slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks

Similar documents
Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom? Martin Uribe and Vivian Yue (JIE, 2006)

Global Financial Conditions, Country Spreads and Macroeconomic Fluctuations in Emerging Countries: A Panel VAR Approach

Country Spreads as Credit Constraints in Emerging Economy Business Cycles

Real Business Cycles in Emerging Countries?

Reserve Accumulation, Macroeconomic Stabilization and Sovereign Risk

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions. M. Canzoneri, F. Collard, H. Dellas and B. Diba

Uncertainty and Economic Activity: A Global Perspective

Unemployment Fluctuations and Nominal GDP Targeting

Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: A Neoclassical Perspective

Financial Econometrics Jeffrey R. Russell. Midterm 2014 Suggested Solutions. TA: B. B. Deng

How Important Are Terms of Trade Shocks?

Exchange Rates and Uncovered Interest Differentials: The Role of Permanent Monetary Shocks. Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Martín Uribe

Transitory and trend shocks to productivity.

US real interest rates and default risk in emerging economies

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES REAL BUSINESS CYCLES IN EMERGING COUNTRIES? Javier García-Cicco Roberto Pancrazi Martín Uribe

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Spring, 2009

Debt Financing and Real Output Growth: Is There a Threshold Effect?

Does One Law Fit All? Cross-Country Evidence on Okun s Law

What determines government spending multipliers?

5. STRUCTURAL VAR: APPLICATIONS

Country Risk, Exchange Rates and Economic Fluctuations in Emerging Economies

Open Economy Macroeconomics: Theory, methods and applications

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

Sovereign Debt Crises: Some Data and Some Theory

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy

Commodity Prices and Sovereign Default: A New Perspective on the Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect

Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Prices: The Role of Financial Frictions

Are Predictable Improvements in TFP Contractionary or Expansionary: Implications from Sectoral TFP? *

Online Appendix. Revisiting the Effect of Household Size on Consumption Over the Life-Cycle. Not intended for publication.

Asset pricing in the frequency domain: theory and empirics

Terms of Trade Shocks and Investment in Commodity-Exporting Economies 1

Comment. The New Keynesian Model and Excess Inflation Volatility

Private Leverage and Sovereign Default

Stock Price, Risk-free Rate and Learning

On the new Keynesian model

HOW IMPORTANT ARE TERMS-OF-TRADE SHOCKS? Columbia University, CEPR, and NBER, U.S.A.; Columbia University and NBER, U.S.A.

on Inequality Monetary Policy, Macroprudential Regulation and Inequality Zurich, 3-4 October 2016

Online Appendix for The Heterogeneous Responses of Consumption between Poor and Rich to Government Spending Shocks

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Fiscal Multipliers in Recessions

Resource Allocation within Firms and Financial Market Dislocation: Evidence from Diversified Conglomerates

ECO 2016/10 Department of Economics. Monetary News, U.S. Interest Rate and Business Cycles in Emerging Economies. Alejandro Vicondoa

Lecture 2. (1) Permanent Income Hypothesis. (2) Precautionary Savings. Erick Sager. September 21, 2015

Aggregate Implications of Lumpy Adjustment

DSGE Models and Central Bank Policy Making: A Critical Review

A Small Open Economy DSGE Model for an Oil Exporting Emerging Economy

Credit Frictions and Optimal Monetary Policy. Vasco Curdia (FRB New York) Michael Woodford (Columbia University)

Credit constraints, productivity shocks and consumption volatility in emerging economies

Adaptive Beliefs in RBC models

Taxes and the Fed: Theory and Evidence from Equities

Government Sector and the Government Spending Multipliers

International Business Cycle Transmissions and News Shocks

Financial intermediaries in an estimated DSGE model for the UK

MA Advanced Macroeconomics: 11. The Smets-Wouters Model

Capital Flows, House Prices, and the Macroeconomy. Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Market Economies

Emerging Economies Business Cycles: The Role of Commodity Terms of Trade News

Capital flows to Emerging Markets

Estimating and Accounting for the Output Gap with Large Bayesian Vector Autoregressions

The Role of Investment Wedges in the Carlstrom-Fuerst Economy and Business Cycle Accounting

