Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Foreca. Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors

Similar documents
Optimal Window Selection for Forecasting in The Presence of Recent Structural Breaks

Week 7 Quantitative Analysis of Financial Markets Simulation Methods

Introduction Dickey-Fuller Test Option Pricing Bootstrapping. Simulation Methods. Chapter 13 of Chris Brook s Book.

Chapter 6 Forecasting Volatility using Stochastic Volatility Model

Monetary Economics Final Exam

Understanding the Sources of Macroeconomic Uncertainty

Predictive Regressions: A Present-Value Approach (van Binsbe. (van Binsbergen and Koijen, 2009)

Aggregate Earnings Surprises, & Behavioral Finance

D.1 Sufficient conditions for the modified FV model

The Variability of IPO Initial Returns

Information Processing and Limited Liability

Ambiguous Information and Trading Volume in stock market

Interval estimation. September 29, Outline Basic ideas Sampling variation and CLT Interval estimation using X More general problems

ARCH and GARCH models

Chapter 7 - Lecture 1 General concepts and criteria

Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles

Understanding Tail Risk 1

An analysis of momentum and contrarian strategies using an optimal orthogonal portfolio approach

Can Rare Events Explain the Equity Premium Puzzle?

Estimating a Dynamic Oligopolistic Game with Serially Correlated Unobserved Production Costs. SS223B-Empirical IO

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns

Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis. () Chapter 5 Univariate time-series analysis 1 / 29

Behavioral Theories of the Business Cycle

News Shocks and Asset Price Volatility in a DSGE Model

Feedback Effect and Capital Structure

Unpublished Appendices to Market Reactions to Tangible and Intangible Information. Market Reactions to Different Types of Information

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns

Appendix to: AMoreElaborateModel

Consistent estimators for multilevel generalised linear models using an iterated bootstrap

What Can Rational Investors Do About Excessive Volatility and Sentiment Fluctuations?

Stochastic Volatility (SV) Models

Microeconomic Foundations of Incomplete Price Adjustment

BIASES OVER BIASED INFORMATION STRUCTURES:

Chapter 8. Introduction to Statistical Inference

Chapter 9, section 3 from the 3rd edition: Policy Coordination

1 Volatility Definition and Estimation

Supplementary online material to Information tradeoffs in dynamic financial markets

LECTURE NOTES 10 ARIEL M. VIALE

Financial Economics Field Exam August 2011

Lecture 22. Survey Sampling: an Overview

Signal or noise? Uncertainty and learning whether other traders are informed

trading ambiguity: a tale of two heterogeneities

Identifying Long-Run Risks: A Bayesian Mixed-Frequency Approach

Asset Pricing with Left-Skewed Long-Run Risk in. Durable Consumption

Exploring Financial Instability Through Agent-based Modeling Part 2: Time Series, Adaptation, and Survival

ARIMA-GARCH and unobserved component models with. GARCH disturbances: Are their prediction intervals. different?

Keynesian Views On The Fiscal Multiplier

Bailouts, Bail-ins and Banking Crises

Module 4: Point Estimation Statistics (OA3102)

Optimal Financial Education. Avanidhar Subrahmanyam

Equilibrium Yield Curve, Phillips Correlation, and Monetary Policy

Risk and Ambiguity in Asset Returns

An Empirical Examination of the Electric Utilities Industry. December 19, Regulatory Induced Risk Aversion in. Contracting Behavior

FE670 Algorithmic Trading Strategies. Stevens Institute of Technology

Estimating Macroeconomic Models of Financial Crises: An Endogenous Regime-Switching Approach

FE570 Financial Markets and Trading. Stevens Institute of Technology

Advanced Topics in Monetary Economics II 1

Chapter 6: Point Estimation

Financial Econometrics

Problem set 1 Answers: 0 ( )= [ 0 ( +1 )] = [ ( +1 )]

Earnings Inequality and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Brazil

Comparison of OLS and LAD regression techniques for estimating beta

Fresh Momentum. Engin Kose. Washington University in St. Louis. First version: October 2009

Improving Returns-Based Style Analysis

Labor Economics Field Exam Spring 2011

Financial Time Series and Their Characteristics

The Consistency between Analysts Earnings Forecast Errors and Recommendations

Explaining the Last Consumption Boom-Bust Cycle in Ireland

Alternative VaR Models

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns

Lecture 5a: ARCH Models

Much of what appears here comes from ideas presented in the book:

The Great Moderation Flattens Fat Tails: Disappearing Leptokurtosis

Asymmetric Price Transmission: A Copula Approach

STAT 509: Statistics for Engineers Dr. Dewei Wang. Copyright 2014 John Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Generalized Dynamic Factor Models and Volatilities: Recovering the Market Volatility Shocks

Dividend Dynamics, Learning, and Expected Stock Index Returns

A Two-Step Estimator for Missing Values in Probit Model Covariates

Tests for One Variance

Toward A Term Structure of Macroeconomic Risk

Do Peer Firms Affect Corporate Financial Policy?

