation Rate Predictable, Policy Inflation (Cases 1 and 2) Nominal Rate Stable (Case 3) Nominal Anchor (λ >1) E(π) 0 0 E t (π t+1 ) 0 1/b u t σ(π) 0 (1/b) 2 σ u σ t (π t+1 ) 0 0 Indeterminate Initial Price Level (λ <1) E(π) N.A. N.A. E t (π t+1 ) 0 1/b u t σ(π) N.A. N.A. σ t (π t+1 ) 0 0 Case 2. Stabilize using λ. One may alternatively respond strongly and directly to inflation in order to stabilize it: let λ, while the other policy parameters are bounded but otherwise free to choose. This establishes the same equilibrium as above and, furthermore, provides a nominal anchor with λ>1. Case 3. Stabilize using λ u 1. Monetary authorities may make the inflation rate predictable by promising to respond to today s shock in the next period; λ u =0and λ u 1 /λ = 1/b. The inflation rate is now variable but predictable and absorbs the shock, while the nominal interest rate is stable in equilibrium: i t =(λ/b) u t 1 (λ/b) u t 1 = 0 and π t =1/b u t 1. The first and second moments for inflation under different policies summarized in table 1 illustrate that a stable conditionally expected inflation rate is neither necessary nor sufficient for a nominal anchor to be established. Hence, in the case where the nominal anchor is secured and the central bank stabilizes output, the inflation rate may be variable but bounded. In the case where the nominal anchor is not secured,

60 International Journal of Central Banking June 2014 the unconditional variance of inflation is unbounded because we do not know where the initial price level will be. The KM/Coenen and Warne loss function reflects exactly a concern about inflation variance beyond certain limits. 4. Concluding Remarks As KM and Coenen and Warne have stressed, one might want to provide more compact and accessible information about inflation and deflation risk than what is contained in density forecasts. But the BR concept describes deviations from optimal policy it is a target criterion. Therefore, a search for a more objective way of providing compact information about inflation risk, which is more decoupled from preferences perhaps inspired by Hart (2011), might be worthwhile. More objectives than just inflation in the loss function might seem natural when applying the BR concept as a guide to the design of stabilization policy. With inflation as the only argument, the loss function with tolerance for inflation variation within a range instead seems to describe a concern about the existence of bounded first and second moments for the inflation rate, or a nominal anchor. It might then be useful to use density forecasts from surveys or density forecasts extracted from market data instead of density forecasts from a model as arguments in the loss function. 10 Forecasts from models are well behaved and will by design not exhibit non-stationary behavior anyway. References Giannoni, M. P., and M. Woodford. 2003. Optimal Inflation Targeting Rules. NBER Working Paper No. 9939.. 2012. Optimal Target Criteria for Stabilization Policy. Staff Reports (Federal Reserve Bank of New York) 535 (January). Hart, S. 2011. Comparing Risks by Acceptance and Rejection. Journal of Political Economy 119 (4): 617 38. 10 See also www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp1540.pdf.

Vol. 10 No. 2 Discussion: Alstadheim 61 Kilian, L., and S. Manganelli. 2003. The Central Banker as a Risk Manager: Quantifying and Forecasting Inflation Risks. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3918.. 2007. Quantifying the Risk of Deflation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39 (2 3): 561 90.. 2008. The Central Banker as a Risk Manager: Estimating the Federal Reserve s Preferences under Greenspan. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40 (6): 1103 29.