Lecture 4. Extensions to the Open Economy. and. Emerging Market Crises

Frequency of Price Adjustment and Pass-through

Taxing Firms Facing Financial Frictions

Online Appendix: Asymmetric Effects of Exogenous Tax Changes

The Effects of Monetary Policy on Asset Price Bubbles: Some Evidence

2. Preceded (followed) by expansions (contractions) in domestic. 3. Capital, labor account for small fraction of output drop,

A Macroeconomic Model with Financial Panics

Volume 38, Issue 1. The dynamic effects of aggregate supply and demand shocks in the Mexican economy


Do Peer Firms Affect Corporate Financial Policy?

Idiosyncratic risk, insurance, and aggregate consumption dynamics: a likelihood perspective

Long-duration Bonds and Sovereign Defaults. June 3, 2009

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Equity Returns and Business Cycles in Small Open Economies

The source of real and nominal exchange rate fluctuations in Thailand: Real shock or nominal shock

Credit Spreads and the Macroeconomy

What Drives Commodity Price Booms and Busts?

The relation between bank losses & loan supply an analysis using panel data

Graduate Macro Theory II: The Basics of Financial Constraints

Equity Returns and Business Cycles in Small Open Economies

Gernot Müller (University of Bonn, CEPR, and Ifo)

Financial Intermediation, Consumption Dynamics, and Business Cycles

CEO Attributes, Compensation, and Firm Value: Evidence from a Structural Estimation. Internet Appendix

News Shocks and Asset Price Volatility in a DSGE Model

Precautionary Demand for Foreign Assets in Sudden Stop Economies: An Assessment of the New Mercantilism

Lorant Kaszab (MNB) Roman Horvath (IES)

Collateral Constraints and Multiplicity

STATE UNIVERSITY OF NEW YORK AT ALBANY Department of Economics. Ph. D. Comprehensive Examination: Macroeconomics Fall, 2010

Is the Affordable Care Act s Individual Mandate a Certified Job-Killer?

Financial Amplification, Regulation and Long-term Lending

Debt Covenants and the Macroeconomy: The Interest Coverage Channel

The Eurozone Debt Crisis: A New-Keynesian DSGE model with default risk

The Real Business Cycle Model

The Aggregate Implications of Regional Business Cycles

Notes on Macroeconomic Theory II

Growth Opportunities, Investment-Specific Technology Shocks and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy 1

Volatility Risk Pass-Through

Risk-Adjusted Capital Allocation and Misallocation

Transcription:

slides chapter 6 Interest Rate Shocks Princeton University Press, 217

Motivation Interest-rate shocks are generally believed to be a major source of fluctuations for emerging countries. The next slide displays country interest rates and output for 7 emerging economies between 1994:Q1 and 21:Q4. Why is there one interest rate per country, as opposed to just one world interest rate? One reasons is that each country has a different default risk, which is reflected in a country-specific interest-rate premium. The most commonly-used measure of country spreads is J.P. Morgan s EMBI+ bond index (Emerging Market Bond Index). The figure suggests that output and country interest rates are negatively correlated. Primary References: Neumeyer and Perri (JME, 25) and Uribe and Yue (JIE, 26). 2

Negative Comovement Between Interest Rates and Output Argentina Brazil Ecuador Mexico.2.2.5.2.2 1994 1998.2 22 1994 1998 Peru Philippines.2.2.5 1994 1998.2 22 1994 1998 22 South Africa.1.2 1994 1998 22.2.1 1994 1998 22 1994 1998 22 Output Country Interest Rate Correlations: Argentina -.67; Brazil -.51, Ecuador -.8, Mexico -.58, Peru -.37, The Philippines -.2, South Africa -.7. 3

Who Drives Whom? The observed negative correlation between output and the interest rate does not necessarily indicate that movements in the interest rate cause movements in output. Addressing this question requires a combination of data and theory. We will study two ways of combining data and theory: (1) SVAR analysis: here the emphasis is in the S. Converting a simple VAR into an SVAR requires the imposition of identifying assumptions, which are necessarily theoretical in nature. (2) Estimated DSGE model. The main difference between these two approaches is how much weight they place on data and theory. We begin with approach (1). 4