Control Chart for Autocorrelated Processes with Heavy Tailed Distributions

Optimal Portfolio Inputs: Various Methods

Multitask, Accountability, and Institutional Design

Asymmetric Information and the Impact on Interest Rates. Evidence from Forecast Data

The Estimation of Expected Stock Returns on the Basis of Analysts' Forecasts

Weight Smoothing with Laplace Prior and Its Application in GLM Model

ANOMALIES AND NEWS JOEY ENGELBERG (UCSD) R. DAVID MCLEAN (GEORGETOWN) JEFFREY PONTIFF (BOSTON COLLEGE)

Predictability of Interest Rates and Interest-Rate Portfolios

Credit Shocks and the U.S. Business Cycle. Is This Time Different? Raju Huidrom University of Virginia. Midwest Macro Conference

The Kalman filter - and other methods

The Kalman filter - and other methods

The Predictability Characteristics and Profitability of Price Momentum Strategies: A New Approach

Chapter 5. Statistical inference for Parametric Models

Applied Statistics I

Correlation Ambiguity

Ambiguity Aversion: Implications for the Uncovered Interest Rate Parity Puzzle

PARAMETRIC AND NON-PARAMETRIC BOOTSTRAP: A SIMULATION STUDY FOR A LINEAR REGRESSION WITH RESIDUALS FROM A MIXTURE OF LAPLACE DISTRIBUTIONS

Financial Economics Field Exam January 2008

Exercises on the New-Keynesian Model

Transcription:

Reading the Tea Leaves: Model Uncertainty, Robust Forecasts, and the Autocorrelation of Analysts Forecast Errors December 1, 2016

Table of Contents Introduction Autocorrelation Puzzle Hansen-Sargent Autocorrelation Decomposition

Autocorrelation Puzzle For a one-period forecast, if analysts know the process and seek to minimize mean squared-error, forcast errors will have mean zero and be serially uncorrelated. Empirical evidence that forecaster errors tend to be positive and auto-correlated. This would imply that analysts do not learn from past mistakes. Why?

Motivating Example Parameter uncertainty: x t = (a + u t )x t 1 + ε t where u t N(0,σ 2 ) The error dissipates as analysts learn. Model (Knightian) uncertainty: Analyst does not know the underlying model. They have an approximating model.

In a robust forecast, analysts overestimate Authors find that variation in mean forecast errors contributes to one-fifth of the measured autocorrelation Estimation errors of earnings growth shocks contributes another one-fifth of the measured autocorrelation Finally, model uncertainty contributes to 60% of the measured autocorrelation.

Why is this Important? Contributes to the literature on analyst behavior and asset pricing anomalies. Important regarding the question of efficient distribution of information and welfare.

Relation to other literature Other literature Uppal and Wang (2003), Maenhout (2004), and Epstein and Schneider (2008) suggest that model uncertainty is of first-order importance for portfolio choice and asset pricing. Hilary and Hsu (2013) find analyst consistency rather than accuracy determines their ranking.

Earning and Signals Processes Earnings Process y t+1 = µ + x t+1 + a t+1 where y t+1 is the reported earnings, x t+1 is the persistent (permanent) component of the earnings process and a t+1 is noise. Signal Process (Private Signal) s t = e t+1 + n t where e t+1 is the permanent earnings shock and n t N(0,σ 2 n ). All shocks have zero cross-correlations, autocorrelations and cross-autocorrelations.