SVAR Analysis, Uribe and Yue (26) A ŷ t î t tby t ˆR t us ˆR t = B ŷ t 1 î t 1 tby t 1 ˆR t 1 us ˆR t 1 + ɛ y t ɛ i t ɛ tby t ɛ rus t ɛ r t, where y t =output, i t =investment, tby t =trade-balance-to-gdp ratio, R us t =U.S. interest rate, and R t=country interest rate. Identification Assumptions: A is lower triangular (A(i, j) = j > i). R US t follows a univariate process (A(4, j) = B(4, j) = j 4). Countries: Argentina, Brazil, Ecuador, Mexico, Peru, The Philippines, South Africa. Sample Period: 1994:Q1-21:Q4. 5

Comments On Identification A lower triangular implies that shocks to real variables (output, investment, and the trade balance) affect the country interest rate contemporaneously, but shocks to the U.S. interest rate or to the country interest rate affect real variables with a lag. This makes sense, because real variables (think about starting investment projects, hiring and firing decisions, etc.) should respond more slowly than financial variables. Assuming that Rt us is univariate is sensible because one should not expect individual emerging countries to affect interest rates in the U.S. Implications of Identifying Restrictions: ɛ rus t and ɛ r t can be interpreted as exogenous U.S.-interest-rate and country-spread shocks, respectively. The identification scheme is vague about the nature of ɛ y t, ɛi t, and. This is not a problem, because our interest is to understand the effects of interest-rate shocks. ɛ tby t 6

Impulse Response To A Country-Spread Shock, ɛ r t Output Investment Trade Balance to GDP Ratio % dev. from trend dev. from mean.1.2.3 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock U.S. Interest Rate 1.5.5 1 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock % dev. from trend dev. from mean.5 1 1.5 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Country Interest Rate 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock dev. from mean dev. from mean.4.3.2.1 1.5 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Country Spread 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Point Estimate 2-std. Error Band 7

Impulse Response To A U.S. Interest-Rate Shock, ɛ rus t dev. from mean % dev. from trend 1 1 Output 2 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock U.S. Interest Rate 1.5.5 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock % dev. from trend dev. from mean 5 5 Investment 1 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Country Interest Rate 4 2 2 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock dev. from mean dev. from mean Trade Balance to GDP Ratio 3 2 1 1 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Country Spread 4 2 2 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Point Estimate 2-std. Error Band 8

Observations on Responses to ɛ r t and ɛrus t Country-spread and US-interest-rate shocks cause sizable contractions in output and investment and a sizable improvement in the trade-balance-to-gdp ratio (i.e., domestic absorption contracts relatively more than output). The response to US-interest-rate shocks is estimated with significant uncertainty. One reason is that by design, Rt us does not vary across countries. US-interest-rate shocks cause a large, delayed overshooting of country spreads. 9

Impulse Response To An Output Shock, ɛ y t % dev. from trend dev. from mean 1.5 Output.5 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock U.S. Interest Rate 1.5.5 1 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock dev. from mean % dev. from trend 4 2 Investment 2 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Country Interest Rate.5.5 1 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock dev. from mean dev. from mean Trade Balance to GDP Ratio.2.2.4.6 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Country Spread.5.5 1 4 8 12 16 quarters after shock Point Estimate 2-std. Error Band 1

Observations on Response to ɛ y t An output shock causes expansions in output and investment, and a deterioration of the trade-balance-to-gdp ratio, resembling a technology shock or a terms-of-trade shock in the SOE-RBC model. More importantly for the purpose of the present analysis, the output shock drives down the country spread, thus lowering the country s cost of borrowing. Recall that the present identification scheme is vague with respect to the precise nature of ɛ y t. It could represent a mix of shocks of diverse natures, such as technology shocks, terms-of-trade shocks, etc. 11

Robustness To Expanding The Temporal And Country Coverage of the Data Expanded Time Span: 1994:Q1 to 212:Q4. Expanded Country Set: Argentina, Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Hungary, South Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Peru, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey, and Uruguay. 12

Responses to Country-Spread and U.S.-Interest-Rate Shocks: Expanded Data Output.5 Investment %.1.2.3.4.5.6.7 1 2 3 quarters after the shock %.5 1 1.5 2 1 2 3 quarters after the shock.2 Trade Balance to GDP Ratio 1 Country Interest Rate.15.8.1.6 % %.5.4.2.5 1 2 3 quarters after the shock 1 2 3 quarters after the shock 1% increase in country-spread (solid) and US-int.-rate (broken). Output and investment in % dev. from trend; TB/GDP and country int. rate in percentage point dev. from mean. 13

Responses to an Output Shock: Expanded Data Output Investment 1 3 %.95.9.85.8.75 1 2 3 quarters after the shock % 2.8 2.6 2.4 2.2 2 1.8 1 2 3 quarters after the shock.1 Trade Balance GDP Ratio.21 Country Interest Rate.15.22 %.2.25 %.23.24.25.3 1 2 3 quarters after the shock.26 1 2 3 quarters after the shock 1% output shock. Output and investment in % dev. from trend; TB/GDP and country int. rate in percentage point dev. from mean. 14

Observations on Robustness Analysis The preceding two figures show that the baseline empirical results are robust to extending the temporal and cross-sectional dimensions of the panel, especially along the following dimensions: Increases in the U.S.-interest-rate and country-spread cause contractions in output and investment. Increases in the U.S.-interest-rate and country-spread cause an improvement in the trade-balance-to-gdp ratio (or, equivalently, a proportionally larger contraction in domestic absorption than in output). U.S.-interest-rate shocks cause a delayed increase in country spreads. Output shocks cause an expansion in investment, a deterioration of the trade-balance-to-gdp ratio, and, more importantly, a fall in country spreads. 15

Decomposition of Forecast-Error Variances Let x t [ŷ t ît tby t R us t R t ]. Then the SVAR can be written as Ax t+h = Bx t+h 1 + ɛ t+h And its MA( ) representation is x t+h = j= The forecast of x t+h in t is C j ɛ t+h j, with C j ( A 1 B ) j A 1 E t x t+h = j=h C j ɛ t+h j And the associated forecast error, denoted FE h t, is FEt h h 1 = j= C j ɛ t+h j 16

Then the forecast-error variance at horizon h, denoted FEV h, is FEV h = h 1 j= C j Σ ɛ C j, where Σ ɛ E[ɛ t ɛ t ] The forecast-error variance attributable to shock i (the i-th element of ɛ t ), denoted FEV h,i, is FEV h,i = h 1 j= (C j Λ i )Σ ɛ (C j Λ i ), where Λ i is a square conformable matrix with all zeros except for diagonal element (i, i) which equals unity. 17

The share of forecast-error variance of variable k (i.e. k-th element of x t ) at horizon h attributable to shock i, denoted SFEV h,i k, is given by SFEV h,i k = h,i FEVkk FEVkk h, where kk denotes the k-th diagonal element. This is called a forecasterror variance decomposition. As the horizon become large, h, the forecast-error variance of variable k due to shock i converges to the unconditional variance of k due to i. The next slide presents the forecast-error variance decomposition implied by the estimated SVAR system. 18

Estimated Forecast-Error Variance Decomposition percent 3 2 1 Output percent 4 3 2 1 Investment percent Trade Balances to GDP Ratio 6 4 2 1 4 8 12 16 2 24 horizon (quarters) U.S. Interest Rate 1 1 4 8 12 16 2 24 horizon (quarters) Country Interest Rate 1 1 4 8 12 16 2 24 horizon (quarters) Country Spread 1 percent 5 percent 5 percent 5 1 4 8 12 16 2 24 horizon (quarters) 1 4 8 12 16 2 24 horizon (quarters) ɛ rus t ɛ rus t + ɛ r t 1 4 8 12 16 2 24 horizon (quarters) 19

Observations on the Forecast-Error Variance Decompositions Jointly, country-spread and US-interest-rate shocks (ɛ r t explain and ɛrus t ) 3% of movements in output. 32% of movements in investment. 44% of movements in the trade-balance-to-gdp ratio. 85% of movements in country-spreads. About 6% of movements in country spreads is explained by country-spread shocks. 2