Earning and Signals Processes The analyst s objective in period t is estimate y t+1 given the history of earnings and signals E[y t+1 s t,s t 1,...,s 1,y t,y t 1,...,y 1 ] = E[y t+1 F t ] This is the linear part of the model

The Uncertainty Environment a w t = κ 0 + κ 1 a t where a w is the worse case realization and a is the analyst s approximating model Analysts do not know the distribution but we assume they approximate this noise as a t i.i.d.n(0, ˆσ 2 a ). The author s assume the approximated variance, ˆσ 2 a, is equal to the real variance σ 2 a in order to ensure the approximating model is good. The actual realization is at w N(κ 0,κ1 2σ a 2 ), where κ 0 is a real number and κ 1 is a non-negative number. The realization is a function of a random draw from this distribution.

The Problem subject to min max E[{y t w ŷ t t 1 F t 1 ] ŷ t t 1 (κ 0, κ 1 ) E[{(at w at ) + (ˆx }{{} t t 1 w ˆx t t 1) } 2 F t 1 ] η 2 σa 2 }{{} Deviation Perceived Bias where y w is the worst ex ante outcome; ŷ t t 1 is the analyst s optimal forecast given information hitherto; ˆx t t 1 w is the optimal forecast of x t (using a Kalman filter) under the worst case; and ˆx t t 1 is the optimal forecast forecast of x t given the analyst s expectations of the evil agent s choice of κ 0 and κ 1. Finally, at w the worse case realization of a t, whereas a is the approximating estimate. is

Direct and Indirect Effects (a w t a ) is the direct effect. This expresses the amount of distortion induced by the evil agent. (ˆx w t t 1 ˆx t t 1) is the indirect effect from the analysts relying on inaccurate historical information in their future estimations. η measures the agent s concern for model misspecification and σ 2 a the variance of the noise induced by the evil agent. Thus, ησ 2 a is the degree of robustness in the model. As η, the entropy becomes so great that it becomes impossible for the analyst to distinguish models. When η = 0, we have a standard Rational Expectations model.

Minimax Optimization The analyst solves a static optimization problem: the forecasts are independent from her last forecasts and the same solution applies at every date t. The analyst knows the parameters of the true earnings process completely determine her current estimate (ŷ t t 1 ). In other words, after choosing (ˆκ 0, ˆκ 1 ), their estimate of the evil agent s noise process, the analyst obtains an optimal forecast using a Kalman filter.

Intuition behind Lemma 2.1 The forecast is a function of the previous forecast ŷ t, the forecast error (y t ŷ t ) and the additional signal s t. The Kalman gain K captures how much the analyst uses previous forecast errors to revise estimates of x t The weight w measures how much the analyst uses the extra-signal s t to estimate e t+1, the permanent growth shock.

Intuition behind Prop. 2 If ˆθ = θ- that is the analyst predicts the true values of the model - autocorrelation of forecast errors goes to zero. With robust forecasting, analyst knows everything but the distribution of the noise a t. The first term goes to zero but the second two terms are strictly positive.

Intuition behind Analysts concerned about model misspecification will issue forecasts that perform well under the worst cast (highest variance). The analyst will overestimate the amount of noise in reported earnings (y t ) in order to achieve better accuracy than expected. Why? The noisier the reported earnings, the less accurate the analyst s forecast will be. The analyst s inference of x t will be farther away, on average, from the actual state. The analyst underreacts to historical earnings. As a result, we find positive autocorrelation in forecast errors.

Robustness in asset pricing versus forecasting In asset pricing literature, it is the investor s preferences, the structure of their utility function, which determine the worst-case scenario. In the forecasting problem, the decision maker has a preference for accuracy.

Parameter vs Model uncertainty Collin-Dufresne, Johannes, and Lochstoer (2013, 2015) show that if investors have recursive preferences, rational parameter learning generates subjective, long-run risks. Why? The investors can learn or know the true model. They face parameter uncertainty. The shocks are therefore permanent and affect all future periods of consumption With a robust decision maker, the analyst accepts model misspecification as a permanent state of affairs. They focus on robust controls.

Data Sources Combine data from I/B/E/S, Compustat and the the Center for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP). Use data from January 1984 to December 2013. Match firms against Compustat and CRSP: firms must be listed on NYSE, Nasdaq or AMEX. Sample Selection rules (to control for outliers): Delete observations with beginning of the quarter stock price below $5. Delete observations where the forecasted year-to-year change in quarterly earnings per share is greater than $10 in absolute value Trim extreme values (1% and 99%) for earnings, forecasts and forecast errors. Require a firm to have at least 20 observations of actual earnings and forecasts.