Alternative Identification Scheme: Why Not Place the Country Spread First in the SVAR System? SVAR Prediction Under This Specification: Output and investment expand in response to an increase in the U.S. interest rate. Problematic: It s difficult to rationalize this implication on theoretical grounds. 21

DSGE Analysis Motivation The SVAR analysis is based on loose theoretical restrictions. Does the propagation mechanism of interest rate shocks (ɛ rus t and ɛ r t ) implied by the estimated SVAR model concur with the one implied by an optimizing DSGE open economy model? If so, the identified interest-rate shocks would be more compelling since the effects they generate would be consistent with the optimizing behavior of households and firms. Strategy: (1) Build a DSGE model of the open economy. (2) Feed the model with the estimated processes for Rt us and R t (the last 2 equations of the SVAR). (3) Compare the impulse responses predicted by the SVAR and DSGE models. 22

The Theoretical Model (Uribe and Yue, 26) Open economy model with three frictions: Working-capital constraint on firms Gestation lags and convex adjustment costs in investment Habit formation 23

Firms and Working Capital Constraints [ max F(k t, h t ) u t k t w t h t 1 + η(rd t 1) ] Rt d where F(, ) is a production function, h t =labor, k t =capital, w t =wage rate, and Rt d =gross interest rate. The parameter η governs the strength of the working-capital constraint. The implied demand for labor is ( )] R d F h (k t, h t ) = w t [1 + η t 1 The working-capital constraint is a financial friction that allows for a supply-side effect of interest rate shocks. An increase in the interest rate increases the (financial) cost of labor, inducing a contraction in labor demand. R d t 24

Capital Accumulation: Gestation Lags and Convex Adjustment Costs i t = 1 4 3 i= s it. s i+1t+1 = s it, i =,1,2 ( ) s3t k t+1 = (1 δ)k t + k t Φ k t where i t =investment, s it =number of investment projects started in period t i, for i =,1,2,3 (4-period gestation lag); k t =capital stock. Function Φ( ) captures convex adjustment costs (note that Φ( ) must be concave). 25

Households and Habit Formation subject to max E t= β t U(c t µ c t 1, h t ), d t = R t 1 d t 1 w t h t u t k t + c t + i t + Ψ(d t ) lim j E t d t+j+1 j s= R t+s The function Ψ(d t ) is convex; it introduces portfolio adjustment costs and gives rise to an effective interest rate, R d t, satisfying R d t = R t 1 Ψ (d t ). 26

Driving Forces ˆR t =.63ˆR t 1 +.5ˆR t us +.35ˆR t 1 us.79ŷ t +.61ŷ t 1 +.11î t.12î t 1 +.29tby t.19tby t 1 + ɛ r t, ˆR us t =.83ˆR us t 1 + ɛrus t, where ɛ r t and ɛrus t are mean-zero, iid, innovations with standard deviations equal to.31 and.7, respectively. 27

Functional Forms U(c µ c, h) = [ c µ c ω 1 h ω] 1 γ 1 1 γ F(k, h) = k α h 1 α Φ(x) = x φ 2 (x δ)2 ; φ > Ψ(d) = ψ 2 (d d) 2 28

Calibrated Parameters (Quarterly) ω = 1.45 γ = 2 α =.32 R = β 1 = 1.277 δ =.25 tb y =.2 29

Estimating φ, ψ, η, and µ Criterion: Minimize the distance between empirical and theoretical impulse response functions. Formally, φ, ψ, η, and µ are set so as to minimize [IR e IR m (ψ, φ, η, µ)] Σ 1 IR e [IR e IR m (ψ, φ, η, µ)], Result of estimation: ψ =.42 φ = 72.8 η = 1.2 µ =.2 3

.1.2 Theoretical and Estimated Impulse Response Functions IR of Output to ε rus.5 1 1.5 1 2 IR of Output to ε r.3 1 2.5 1 IR of Investment to ε rus 2 4 6 1 2 IR of Investment to ε r 1 2.4.2 IR of TB/GDP to ε rus 2 1 1 2 IR of TB/GDP to ε r 1 2 Empirical IR Error Band -x-x Theoretical IR IR of Country Int. Rate to ε rus 3 2 1 IR of Country Int. Rate to ε r 1.5 1 2 1 2 31

Observations on the Theoretical Impulse Responses The theoretical model replicates well a number of key features of the estimated IRFs: Output and investment contract in response to an increase in ɛ rus t or ɛ r t. The trade balance improves in response to an increase in ɛ rus t or ɛ r t. The country interest rate, R t, displays a hump-shaped response to an increase in ɛ rus t. These findings suggest that the identification assumptions imposed in the SVAR analysis are successful in isolating U.S.-interest-rate and country-spread shocks.