Descriptive Statistics

AR(1)-plus-noise FE i,t+1 = α + ρfe i,t + ε i,t+1 The pooled estimate of the autocorrelation in forecast errors, 0.216, is significant with a heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent t-value of 28.87.

A Joint Model of earnings and forecasts This whole system described above can be estimated as a VARMA(1,1): Y t+1 = A + BY t = Cε t+1 + Dε t where [ ] a t σ 2 a 0 0 yt Y t =, ε ŷ t = e t, cov(ε t ) = 0 σa 2 0 t n t 1 0 0 σ [ ] [ ] a 2 µ(1 φ) φ 0 A =, B = ˆµ(1 φ) ˆφ ˆK ˆφ(1 ˆK) where µ is the long-term mean of y t. C = [ 1 1 0 0 ŵ ŵ ], D = [ φ 0 ] 0 0 0 0

Estimation Procedure 1 Estimate the parameters of the AR-plus-noise using maximum likelihood. 2 Holding the parameter values fixed, estimate the rest of the VARMA model using conditional maximum likelihood. 1 Use a block bootstrapping procedure, resampling at the firm level to preserve time series properties. 1 Why block bootstrap? The errors are correlated, so simple residual resampling will fail. Rather, resample blocks of data.

Table 2

Reliance on historical data Pseudo-R 2 of analyst forecasts = 1 var(y t+1 ŷ t+1 ) var(y t+1 ) If analysts use only historical data, the precision of their forecasts should be comparable to the R 2 of the ARMA(1,1). Using the pseudo-r 2, the authors find the R 2 of the analyst s forecasts is 79.8%.

Which mistakes drive the autocorrelation in forecast errors? The optimal forecast is: ŷ t = (1 ˆφ)ˆµ + ˆφ{ŷ t + ˆK(FE t )}+ŵs t ˆφ is the belief about the persistence of earnings growth shocks ˆK summarizes the belief in the informativeness of the reported earnings growth ŵ is how much the analyst weighs the additional signal s informativeness. An overconfident analyst weighs their private information more (ŵ w), while an analyst who herds weighs their information less (ŵ w).

Why is the Kalman Gain underestimated? Table 2 shows that it is the underestimation of K driving the autocorrelation; ˆφ and ŵ are quite close to their true values. This suggests the analysts have correct beliefs about the precision of the extra signals and the variance of the shocks to the persistent component of earnings growth. The Kalman gain used by the analysts ( ˆK = 0.414) vs. actual Kalman gain (K = 0.953) ŵ w 0, meaning analysts do not overestimate the precision of the additional signal ( ˆσ 2 n ) or the permanent growth shocks ( ˆσ 2 e ). The only explanation (in this model) for this is that ˆσ 2 a σ 2 a or an overestimation of the noise of the reported earnings.

Detection Error Probabilities In order to estimate the amount of robustness, we estimate the distance between the approximating and worst case model. Definitions Detection Error Probability p(η) = 1 (Pr(mistake A) + Pr(mistake W )) 2 where A is the approximating model and W is the worst case model

Table 3 Insert Table 3 here

Autocorrelation from the variation in the mean forecast error Intuition: A positive error is likely to be followed by a positive error. The sample is drawn from groups (firms, time periods or combination of both). If the mean forecasts differ between groups - then the error terms will cor(fe t+1,fe t ) = var(b m) var(µ ˆµ) = var(fe t ) var(fe t ) For examples, analysts could be accurate but issue systematically too low or too high forecasts for some firms. This will lead to an upward bias in the forecasts.

Figure 2

Autocorrelation from estimation errors in the persistence of the earnings growth shocks This effect comes from the first term in proposition 2. Variation in the estimation of the persistent component of the earnings growth. cov( ˆKy t + (1 ˆK)ŷ t,fe t ) (φ ˆφ) var(fe t )

Table 4

Ideas for further research If autocorrelation is present in analysts forecasts, then it should have an effect on how investors learn about analysts ability and objectives. Following Chen et al.(2005), we have a simple estimation of Bayesian learning: M i,t = α 0 +a 1 NEWS i,t +a 2 w(n i,t ) NEWS i,t +a 3 w(n i,t ) ACC(N i,t ) NEW 1 M i,t is a measure of market impact 2 N is performance signals 3 NEWS is difference between forecast and consensus 4 ACC(N) is accuracy (average absolute forecast error) 5 w(n) is a weight increasing in observations of N