Conditional Standard Deviations Implied by the SVAR and Theoretical Models ɛ rus t ɛ r t Unconditional Variable SVAR Theory SVAR Theory SVAR ŷ 1.5 1.6 1.3 1.3 3.7 î 6.4 3.6 5. 2. 14.2 tby 2.1 1.6 2..9 4.4 R us 1.3 1.3 1.3 R 3.8 3.5 4.7 4.4 6.5 32

Observations on Conditional Volatilities SOE model does well at capturing the importance of U.S.-interestrate and country-spread shocks in explaining movements in output and country interest rates. The SOE model does a good job at accounting for variations in the trade balance due to U.S.-interest-rate shocks. But the SOE model underpredicts the volatilities of investment and the trade balance caused by country-spread shocks. SOE model implies that ɛ rus t and ɛ r t jointly explain 32 percent of fluctuations in output ((1.6311 2 + 1.2779 2 )/3.6583 2 =.32), almost same as SVAR ((1.5274 2 + 1.33 2 )/3.6583 2 =.3). But SOE model assigns less importance to ɛ rus t and ɛ r t in accounting for variations in i t and tby t than does the SVAR. Overall, identified ɛ rus t and ɛ r t shocks are sensible and economically important. 33

Shocks to Global Risk Premia What is the effect of movements in global risk premia on real and financial variables in emerging economies? Akinci (213) expands the SVAR studied above to include the spread between the U.S. Baa corporate bond rate and the 2-year U.S. Treasury bond yield. Baa corporate bonds carry a medium degree of default risk: 13% cumulative default risk over 2 years, compared with less than 1% for Aaa rated bonds (highest rating by Moody s) and more than 7% for C rated bonds (lowest rating). 34

The Augmented SVAR A ŷ t î t tby t R t us Ŝt us R t = B(L) ŷ t 1 î t 1 tby t 1 R t 1 us Ŝt 1 us R t 1 + ɛ y t ɛ i t ɛ tby t ɛ rus t ɛ sus t ɛ r t, St us = U.S. corporate bond spread. Identification: same as Uribe and Yue (26). Pair [Rt us St us ] follows bivariate process. ɛ sus can be interpreted as an innovation to the U.S. risk premium. t Same interpretation as before for other innovations. Countries: Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, Peru, South Africa, Turkey. Sample: 1994:Q1 to 211:Q3. 35

Predictions of SVAR with Global Risk Premium Shocks Interest rate shocks, i.e., [ɛ rus t ɛ sus t ɛ r t ], jointly explain 42% of the variance of output reinforces the result obtained by Uribe and Yue (26). The global risk-premium shock takes over the role previously played by the U.S. interest rate: ɛ sus t explains 18% of the variance of output whereas ɛ rus t explains only 6%. The country spread shock, ɛ r t, continues to be an important driver of aggregate fluctuations in emerging countries, accounting for 18% of the observed variance of output. Effects of global risk-premium shocks is mediated by the country premium: a 1 percentage point increase in ɛ sus t raises the country premium by 1.3 percentage points. 36

Chapter Summary Interest-rate shocks represent an important driver of business cycles in emerging countries, accounting for 3 to 42 percent of the variance of output. Of the 3 to 42 percent of output variance explained by interest rate shocks, half is due to a global component (U.S.-interest-rate shocks and U.S.-risk-premium shocks) and the other half is due to country-specific spread shocks. In response to an increase in the interest rate, output and investment contract and the trade balance improves. An increase in the U.S. interest rate or in the U.S. risk premium produces an overshooting in country spreads, that is, the country spread increases by more than one for one. The majority of movements in country spreads (more than 6 percent) is explained by country spread shocks. 37